Abstract

We propose and implement a procedure to optimally hedge climate change risk. First, we construct climate risk indices through textual analysis of newspapers. Second, we present a new approach to compute factor-mimicking portfolios to build climate risk hedge portfolios. The new mimicking portfolio approach is much more efficient than traditional sorting or maximum correlation approaches by taking into account new methodologies of estimating large-dimensional covariance matrices in short samples. In an extensive empirical out-of-sample performance test, we demonstrate the superior all-around performance delivering markedly higher and statistically significant alphas and betas with the climate risk indices.

PL Credits: 2.0:

    Introduction

    Climate change poses a great risk to the global economy and ultimately to the human race. Investors recognizing this risk are demanding portfolios that recognize and optimize with respect to this risk. The financial services industry has responded with a plethora of new offerings. In April 2022, Bjoy et al. (Citation2022) identified 860 global mutual funds and exchange-traded funds (ETFs) with a climate mandate. These funds have assets under management of $407 billion—double the value from a year earlier. As this segment of investment products expands, it is natural to study the effectiveness of these offerings and the theory underlying their management. Of course, objectives may differ for different asset managers and investors. Morningstar now divides this universe into five buckets: low carbon, climate conscious, green bonds, climate solutions, and clean energy/tech. In most cases, a simple feature is a common component of all these categories. The portfolio over-weights stocks that are or will be prepared for climate change and underweights those that are not. The portfolio should therefore outperform the broad market in a bad climate outcome and can be considered a climate hedge portfolio. See, for example, Jurczenko and Teiletche (Citation2022); Engle et al. (Citation2020); Andersson, Bolton, and Samama (Citation2016); Engle (Citation2014); and others following the framework of Merton (Citation1987). The actual management of these funds recognizes that there are competing objectives and many theories about how climate change will evolve and impact different firms and sectors.

    Investors around the world desire products that allow them to hedge against the realizations of climate risk. Because of the long-run and nondiversifiable nature of climate risk, standard futures or insurance contracts in which one party promises to pay the other in the event of a climate disaster are difficult to implement. Indeed, no counterparty could credibly guarantee to pay claims during a climate disaster event that might materialize in many decades, in part because a bad outcome would mandate all contracts to be paid at the same time. Individual investors are therefore largely constrained to self-insure against climate risk.

    In this paper, we will propose and implement an approach to forming an optimal hedge portfolio of publicly available sustainable funds. We will call this a climate-efficient factor-mimicking portfolio (CEP). Roughly, this portfolio will have both a minimum variance objective and maximum greenness criterion. The risk of these funds will be estimated by a new shrinkage estimator from De Nard (Citation2022) that reduces the noise in large covariance matrices when samples are short. This is an important property, as the number of sustainable funds is increasing rapidly, but their track records are usually (too) short. The greenness of any fund and of the CEP will be measured by its response to new information on climate change after controlling for other standard risk factors. The balance between these two criteria will be based on out-of-sample performance of an extensive real-life empirical analysis for various climate (change) news indices.

    Due to the rise in investors’ awareness of the economic and financial risks of climate change and the increased demand for financial instruments to hedge these risks, there have recently been great strides in academic research on operationalizing methods for climate hedging.

    Our approach is related to the “mimicking portfolio” approach of Lamont (Citation2001), where climate risk series are projected onto a set of portfolio returns using time-series information. Since it does not take an a priori view on which assets gain or lose when climate shocks occur, it needs to learn this from assets’ return performance during past climate risk realizations. The innovation of our approach is to rely on efficient long-only portfolios based on sustainable and climate-related ETFs, reducing not only exposure to climate change risks but also financial risks (portfolio standard deviation) and superior (risk-adjusted) returns.

    One drawback of these mimicking portfolio approaches is that they require long time series. That is why alternative approaches focus more on long and short positions based on economic reasoning, for example, sell coal companies and buy clean energy companies or, as suggested by Engle et al. (Citation2020), buy (sell) companies with high (low) ESG scores. The difficulty of this approach is to use the right priors about investors’ perceptions of each industry’s exposures to climate risk. It only hedges climate risk if the underlying economic intuition is aligned with that of the “average investor.”

    A new, promising quantity-based approach from Alekseev et al. (Citation2022) shows improved hedging performance by exploiting information on how mutual fund managers trade in response to idiosyncratic changes in their climate risk beliefs.Footnote1 The quantity-based approach predicts the investors’ capital reallocation around such idiosyncratic (climate change) belief shocks that could move equilibrium prices. Alekseev et al. (Citation2022) show that a portfolio that is long stocks that investors tend to buy after experiencing negative idiosyncratic climate belief shocks and short stocks that investors tend to sell, appreciate in value in periods with negative aggregate climate news shocks. An advantage of the quantity-based approach is that it learns from rich cross-sectional trading responses rather than time-series price information.

    Acknowledging the discussed alternative approaches, we focus on advances for the more traditional mimicking portfolio approach. Our contribution is to introduce an investible long-only climate-efficient factor-mimicking portfolio that is simple to implement, interpret, and customize. Contrary to the discussed literature, we focus on sustainable and climate-related ETFs without any short sales, as we deem our investment universe as “green.” Additionally, we use (hedging) optimized portfolios rather then sorting portfolios where further (sustainability) constraints and portfolio preferences can be easily included. To tackle the curse of dimensionality (rapidly increasing number of sustainable funds, but with short track record) we use shrinkage estimators for more robust portfolio optimization. Finally, an investor needs to select only its investment universe and climate hedge target. Additional expensive and difficult-to-obtain data are not necessary.

    Framework

    Climate risk is the risk that changes in climate will negatively impact cash flows in the future. To some extent, the market has already priced this risk; where this risk is great, assets are priced below their intrinsic riskless value. Equivalently, expected returns must be high to compensate investors for holding assets heavily exposed to climate risk. This feature has been documented empirically by Bolton and Kacperczyk (Citation2021). This climate risk premium must be based on the market’s view of the severity, likelihood, and urgency of climate change and the exposure of this asset to such risks. It is natural to formulate this as a climate risk factor, which is a weighted average of financial assets where the weights are based on the climate exposure of each asset. Investors unconcerned with climate risk would hold this portfolio for its higher expected return, and investors who want to hedge climate risk would short this portfolio and expect a negative risk premium and reduced returns in exchange for reduced risk. New information will induce repricing of assets. If the new information indicates that climate risk is increasing, then asset values will fall roughly in proportion to the asset exposures; therefore, the climate risk portfolio will underperform and its short counterpart—the climate hedge portfolio—will outperform.

    To examine this empirically, it is necessary to have a measure of the news. This could be text-based measures from news channels or physical news such as temperature extremes. Whenever there is news that climate risks are greater than the market has priced, the climate hedge factor should appreciate in value. These changes will appear as an alpha when the climate risk factor is missing. Over time, as the market reprices with new scientific and public analyses, the market pricing should approach the scientific view and if this continues to deteriorate, the hedge portfolios should continue to appreciate. Thus, holding a climate hedge portfolio should yield negative returns in the absence of news on climate risk, but when there is news, the yield should be positive. From this perspective, the news simply accumulates. Either there is no news or there is some news and the cumulative excess returns on the climate hedge portfolio will depend upon the cumulative news. Thus, the alpha at any point in time should be associated with the news at that point in time, possibly with some lags.

    A closely related theoretical analysis is presented by Pástor, Stambaugh, and Taylor (Citation2021), wherein the driving force is differences in investor preferences for green stocks rather than differences in risk. The results instead are lower prices for green stocks and higher returns. The differences could be due to the timing of climate news as well as the characterization of green and brown stocks.

    Careful analysis of the implications of climate change suggests in fact that at least two disparate factors can be defined. One is the physical risk of climate change from rising temperatures, increased storms, droughts, and wildfires and the range of physical hazards that could result. The second is the risk inherent in the transition to a low–carbon emission economy that is a natural response to the risks of climate change. This risk is based at least in part on policy and is therefore sometimes called regulation risk, although it is more commonly called transition risk. While both factors would be expected to have positive risk premiums, the factors are often negatively correlated. If important regulations are proposed, transition risk rises and physical risk falls. However, a predicted severe hurricane season would increase both risks and a technological breakthrough in carbon sequestration would decrease both risks.

    Measuring Climate Change News

    A central feature of this theory is that climate hedge portfolios should appreciate when there is news that climate risk is increasing. There are many ways this news can be measured, and we have used several in this analysis, following the literature by Engle et al. (Citation2020), Ardia et al. (Citation2022), and Faccini, Matin, and Skiadopoulos (Citation2021), among others. These measures have obvious shortcomings and yet are simple and easily understood. Since we are asking what news will move the market perception of climate change risk, there will always be room for improvement and it is important to understand the strengths and limitations of such measures. We feel that the series we discus here are good compromises.

    New York Times

    Two measures are based on textual analysis of The New York Times (NYT). In Engle et al. (Citation2020), the same methodology was applied to The Wall Street Journal (WSJ). The procedure follows Gentzkow, Bryan Kelly, and Taddy (Citation2019). Each article is examined for its word frequency, and these frequencies are compared with the same body of authoritative texts on the subject of climate change. After stripping out small words (stop words) and combining words with the same root but different stems (stemming), we have a unique set of one- and two-word combinations. We count their frequency in the dictionary and in each day of the NYT. For each document in the NYT and in the dictionary, these counts are converted to “term frequency–inverse document frequency” or tfidf scores. For word j, in document I, this expression is: (3.1) tfi,jidfj=ci,jni×log(ndj),(3.1) where ci,j is the specific word count in document i, ni is the total word count in document i, and dj is the number of documents that contain word j. Hence, a word that is in most documents will have a weight near zero. Rare words will be emphasized, and if they appear in document j, the tfidf can be very big. Finally, we construct our daily climate change index as the “cosine similarity” between the tfidf scores for each daily edition of NYT and the climate dictionary.

    A second index is constructed from the same source but uses tags that are supplied by LexisNexis to each article in the daily NYT. There are several thousand tags that are constructed, and each article has one or more tags. These tags are assigned by a proprietary natural language processing procedure that may or may not correspond to the matching of word frequencies. Thus, we can interpret such tags as the result of an algorithm that is constructed for public use of the news series. We measure the proportion of news articles that include either “global warming” or “climate change” as one of the tags. Although both indices are inherently daily, we use a weekly version. The news series are reported for seven days, yet the stock market has only a five-day week. The news series, thus, is treated as constant for a week at the level from the preceding week.

    The indices are plotted in . The figure shows that the intensity of climate news coverage has steadily increased in the last two decades. In addition, the climate risk indices spike during salient climate events, such as the adoption of global climate treaties (e.g., Paris Agreement or the Kyoto Protocol), or important global conferences to battle climate change (e.g., the 2009 UN Climate Change Conference in Copenhagen).

    Figure 1. The New York Times Climate News Indices from June 2001 to January 2021

    Figure 1. The New York Times Climate News Indices from June 2001 to January 2021

    Figure 2. Plot of the Cumulative Returns of the Various Investable Factors in Log Scale

    Figure 2. Plot of the Cumulative Returns of the Various Investable Factors in Log Scale

    Wall Street Journal

    Several news indices were constructed from the WSJ. These indices are based upon machine learning algorithms that use keywords to direct the search for clusters of relevant news. These are designed to reflect general climate risk, physical risk, and transition risk.

    The WSJ indices are plotted in . The figure shows also that the intensity of climate news coverage has increased in the last two decades and that the climate risk indices spike during salient climate events or important global conferences. Additionally, we see that the three WSJ indices have overall similar co-movements. In , we report the (daily) pairwise correlations among all investigated climate news indices. All the indices are positively correlated with each other, and the correlations between the WSJ versions are especially large.

    Factor-Mimicking Portfolios

    Selection of the Investment and Factor Universe

    We seek portfolios of underlying assets that are efficient climate hedge portfolios. We propose to focus on assets that are sustainable and climate-related portfolios. For example, a selection by Morningstar of US funds includes mutual funds and ETFs that satisfy at least one of the following criteria: fossil fuel–free, low-carbon, low–environmental risk score, and sustainable-sector funds. We restrict our attention to V-LAB’s 177 climate-focused funds.Footnote2

    There are two general approaches to forming factor-mimicking portfolios of a non-investible factor such as climate news. The first is often called a maximum-correlation portfolio and was introduced by Huberman and Kandel (Citation1987) and Lamont (Citation2001). The news series is regressed on asset returns to find a portfolio with maximum correlation with the news series. This approach was employed in Engle et al. (Citation2020), among others. The second uses a two-step method to find the sensitivity of each asset to the news series and then combines this information through a Fama and MacBeth (Citation1973) or Lehmann and Modest (Citation1988) cross-sectional regression to get the portfolio. These are shown in Jurczenko and Teiletche (Citation2019, Citation2022) to be special cases of the general asset pricing setting which seeks a minimum-variance portfolio subject to a constraint on its correlation with the news series. Their formulation, however, does not include other investible factors and expects the underlying assets to span the universe of returns in order to form principle components that span the factor space. We provide a simple and useful extension.

    When deriving a climate factor-mimicking portfolio, we find it important—but not mandatory—to control for other well-known factors from the literature. We deem the three Fama–French factors (MARKET, HML, and SMB) as well as a stranded asset (SA) and oil short-term future factor (ROIL) the most useful for our purpose.Footnote3 Note that we are interested in investable risk factors. Thus, we compute the investable factors as follows:

    • MARKET:=VTIrfFootnote4

    • HML:=IWD+IWN(IWF+IWO)

    • SMB:=IWN+IWO(IWF+IWD)

    • SA:=SPY0.7*KOL0.3*XLE

    • ROIL := WTI crude oil returns

    where VTI is the Vanguard Total Stock Market Index Fund ETF; rf is the risk-free rate; IWD is the Russell 1000 Value ETF; IWF is the Russell 1000 Growth ETF; IWN is the Russell 2000 Value ETF; IWO is the Russell 2000 Growth ETF; SPY is the SPDR S&P 500 ETF Trust; KOL is the VanEck Vectors Coal ETF; and XLE is the Energy Select Sector SPDR Fund. The investable factors are plotted in .

    The Climate Factor Signal

    Basically, we are interested to find climate-related funds that mimic the behavior of an underlying climate factor. Therefore, we include our climate news series detailed in “Measuring Climate Change News.” Then, we regress each climate-related fund, i=1,,177, on the factors and the climate (change) news, CC, using a rolling regression with (one year of) daily data: (4.1) ri,t=β̂i CCt+γ̂i Factorst+ϵ̂i,t,(4.1) where Factors = (MARKET, HML, SMB, SA, ROIL). Now the β̂i for each climate-related fund is the signal upon which we want to derive our mimicking portfolio. We argue that the higher the β̂i, the better and thus the higher the fund's weight must be. However, if β̂i is negative, we give a weight of zero to the particular fund. Consequently, we propose a long-only factor-mimicking portfolio. The reason we restrict our attention to a long-only portfolio is twofold. First, for our investment universe we select only sustainable and climate-related funds. Thus, we do not want to short sell such a fund that Morningstar and V-LAB deem to be climate-focused. Second, similar to why we consider investable (control) factors, we want to compute real-life investable portfolios without any difficult-to-implement constraints.

    A simple method to generate a signal (vector) b out of the β̂’s is to weight the positive β̂’s: (4.2) bβ̂:=β˜i=1177β˜i,β˜:=max(β̂,0).(4.2)

    We also propose two alternative signals based on the squared β̂’s and β̂ times its t statistics: (4.3) bβ̂2:=β˜2i=1177β˜i2,β˜2:=(β˜12,,β˜1772),(4.3) (4.4) bt‐stat:=β˜t‐stati=1177β˜it‐stat,β˜it‐stat:=β˜i2σ̂iHC3,β˜t‐stat:=(β˜1t‐stat,,β˜177t‐stat),(4.4) where σ̂iHC3 is the heteroskedasticity-consistent HC3 standard error of β̂i.

    As we want to compute a long-only mimicking portfolio, we restrict our attention to strictly positive signals only and thus reduce the investment universe accordingly. More specifically, we consider the sub-universe of N177 funds with (strictly positive) signal vector b.

    Note that the signal vector b on its own is already a very intuitive long-only factor-mimicking portfolio. It simply weights all funds based on their (positive) β̂i on the climate news series we want to mimic. We denote this portfolio as our base case. Even though the base case seems to be an intuitive start, arguably, it is suboptimal portfolio as it is inefficient. We want to improve upon the base-case portfolio by including a more sophisticated and optimized mimicking portfolio construction, resulting in an efficient portfolio by taking into account the information of the funds’ covariance matrix.

    In , we plot the size of the investment universe and the actual number of funds that indeed have a positive signal (β). Note that we invest only in funds that have a complete daily return time series for a yearly rolling window with monthly rebalancing. The number of funds included in the investment universe monotonically increased from 45 in June 2001 to 177 in January 2021. The number of climate-related funds increased especially during the last five years. On the contrary, with exception of the last two years, the number of funds with a positive signal (β) did not increase significantly. In the percentage of funds with a positive signal, there was even a decrease since the financial crisis in 2008. In January 2021, almost 60% of the funds have a positive signal. The average positive β is 0.03, with an average t statistic of 0.80.

    Figure 3. The Number of Funds in the Investment Universe and the Actual Number and Percentage of Funds in Which We Want to Invest

    Notes: Funds with a positive signal and large enough time series. Numbers are for a yearly rolling window with monthly rebalancing frequency from 06/19/2001 until 01/29/2021 for the NYT Tag Climate (Change) News Index. NYT = The New York Times.
    Figure 3. The Number of Funds in the Investment Universe and the Actual Number and Percentage of Funds in Which We Want to Invest

    Efficient Mimicking Portfolio Construction

    The next step is to use the derived signal b to compute a constrained long-only (wi0) and fully invested (w1=1) climate factor-mimicking portfolio w. To this end, we propose the following portfolio-optimization problem: (4.5) minwwΣ̂wλwb,(4.5) (4.6) s.t.wi0 for all i=1,,N and (4.6) (4.7) w1=1,(4.7) where Σ̂ is the N×N estimated covariance matrix of climate funds returns, 1 is a conformable vector of ones, and λ0 is a scaling parameter to define the form of the optimization problem. For example, if we set λ equal to zero, we are basically estimating the constrained minimum-variance portfolio without any signal information, or if we set λ to we do not take into account the covariance matrix and thus invest only in the asset(s) with the largest signal bi. Note that the (exact) value of λ depends on the risk appetite and hedging preference of the investor: The higher (lower) the value of λ, the higher (lower) the risk appetite and hedging preference are. Arguably, the portfolio of interest should consider both the covariance matrix and the signal to be an attractive “well-diversified” and risk-controlled (climate efficient factor–)mimicking portfolio.

    In our analysis, we define the base-case scenario as λ=2, with the identity matrix as covariance matrix estimator Σ̂=I. This is an interesting scenario because the minimization function (4.5) simplifies to ww2wb, with the unique solution w*=b. This is the very intuitive portfolio that weights its constitutes according to their signal. Another special case is when we set λ=0; thus, the constrained minimum-variance portfolio based on replacing the covariance matrix estimator with the identity matrix. This results in the equally weighted portfolio of the assets with positive signal: w*=1/N. Consequently, in the optimization problem (4.5–4.7) with Σ̂=I, we derive two naive benchmarks: b weighting (base case) and equal weighting (1/N).

    We believe that we can improve upon these naive portfolios by taking into account a more sophisticated covariance matrix estimator than just the identity matrix. However, due to the large and increasing number of sustainable and climate-related funds (N; see ) and the short sample that is available/observable (T), this is a challenging task. In such a setting, the sample covariance matrix has a poor out-of-sample performance. Jobson and Korkie (Citation1980) show that the sample covariance matrix suffers from high estimation error, especially when the number of available assets N is high compared to the return time-series length T. The shrinkage estimators of Ledoit and Wolf (Citation2022) compose a powerful class of estimators for this setting. Due to the small sample size, we suggest the (unconditional) constant-variance-covariance (CVC) linear shrinkage estimator of De Nard (Citation2022), which shrinks the sample variances and sample covariances toward their grand mean.Footnote5 Recently, these shrinkage estimators were successfully extended to dynamic and factor models. Unfortunately, due to the short time-series length of the sustainable and climate-related funds, the combination of shrinkage with multivariate GARCH models as introduced by Engle, Ledoit, and Wolf (Citation2019) and the enhancement with intraday data by De Nard et al. (Citation2022) are suboptimal. On the contrary, the extension to factor models of De Nard, Ledoit, and Wolf (Citation2021) is a further improvement to reduce the curse of dimensionality. Therefore, we recommend using the AFM-CVC estimator. This is an approximate factor model (AFM) in which the covariance matrix of the factors and residuals are estimated via CVC shrinkage. The proposed estimator is similar to the Dynamic Conditional Correlation - Nonlinear shrinkage approximate factor model dynamic conditional correlation-nonlinear shrinkage (AFM-DCC-NL) estimator of De Nard and Zhao (Citation2023), but with three modifications: (i) It uses linear shrinkage instead of nonlinear shrinkage due to the small sample, (ii) there is no (multivariate) GARCH component due to the small sample, and (iii) it uses the investable (see “Selection of the Investment and Factor Universe”) instead of the “academic” Fama–French factors. In Appendix B, we give an overview of the modified approximate factor model shrinkage estimator.

    Performance Measures

    The first performance measure is the β of the news variable. Thereby, we regress the (return of the) climate-efficient factor-mimicking portfolio, rCEP,t, on climate news and factors using the whole dataset (without intercept): (4.8) rCEP,t=β̂ CCt+γ̂ Factorst+ϵ̂t.(4.8)

    Ideally, the estimated β should be positive and significant, and the bigger the better. This is an out-of-sample test in the sense that every month of the portfolio return is subsequent to the data used to form the portfolio, as described in “Efficient Mimicking Portfolio Construction.”

    The second performance measure is the α of the mimicking portfolio. Thereby, regress the excess return of CEP on all investable factors using the whole dataset: (4.9) rCEP,trf,t=α̂+γ̂ Factorst+ϵ̂t.(4.9)

    Ideally, the estimated intercept, α̂, should be positive and significant, and the bigger the better. This is an out-of-sample test every month.

    For the estimation of the parameters in regression 4.8 and 4.9, we use adaptive least squares (ALS) for improved inference in financial factor models, as shown by Beck, De Nard, and Wolf (Citation2023). ALS generally leads to smaller heteroskedasticity-consistent (HC) standard errors compared to ordinary least squares (OLS), which translates into improved inference in the form of shorter confidence intervals and more powerful hypothesis tests. The ALS method “decides” between the OLS method and the weighted least squares (WLS) method based on a pretest for conditional homoskedasticity. Only if this test rejects the null—that is, if this tests detects a significant amount of conditional heteroskedasticity in the data—does one use WLS; otherwise, one uses OLS. Of course, either way, one must use corresponding HC standard errors for the inference. Note that we use HC3 to compute the test statistics.

    An interesting alternative performance measure is the (Pearson’s linear) out-of-sample correlation between the CEP and the climate news index. Even though the correlation is an intuitive performance measure to quantify the accuracy of a factor-mimicking portfolio, the goal is to derive a positively correlated factor-mimicking portfolio controlled for various factors. Therefore, in line with the validating β regression, we focus on the partial correlation between the CEP and the climate news index of interest, adjusting for the other five factors mentioned above. Thereby, we focus on daily, weekly, and monthly out-of-sample partial correlations.

    Finally, we also report annualized results on the out-of-sample average portfolio return (AV), standard deviation (SD), and information ratio (IR := AV/SD).

    It is clear that by optimizing these criteria, the results are no longer truly out-of-sample. A fully out-of-sample version of this portfolio is maintained and updated daily on V-LAB. In this case, the tuning parameters remain fixed and the code is fixed. News data and returns are generated daily, and the portfolio weights are updated monthly. Performance of this climate-efficient factor-mimicking portfolio (CEP) is posted daily on V-LAB.

    Empirical Analysis

    In our empirical analysis, we use daily data with a monthly rolling window, resulting in a monthly re-estimation of the models and rebalancing of the portfolios. In this section, we present the main results of our climate-efficient factor-mimicking portfolio approach, the results for monthly rebalancing based on the β×t-statistics signal (Equation4.4). The main results are based on 4,935 daily (out-of-sample) returns of the NYT Tag Index CEP from 06/19/2001 until 01/29/2021. To further the robustness of our results, in “Robustness of the Portfolio” we include other signals and climate news indices.

    Main Results

    To show that we have computed a well-performing climate factor-mimicking portfolio, we plot the alphas and betas for various parameterizations of our CEP optimization in .

    Figure 4. The (Annualized) α̂ and β̂ and Their 95% Confidence Intervals Based on HC3 Standard Errors for the Factor-Mimicking Portfolios of the NYT Climate News Based on the β×t-Statistics Signal

    Note: NYT = The New York Times.
    Figure 4. The (Annualized) α̂ and β̂ and Their 95% Confidence Intervals Based on HC3 Standard Errors for the Factor-Mimicking Portfolios of the NYT Climate News Based on the β×t-Statistics Signal

    We find that our CEP approach is very powerful and robust, as all resulting CEPs have strictly positive (out-of-sample) α̂ and β̂. Interestingly, the extreme portfolio which neglects the signal by setting (λ=0), has positive α̂ and β̂. Therefore, the investment universe selection screening for funds with a positive signal is vitally important. However, the α̂ and β̂ of this constrained minimum-variance portfolio are not statistically significant. To visualize all the CEPs that have statistically significant α̂ and β̂, we plot their 95% confidence bands based on HC3 standard errors. When increasing the exposure to the signal, thus λ, we observe that not only the β̂ but also the α̂ of the CEP is increasing quickly and becoming statistically significant. Consequently, deviating from the minimum-variance portfolio and putting more weight on the signal are clearly beneficial. Nevertheless, putting too much weight on the signal can hurt the performance because in the limit, where λ=, we focus only on the signal, resulting in a CEP investing only in the fund with the largest signal. Arguably, this is not an interesting portfolio for a climate hedging manager as it is undiversified and has a large exposure to estimation error of the signal. Finally, both extreme portfolios are suboptimal with insignificant performance measures, but there is a large spectrum of CEPs in between with large and statistically significant α̂ and β̂. These CEPs find a good combination of signal exposure and variance reduction.

    Due to the robustness of our CEP approach, we see that the α̂ and β̂ are very stable for a “large enough” λ. Nevertheless, empirically we find an optimal and consistent region around λ0.002, with the largest and statistically significant α̂ and β̂. The performance measures of this CEP and all the benchmarks are presented in . The CEP delivers a high α̂ of 7.34% (with a t statistic of 2.68) and a high β̂ of 3.30 (with a t statistic of 2.66). Thus, we have indeed derived climate(-efficient) factor-mimicking portfolios.

    Table 1. Various Annualized Performance Measures (in %) of the Monthly Re-estimated and Rebalanced Climate-Efficient Factor-Mimicking Portfolio (CEP) Based on the β×t-Statistics Signal and Various Benchmarks

    Now we restrict our attention to the (optimal) CEP and compare its performance with various benchmarks: the β×t-statistic signal-weighted portfolio (base case), the signal-only portfolio (λ=), the constrained minimum-variance portfolio (λ=0), the positive signal equally weighted portfolio (1/N), and the (overall) equally weighted portfolio (EW). All performance measures are summarized in .Footnote6

    First, all included benchmarks are consistently and markedly outperformed by the proposed CEP. With exception of the β̂ and monthly partial correlation of the base case, the results are not statistically significant for the benchmarks. For the equally weighted portfolio, the α̂, β̂, and partial correlations are even negative. Thus, even though we focus on a sustainable and climate-related investment universe, it is a difficult task to derive a long-only climate factor-mimicking portfolio with positive and statistically significant results. The 1/N improves the performance by focusing only on the sub-universe with positive signal; however, the results are still bad. Therefore, more impressive are the large and significant α̂ (up to 7.34%) and β̂ (up to 3.30) we can obtain by our CEPs.

    In comparison, the naive benchmarks based on the identity matrix, Σ̂=I, are not performing that well. The base case has a statistically insignificant α̂ of 2.46%, roughly one-third of the CEP, and statistically significant β̂ of 1.71, almost half as large. Therefore, within our CEP approach (Equation4.5), the identity matrix is markedly and consistently outperformed by more sophisticated covariance matrix estimators, for example, by AFM-CVC. Even though the identity matrix is a very naive covariance matrix estimator, it gives us intuitive and diversified portfolios. For example, for λ=0, we get the (positive signal) equally weighted portfolio (1/N), and for λ=2 we get the (positive) signal-weighted portfolio (base case). Even though the base case has positive α̂ and β̂ and the 1/N has positive β̂, they are suboptimal portfolios markedly outperformed by our CEP.

    As mentioned above, there are two interesting special cases for CEP. The first is (λ=) which gives a maximum weight to the signal and selects an undiversified portfolio investing only in the asset with the largest signal at each rebalancing. This extreme portfolio is performing decently and is the best benchmark; it is also much better then the base case that weights the portfolio according to the signal size. It has high α̂ (5.55%) and β̂ (2.74); however, the parameter estimates are not statistically significant and are still way below the CEP. This is due to the large estimation error of the noisy signal and no diversification effect. On the contrary, if we ignore the signal (λ=0) and compute the long-only minimum-variance portfolio, the α̂ and β̂ shrink close to zero but are still higher than those of the equally weighted naive benchmarks.

    A further contribution of our CEP approach is that we compute efficient portfolios and not just maximum correlation portfolios or naively weighted portfolios. We directly incorporate the covariance matrix of the funds in our optimization to control for the CEP variance. Therefore, the higher the λ, the higher the risk appetite of an investor, usually resulting in increased average return (AV), standard deviation (SD), and turnover (TO) of the portfolio. We present the relevant summary statistics in . Additionally, in we plot the standard deviation and information ratio (IR := AV/SD) for our CEPs based on the AFM-CVC shrinkage covariance matrix estimator (in blue) and the identity matrix as implied by the base case and the equally weighted benchmarks. All the benchmarks are markedly and consistently outperformed by more sophisticated covariance matrix estimators, for example, by AFM-CVC. AFM-CVC successfully reduces the out-of-sample standard deviation and thus increases the information ratio. In terms of SD, the outperformance of AFM-CVC over the identity matrix is (always) highly statistically significant and also economically meaningful.Footnote7 In terms of IR, the outperformance of AFM-CVC over the identity matrix is usually statistically significant and also economically meaningful.Footnote8 For example, for the CEP, thus AFM-CVC with λ=0.0022 marked with *, the IR is 0.69 and hence much larger than all benchmarks. Consequently, the efficiency of optimizing (4.5) by the proposed CEP not only finds a markedly improved tradeoff solution of the signal-to-noise ratio, by increasing the α̂ and β̂ and making them statistically significant, but also improves upon the risk-return tradeoff by generating (statistically significant) larger risk-adjusted returns; see .

    Figure 5. The (Annualized) Out-of-Sample Standard Deviation and Information Ratio of Various NYT Climate News Factor-Mimicking Portfolios Based on the β×t-Statistics Signal

    Notes: The efficient factor-mimicking portfolios are based on the AFM-CVC shrinkage estimator (blue), and the optimal CEP is marked with *. The numbers of the benchmarks based on the identity matrix are plotted as horizontal lines for comparison. AFM = approximate factor model; CEP = CEP = climate-efficient factor-mimicking portfolio; CVC = constant-variance-covariance; NYT = The New York Times.
    Figure 5. The (Annualized) Out-of-Sample Standard Deviation and Information Ratio of Various NYT Climate News Factor-Mimicking Portfolios Based on the β×t-Statistics Signal

    As an alternative performance measure, we also present (out-of-sample) partial correlations (PCor) between the factor-mimicking portfolios and the climate news index; see . Also in terms of partial correlation, our CEPs are very powerful and robust. Across all return frequencies, any computed CEP has strictly positive partial correlation with the climate news index. Interestingly, the partial correlation increases markedly with lower frequencies. There are two main reasons: First, aggregating daily returns to weekly or monthly returns reduces the noise extensively. Second, the climate news index is on a weekly frequency. Note that in terms of partial correlation, the base case consistently outperforms the CEPs and for monthly returns the PCor of 15.58% is even statistically significant. The equally weighted portfolios have very low or even negative PCor. This shows again that even with a sustainable and climate-related investment universe, it is difficult to compute a decent out-of-sample factor-mimicking portfolio.

    Finally, when we compare the distribution of the out-of-sample performance measures, IR (), α̂ and β̂ (), and partial correlations, we observe a similar pattern. In general, the performance can be markedly increased by increasing the weight λ toward the signal; however, a too-large λ results in a less diversified and extreme portfolio. Motivated by our empirical findings, we propose to use a λ0.002 to obtain all-around large and statistically significant performance measures.

    Portfolio Composition

    In this section, we restrict our attention to the portfolio composition of the CEP and its benchmarks to investigate the portfolio holdings and their dynamic to obtain a successful mimicking portfolio. In the top panel of , we plot the fund weights of the climate-efficient factor-mimicking portfolios in terms of the scaling parameter λ at the end of the sample (01/29/2021). Hence, on the very left of this panel we see the fund weights of the long-only minimum-variance portfolio that is well diversified. Now increasing λ, and thus the weight to the climate signal, we observe how most of the weights and the number of assets in the portfolio become smaller. Note that in the limit (λ=), we invest only in the asset with the largest signal. The “optimal” CEP with λ=0.0022 is almost in the middle of this top panel, indicating that we invest only in a few assets with large position in a single fund. In the bottom panel of , we list the top 10 positions of this CEP at the end of the sample and see that it invests almost 65% in KraneShares MSCI China Environment (KGRN), more than 15% in Global X Lithium & Battery Tec (LIT), 7% in iShares Global Clean Energy (ICLN), as well as 5% in Invesco Global Clean Energy (PBD) and Invesco Solar (TAN).

    In the middle panel of , we plot the fund weights of the “optimal” CEP over time. We see that it is erratic, with often extreme positions that can change quickly from one rebalancing to another; thus, it has a high average monthly turnover of 95%. On the other hand, the base-case scenario is much more stable over time by investing proportional to the (positive) signal size with an average monthly turnover of 40%. Nevertheless, the CEP consistently outperforms the base case (in terms of risk-adjusted returns, α̂ and β̂), indicating how important it is to compute an efficient portfolio optimizing for portfolio variance and signal exposure. Consequently, diversification is not that important for a factor-mimicking portfolio; for example, see the results for no diversification at all with λ=.

    In , we also show the largest average monthly holdings and the percentage of holdings larger than 1%, both over the entire sample. For the last two decades, the New Alternatives (NALFX) ETF has been vitally important for climate news hedging with an average portfolio position of 8.55% and being more than 14% of the rebalancings in the portfolio.

    Besides examining the portfolio holdings, we also plot the sector exposures of the CEP and the base case in . We use the V-LAB classification of the 177 climate-related funds into (i) fossil fuel free, (ii) low carbon, and (iii) low environmental risk. We observe the same pattern that the base case is more diversified and stable over time. Interesting is that for the base case, at the beginning of the sample there is a similar exposure to all three sectors, in the middle there is a clear overweight of low environmental risk, and at the end there is a clear overweight of fossil fuel–free funds (80%) and no exposure anymore to low environmental risk. The CEP invests at the end of the sample only in fossil fuel–free funds, neglecting the low-carbon funds.

    Robustness of the Portfolio

    To further enhance the robustness of our results, we run several sensitivity checks. The results are robust also for weekly re-estimation of the models and rebalancing of the climate factor-mimicking portfolio. However, the average performance and significance of coefficients, α̂ and β̂, usually decreases for higher frequencies. Therefore, we deem monthly updating the most useful for our purpose.

    Transaction Costs

    An important disadvantage of the CEP is the discussed large monthly turnover and often low diversification compared to (most of) the benchmarks. Even though we empirically show that it is important to have sometimes large and dynamic exposures to single funds due to optimal hedging goals, arguably, the large turnover should be penalized due to investor preferences and costs. Consequently, we run a sensitivity analysis for performance numbers net of various transaction costs. In , we report the usual performance measures, taking into account 10 bps of transaction costs and report additionally the monthly average turnover (TO). The 10 bps are a conservative estimate of transaction costs because the 177 sustainable V-LAB funds are in general very large and liquid.

    Table 2. Various Annualized Performance Measures Net of 10 bps Transaction Costs of the Monthly Re-estimated and Rebalanced Climate-Efficient Factor-Mimicking Portfolio (CEP) Based on the β×t-Statistics Signal and Various Benchmarks

    From , we see that the transaction costs of 10 bps reduce the α̂ from 7.34 to 6.20 and the β̂ from 3.30 to 2.95. Due to the large turnover, the reduction is substantial and larger compared to the benchmarks, but the coefficients are still positive as well as economically important and statistically significant. Even net of transaction costs, there is superior all-around performance of CEP compared to all the benchmarks. Note that for CEP, we would need (unrealistically) large transaction costs of 25 bps to get insignificant but still positive α̂ and β̂.

    Alternative Signals

    To assess how robust and general our CEP approach is, we focus now on alternative (simpler) signals. In the empirical analysis, we used the β×t-statistic defined in (Equation4.4). The idea is to multiply the β with its t statistic to take into account not only the size but also the power of the signal. Alternatively, one could use directly the β or the squared β as a signal to overweight the actual size. The problem, especially of the latter, is that large(r) (absolute) signal numbers often have also large(r) estimation error and are prone to over-fitting and “error maximization” in optimization problem (Equation4.5). This error maximization is comparable with the estimation error problem of the covariance matrix. Michaud’s (Citation1989) explanation is that the most extreme sample covariance matrix coefficients, or here signals, tend to be extreme not because this is necessarily true but because they contain an extreme amount of error. Consequently, a Markowitz (Citation1952) signal-variance investor interested to solve (Equation4.5) takes the highest bets on the unreliable extreme coefficients of the beta and the sample covariance matrix for “optimal” signal exposure and risk control, which is counterproductive. This is why we suggest using a shrinkage estimator of the sample covariance matrix (AFM-CVC) and to weight the beta coefficients by their power (t statistics) to reduce estimation error.

    To show the benefit of weighting the signals by their power, we present the results of the β and β2 signals in and . First, the results show that our CEP approach is robust in terms of the signal choice as we observe similar results and patterns. Also for the alternative signals, we find a consistent outperformance when taking into account the AFM-CVC covariance matrix estimator with overall positive α̂, β̂, and partial correlation. Nevertheless, we see some intuitive differences between the signals. For example, the number of significant α̂ and β̂ reduces drastically for the β and β2 signal compared to the β×tstatistic signal. Furthermore, not only does the region of statistically significant CEPs shrink (in terms of λ) but also the level of α̂ and β̂ reduces consistently and markedly and, in general, the risk-adjusted returns also get smaller. Thus, controlling for the power of the β signal is clearly beneficial by avoiding very large positions in unreliably high β funds.

    Figure 6. The (Annualized) α̂ and β̂ and Their 95% Confidence Intervals Based on HC3 Standard Errors for Various Efficient Factor-Mimicking Portfolios of the NYT Climate News Based on the β and β2 Signal

    Note: NYT = The New York Times.
    Figure 6. The (Annualized) α̂ and β̂ and Their 95% Confidence Intervals Based on HC3 Standard Errors for Various Efficient Factor-Mimicking Portfolios of the NYT Climate News Based on the β and β2 Signal

    Table 3. Various Annualized Performance Measures (in %) of the Monthly Re-estimated and Rebalanced Climate-Efficient Factor-Mimicking Portfolio (CEP) Based on the β Signal (λ=0.0035) as Well as β2 Signal (λ=0.0015)

    Note that the results are very robust, such that for every signal investigated the CEP approach systematically outperforms all the benchmarks, delivering a statistically significant factor-mimicking portfolios with better (risk-adjusted) return profile. Again, only in terms of (monthly) out-of-sample partial correlations, the base-case scenario is hard to beat. In terms of “optimal” parametrization, we observe that the β-CEP λ of 0.0035 is larger than the β2-CEP λ of 0.0015. Thus, the β2-CEP gives more weight to the minimum-variance portfolio, which is intuitive as it does not want to put too high a weight on the very noisy signal.

    Alternative Climate News Indices

    To assess how robust and general our CEP approach is, we focus now on alternative climate news indices introduced in “Measuring Climate Change News.” Therefore, we also replicated the empirical analysis for the WSJ indices and find overall similar results. In , we report the most important summary statistics.

    Table 4. Various Annualized Performance Measures (in %) of the Monthly Re-estimated and Rebalanced WSJ General and Physical Climate Factor-Mimicking Portfolio Based on the β×t-Statistics Signal

    For the alternative WSJ indices, we find a consistent outperformance when taking into account the AFM-CVC covariance matrix estimator with overall positive α̂, β̂, and partial correlations. Interesting is that the level of α̂ and β̂ is in general higher for the WSJ indices compared to NYT; however, the estimation error in the coefficient is also larger, resulting in a smaller region of statistically significant performance measures. For example, the “optimal” WSJ physical CEP with λ=0.0011, presented in , has an impressive but insignificant β̂ of 7.32. Nonetheless, the “optimal” WSJ general CEP with λ=0.0020, also presented in , has the largest and statistically significant α̂ of 8.19%, β̂ of 6.58, and IR of 0.73, across all indices and signals. Thereby, the β̂ of the WSJ general CEP almost doubles compared to the NYT CEP.

    Note that the results are very robust, such that for every investigated signal and index the CEP approach systematically outperforms all the benchmarks, delivering (in general) statistically significant factor-mimicking portfolios with better (risk-adjusted) return profiles.

    Conclusion

    Earth’s climate is changing, but uncertainty around the trajectory and the economic consequences of climate change is substantial. As a result, investors around the world desire products that allow them to hedge against the realizations of climate risk. In this article, we provide a rigorous and efficient methodology for constructing portfolios that hedge against risks that are otherwise difficult to insure.

    We demonstrate how an efficient mimicking portfolio approach can be successful in hedging climate (change) risk across a number of out-of-sample performance tests. A central feature is that climate hedge portfolios should appreciate when there is news that climate risk is increasing. For this purpose, we first estimate climate risk by (daily) textual analysis of The New York Times and The Wall Street Journal, following the procedure of Gentzkow, Bryan Kelly, and Taddy (Citation2019) and Engle et al. (Citation2020). Second, we define a climate-efficient factor-mimicking portfolio (CEP) approach that takes into account not only the betas of the assets with the climate risk news (maximum-correlation approach) but also their risk by the estimation of their covariance matrix. Thereby, we focus on long-only portfolios based on V-LAB’s 177 climate-focused funds. Note that the (real-life) performance of the NYT CEPs are posted daily on https://vlab.stern.nyu.edu/climate.

    Taken together, we show that our CEP approach is very powerful and robust. It has superior all-around performance against a variety of benchmarks, delivering markedly higher and statistically significant alphas and betas with the climate news indices. Additionally, due to the optimization considering the covariance matrix, it returns an improved maximum correlation versus variance tradeoff with statistically significant larger information ratios.

    Disclaimer

    The views and opinions expressed herein are those of the authors; do not necessarily reflect the views of AQR Capital Management or OLZ AG, its affiliates, or its employees; do not constitute an offer, solicitation of an offer, or any advice or recommendation to purchase any securities or other financial instruments; and may not be construed as such.

    Acknowledgments

    We thank Heebum Lee, Olivier Ledoit, Michael Wolf, and the NSF, participants at the Volatility and Risk Institute Conference at NYU Stern, for helpful comments. This work has been nominated for the Swiss Risk Award 2021.

    Disclosure statement

    No potential conflict of interest was reported by the author(s).

    Additional information

    Funding

    The Norwegian Finance Initiative and the Global Risk Institute, CERES, and the UZH FAN, provided generous grant support.

    Notes on contributors

    Gianluca De Nard

    Gianluca De Nard is a research fellow at NYU Stern, New York, USA; senior researcher at University of Zurich, Zurich, Switzerland; and Head of Quantitative Research at OLZ AG, Zurich, Switzerland. Robert F. Engle is Professor Emeritus of Finance, and Co-Director of the Volatility and Risk Institute at NYU Stern, New York, New York, USA, and Research Associate at NBER, Cambridge, Massachusetts, USA. Bryan Kelly is Professor of Finance at Yale University, New Haven, Connecticut, USA; Head of Machine Learning at AQR Capital Management, Greenwich, Connecticut, US; and Research Associate at NBER, Cambridge, Massachusetts, USA.

    Robert F. Engle

    Gianluca De Nard is a research fellow at NYU Stern, New York, USA; senior researcher at University of Zurich, Zurich, Switzerland; and Head of Quantitative Research at OLZ AG, Zurich, Switzerland. Robert F. Engle is Professor Emeritus of Finance, and Co-Director of the Volatility and Risk Institute at NYU Stern, New York, New York, USA, and Research Associate at NBER, Cambridge, Massachusetts, USA. Bryan Kelly is Professor of Finance at Yale University, New Haven, Connecticut, USA; Head of Machine Learning at AQR Capital Management, Greenwich, Connecticut, US; and Research Associate at NBER, Cambridge, Massachusetts, USA.

    Bryan Kelly

    Gianluca De Nard is a research fellow at NYU Stern, New York, USA; senior researcher at University of Zurich, Zurich, Switzerland; and Head of Quantitative Research at OLZ AG, Zurich, Switzerland. Robert F. Engle is Professor Emeritus of Finance, and Co-Director of the Volatility and Risk Institute at NYU Stern, New York, New York, USA, and Research Associate at NBER, Cambridge, Massachusetts, USA. Bryan Kelly is Professor of Finance at Yale University, New Haven, Connecticut, USA; Head of Machine Learning at AQR Capital Management, Greenwich, Connecticut, US; and Research Associate at NBER, Cambridge, Massachusetts, USA.

    Notes

    1 They focus on two types of idiosyncratic belief shocks: (i) instances when fund advisors experience local extreme heat events that are known to shift climate change beliefs and (ii) instances when fund managers change the language in shareholder disclosures to express concerns about climate risks.

    2 Webpage: vlab.stern.nyu.edu.

    3 Alternatively, one could also include further momentum or profitability ETFs. In practice, the choice of factors will be up to the researcher and will depend upo n the factors relevant to the investor.

    4 Before VTI is available, we take the SPDR S&P 500 ETF Trust, SPYrf.

    5 Alternatively, one could use the analytical nonlinear shrinkage formula of Ledoit and Wolf (Citation2020). However, De Nard (Citation2022) and Ledoit and Wolf (Citation2017) have found that linear shrinkage, especially CVC, outperforms nonlinear shrinkage for smaller sample (T252) and investment universes (N100).

    6 We also analyze the value-weighted benchmark, measured by asset under management of the ETFs, and the buy and hold strategy of the largest ETF: American Funds Fundamental Investors (ANCFX). As these benchmarks have similar (poor) out-of-sample performance as EW, respectively 1/N, and due to readability, we do not report the results here. Nevertheless, the results are available upon request.

    7 Note that to assess the goodness of a covariance matrix estimator, one needs to compare only the SD of the minimum-variance portfolio, thus 13.60 for λ=0, as it is a “clean” problem without estimation of the expected returns or signals. To test the outperformance of the CEPs based on AFM-CVC, a two-sided p-value for the null hypothesis of equal standard deviations is obtained by the prewhitened HAC PW method described in Ledoit and Wolf (Citation2011, Section 3.1). As the out-of-sample size is very large at 4,935, there is no need to use the computationally more involved bootstrap method described in Ledoit and Wolf (Citation2011, Section 3.2), which is preferred for small sample sizes.

    8 A two-sided p-value for the null hypothesis of equal information ratios is obtained by the prewhitened HAC PW method described in Ledoit and Wolf (Citation2008, Section 3.1). Since the out-of-sample size is very large at 4,935, there is no need to use the computationally more expensive bootstrap method described in Ledoit and Wolf (Citation2008, Section 3.2), which is preferred for small sample sizes.

    References

    • Alekseev, G., S. Giglio, Q. Maingi, J. Selgrad, and J. Stroebel. 2022. “A Quantity-Based Approach to Constructing Climate Risk Hedge Portfolios.” National Bureau of Economic Research, Working Paper w30703.
    • Andersson, M., P. Bolton, and F. Samama. 2016. “Hedging Climate Risk.” Financial Analyst Journal 72 (3): 13–32.
    • Ardia, D., K. Bluteau, K. Boudt, and K. Inghelbrecht. 2022. “Climate Change Concerns and the Performance of Green versus Brown Stocks.” National Bank of Belgium, Working Paper No. 395.
    • Beck, E., G. De Nard, and M. Wolf. 2023. “Improved Inference in Financial Factor Models.” International Review of Economics & Finance 86: 364–379. doi:10.1016/j.iref.2023.03.009.
    • Bjoy, H., B. Wang, A. Stankiewicz, and A. Alladi. 2022. Investing in Times of Climate Change. Morningstar Manager Research.
    • Bolton, P., and M. Kacperczyk. 2021. “Do Investors Care about Carbon Risk.” Journal of Financial Economics 142 (2): 517–549. doi:10.1016/j.jfineco.2021.05.008.
    • De Nard, G. 2022. “Oops! I Shrunk the Sample Covariance Matrix Again: Blockbuster Meets Shrinkage.” Journal of Financial Econometrics 20 (4): 569–611. doi:10.1093/jjfinec/nbaa020.
    • De Nard, G., R. F. Engle, O. Ledoit, and M. Wolf. 2022. “Large Dynamic Covariance Matrices: Enhancements Based on Intraday Data.” Journal of Banking & Finance 138: 106426. doi:10.1016/j.jbankfin.2022.106426.
    • De Nard, G., O. Ledoit, and M. Wolf. 2021. “Factor Models for Portfolio Selection in Large Dimensions: The Good, the Better and the Ugly.” Journal of Financial Econometrics 19 (2): 236–257. doi:10.1093/jjfinec/nby033.
    • De Nard, G., and Z. Zhao. 2023. “Using, Taming or Avoiding the Factor Zoo? A Double-Shrinkage Estimator for Covariance Matrices.” Journal of Empirical Finance 72: 23–35. doi:10.1016/j.jempfin.2023.02.003.
    • Engle, R. F. 2014. “A Financial Approach to Environmental Risk.” Resources for the Future, Featurette 187.
    • Engle, R. F., S. Giglio, B. Kelly, L. Heebum, and J. Stroebel. 2020. “Hedging Climate Change News.” The Review of Financial Studies 33 (3): 1184–1216. doi:10.1093/rfs/hhz072.
    • Engle, R. F., O. Ledoit, and M. Wolf. 2019. “Large Dynamic Covariance Matrices.” Journal of Business & Economic Statistics 37 (2): 363–375. doi:10.1080/07350015.2017.1345683.
    • Faccini, R., R. Matin, and G. Skiadopoulos. 2021. “Are Climate Change Risks Priced in the Us Stock Market?.” Danmarks Nationalbank, Working Paper No. 169.
    • Fama, E., and J. MacBeth. 1973. “Risk, Return, and Equilibrium: Empirical Tests.” Journal of Political Economy 81 (3): 607–636. doi:10.1086/260061.
    • Gentzkow, M., B. Bryan Kelly, and M. Taddy. 2019. “Text as Data.” Journal of Economic Literature 57 (3): 535–574. doi:10.1257/jel.20181020.
    • Huberman, G., and S. Kandel. 1987. “Mean-Variance Spanning.” Journal of Finance 42 (2): 873–888.
    • Jobson, J. D., and B. M. Korkie. 1980. “Estimation for Markowitz Efficient Portfolios.” Journal of the American Statistical Association 75 (371): 544–554. doi:10.2307/2287643.
    • Jurczenko, E., and J. Teiletche. 2019. “Macro Factor-Mimicking Portfolios.” Working Paper. doi:10.2139/ssrn.3363598.
    • Jurczenko, E., and J. Teiletche. 2022. “Hedging Climate Risks: A Cross-Asset Approach.” In Climate Investing: New Strategies and Implementation Challenges, edited by E. Jurczenko. Wiley-ISTE.
    • Lamont, O. 2001. “Economic Tracking Portfolios.” Journal of Econometrics 105 (1): 161–184. doi:10.1016/S0304-4076(01)00074-4.
    • Ledoit, O., and M. Wolf. 2008. “Robust Performance Hypothesis Testing with the Sharpe Ratio.” Journal of Empirical Finance 15 (5): 850–859. doi:10.1016/j.jempfin.2008.03.002.
    • Ledoit, O., and M. Wolf. 2011. “Robust Performance Hypothesis Testing with the Variance.” Wilmott Magazine 2011 (55): 86–89. doi:10.1002/wilm.10036.
    • Ledoit, O., and M. Wolf. 2017. “Nonlinear Shrinkage of the Covariance Matrix for Portfolio Selection: Markowitz Meets Goldilocks.” The Review of Financial Studies 30 (12): 4349–4388. doi:10.1093/rfs/hhx052.
    • Ledoit, O., and M. Wolf. 2020. “Analytical Nonlinear Shrinkage of Large-Dimensional Covariance Matrices.” Annals of Statistics 48: 3043–3065.
    • Ledoit, O., and M. Wolf. 2022. “The Power of (Non-)Linear Shrinking: A Review and Guide to Covariance Matrix Estimation.” Journal of Financial Econometrics 20 (1): 187–218. doi:10.1093/jjfinec/nbaa007.
    • Lehmann, B. N., and D. M. Modest. 1988. “The Empirical Foundations of the Arbitrage Pricing Theory.” Journal of Financial Economics 21 (2): 213–254. doi:10.1016/0304-405X(88)90061-X.
    • Markowitz, H. 1952. “Portfolio Selection.” The Journal of Finance 7 (1): 77–91. doi:10.2307/2975974.
    • Merton, R. C. 1987. “A Simple Model of Capital Market Equilibrium with Incomplete Information.” The Journal of Finance 42 (3): 483–510. doi:10.2307/2328367.
    • Michaud, R. 1989. “The Markowitz Optimization Enigma: Is Optimized Optimal?” Financial Analysts Journal 45 (1): 31–42. doi:10.2469/faj.v45.n1.31.
    • Pástor, Ľ., R. F. Stambaugh, and L. A. Taylor. 2021. “Sustainable Investing in Equilibrium.” Journal of Financial Economics 142 (2): 550–571. doi:10.1016/j.jfineco.2020.12.011.

    Appendix A.

    Additional Figures and Tables

    Figure A1. The WSJ Climate News Indices for General, Physical, and Transition Risk

    Figure A1. The WSJ Climate News Indices for General, Physical, and Transition Risk

    Figure A2. Top: The Fund Weights of the Climate-Efficient Factor-Mimicking Portfolios in Terms of the Scaling Parameter λ at the End of the Sample (01/29/2021); Middle: The Fund Weights of the CEP (λ=0.0022) over Time; Bottom: The Fund Weights of the Base Case over Time

    Figure A2. Top: The Fund Weights of the Climate-Efficient Factor-Mimicking Portfolios in Terms of the Scaling Parameter λ at the End of the Sample (01/29/2021); Middle: The Fund Weights of the CEP (λ=0.0022) over Time; Bottom: The Fund Weights of the Base Case over Time

    Figure A3. Top: The Sector Weights of the CEP (λ=0.0022); Bottom: The Sector Weights of the Base Case over Time

    Figure A3. Top: The Sector Weights of the CEP (λ=0.0022); Bottom: The Sector Weights of the Base Case over Time

    Table A1. (Daily) Pairwise Correlations between All NYT and WSJ Climate News Indices

    Table A2. Top 10 Funds of the CEP (λ=0.0022)

    Appendix B.

    Covariance Matrix Estimator

    The proposed covariance matrix estimator of asset returns is based on a static factor model structure, as explained in De Nard, Ledoit, and Wolf (Citation2021): (B.1) Σ̂r:=B̂Σ̂fB̂+Σ̂ϵ,(B.1) where B̂ is a K×N matrix whose ith column is the vector β̂i, Σf is the K×K covariance matrix of factors, and Σϵ is the N×N covariance matrix of residuals, assuming that, for every asset i=1,,N, (B.2) ri,t=α̂i+β̂iFactors+ϵ̂i,t.(B.2)

    An exact factor model (EFM) assumes in addition that Σϵ is a diagonal matrix. In contrast, an approximate factor model (AFM) only assumes that Σϵ is matrix with bounded L1 or L2 norm. De Nard, Ledoit, and Wolf (Citation2021) and De Nard and Zhao (Citation2023) show that the EFM assumption is too strict and suggest to use a nonlinear shrinkage estimator in conjunction with a multivariate GARCH model, namely the DCC-NL model of Engle, Ledoit, and Wolf (Citation2019). However, due to the small sample size, DCC and nonlinear shrinkage are suboptimal in this case. This is why we use the (linear) constant-variance-covariance (CVC) shrinkage estimator of De Nard (Citation2022) instead, which is known to perform well in this challenging and small-sample setting. The intuition of CVC is to shrink the sample variances si2 and sample covariances sij toward their grand mean: (B.3) Σ̂CVC*=δ̂*(s¯2I+s¯ijJ)+(1δ̂*)S,(B.3) where δ* is the optimal shrinkage intensity derived in De Nard (Citation2022), S is the sample covariance matrix, and J:=11I is the off-diagonal matrix.

    Note that we use CVC (EquationB.3) to estimate both Σf and Σϵ, following the suggestion and findings of De Nard and Zhao (Citation2023).

    Another modification of our covariance matrix estimator is that we use investable risk factors, as explained in “Selection of the Investment and Factor Universe” instead of (academic) Fama–French factors or latent/unobservable factors. Finally, we use adaptive least squares regressions to estimate (EquationB.2); see Beck, De Nard, and Wolf (Citation2023).