213
Views
0
CrossRef citations to date
0
Altmetric
Research Articles

A contribution to scientific studies of norms in economics inspired by JN Keynes and Popper

ORCID Icon
Pages 290-309 | Received 13 May 2022, Accepted 02 Oct 2023, Published online: 09 Oct 2023

References

  • Acton, H., & Watkins, J. (1963). Negative utilitarianism. Aristotelian Society Supplementary Volume, 37(1), 83–114. https://doi.org/10.1093/aristoteliansupp/37.1.83
  • Agassi, J. (1960). Methodological individualism. The British Journal of Sociology, 11(3), 244–270. https://doi.org/10.2307/586749
  • Agassi, J. (2009). Popper’s insights into the state of economics. In Z. Parusniková, & R. S. Cohen (Eds.), Rethinking popper (pp. 357–368). Springer Science.
  • Alexandrova, A. (2018). Can the science of well-being be objective? The British Journal for the Philosophy of Science, 69(2), 421–445. https://doi.org/10.1093/bjps/axw027
  • Arneson, R. (2000). Luck egalitarianism and prioritarianism. Ethics, 110(2), 339–349. https://doi.org/10.1086/233272
  • Arrow, K. J. (1951/2012). Social choice and individual values (3rd edition). Yale University Press.
  • Aslanbeigui, N. (1990). On the demise of pigovian economics. Southern Economic Journal, 56(3), 616–627. https://doi.org/10.2307/1059363
  • Backhouse, R. E. (Ed.). (1994). New directions in economic methodology. Routledge.
  • Backhouse, R. E. (2009). Friedman’s 1953 essay and the marginalist controversy. In U. Mäki (Ed.), The methodology of positive economics. Reflections on the milton friedman legacy (pp. 217–240). Cambridge University Press.
  • Backhouse, R. E., & Medema, S. G. (2009). Defining economics: The long road to acceptance of the Robbins definition. Economica, 76(s1), 805–820. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1468-0335.2009.00789.x
  • Badiei, S. (2021). Économie Positive et Économie Normative chez Marx, Mises, Friedman et Popper. Éditions Matériologiques.
  • Badiei, S., & Grivaux, A. (2022). The positive and the normative in economic thought: A historical-analytic appraisal. In S. Badiei, & A. Grivaux (Eds.), The positive and the normative in economic thought (pp. 1–24). Routledge.
  • Blaug, M. (1980/1992). The methodology of economics: Or How economists explain. Cambridge University Press.
  • Boylan, T. A., & O’Gorman, P. F. (Eds.). (2008). Popper and economic methodology: Contemporary challenges. Routledge.
  • Brand-Correa, L. I., Mattioli, G., Lamb, W. F., & Steinberger, J. K. (2020). Understanding (and tackling) need satisfier escalation. Sustainability: Science, Practice and Policy, 16(1), 309–325.
  • Bruni, L. (2002). Vilfredo pareto and the birth of modern microeconomics. Edward Elgar.
  • Büchs, M. (2021). Sustainable welfare: How do universal basic income and universal basic services compare? Ecological Economics, 189, 107152. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.ecolecon.2021.107152
  • Cairnes, J. E. (1857). The character and logical method of political economy. MacMillan.
  • Campagnolo, G. (2010). Criticisms of classical political economy. Menger, Austrian economics and the German historical school. Routledge.
  • Campagnolo, G., & Tosi, G. (2011). L’origine de la Monnaie Selon Menger. In G. Campagnolo (Ed.), Existe-t-il une Doctrine Menger? (pp. 203–237). PUP.
  • Cohen, J. (1997). Deliberation and democratic legitimacy. In J. Bohman, & W. Rehg (Eds.), Deliberative democracy: Essays on reason and politics (pp. 67–92). MIT Press.
  • Colander, D. (1992). Retrospectives: The lost art of economics. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 6(3), 191–198. https://doi.org/10.1257/jep.6.3.191
  • Colander, D., & Su, H. (2013). A failure to communicate: The fact-value divide and the putnam-dasgupta debate. Erasmus Journal for Philosophy and Economics, 6(2), 1–23. https://doi.org/10.23941/ejpe.v6i2.131
  • Colander, D., & Su, H. (2015). Making sense of economists’ positive-normative distinction. Journal of Economic Methodology, 22(2), 157–170. https://doi.org/10.1080/1350178X.2015.1024877
  • Colander, D., & Su, H. (2019). How economics should be done. Essays on the art and craft of economics. Edward Elgar.
  • Coote, A., & Percy, A. (2020). The case for universal basic services. Polity.
  • Dalton, H. (1920). The measurement of the inequality of incomes. The Economic Journal, 30(119), 348–361. https://doi.org/10.2307/2223525
  • Davis, J. (1990). Cooter and rappoport on the normative. Economics and Philosophy, 6(1), 139–146. https://doi.org/10.1017/S0266267100000687
  • Davis, J. (2003). The theory of the individual in economics. Identity and value. Routledge.
  • Davis, J. (2014). Economists’ odd stand on the positive-normative distinction: A behavioral economics view. In G. De Martino, & D. McCloskey (Eds.), Oxford university press handbook on professional economic ethics: Views from the economics profession and beyond (pp. 223–241). Oxford University Press.
  • Davis, J. (2022). Economics as a normative discipline: Value disentanglement in an ‘objective’ economics. In S. Badiei, & A. Grivaux (Eds.), The positive and the normative in economic thought (pp. 87–107). Routledge.
  • Deane, P. (2001). The life and times of JN Keynes: A beacon in the tempest. Edward Elgar.
  • De Marchi, N. (1992). Post-popperian methodology of economics: Recovering practice. Kluwer Academic Publishers.
  • Dockès, P. (1996). La Société N’est Pas Un Pique-nique. Economica.
  • Dodds, S. (1997). Towards a ‘science of sustainability’: Improving the way ecological economics understands human well-being. Ecological Economics, 23(2), 95–111. https://doi.org/10.1016/S0921-8009(97)00047-5
  • Doyal, L., & Gough, I. (1991). A theory of human need. Palgrave Macmillan.
  • Eidlin, F. (2005). Popper’s social-democratic politics and free-market liberalism. Critical Review, 17(1-2), 25–48. https://doi.org/10.1080/08913810508443626
  • Ferber, M. A., & Nelson, J. A. (Eds.). (1993). Beyond economic Man: Feminist theory and economics. University of Chicago Press.
  • Frazer, W. J., & Boland, L. A. (1983). An essay on the foundations of Friedman’s methodology. The American Economic Review, 73(1), 129–144.
  • Friedman, M. (1953). The methodology of positive economics. In M. Friedman (Ed.), Essays in positive economics (pp. 3–43). University of Chicago Press.
  • Gorton, W. (2006). Karl Popper and the social sciences. State University of NY Press.
  • Gough, I. (2015). Climate change and sustainable welfare: The centrality of human needs: Fig. 1. Cambridge Journal of Economics, 39(5), 1191–1214. https://doi.org/10.1093/cje/bev039
  • Gough, I. (2017). Heat, greed and human need: Climate change, capitalism and sustainable wellbeing. Edward Elgar.
  • Gough, I. (2019). Universal basic services: A theoretical and moral framework. The Political Quarterly, 90(3), 534–542. https://doi.org/10.1111/1467-923X.12706
  • Gough, I. (2020). The case for universal basic services. LSE Public Policy Review, 1(2), 6. https://doi.org/10.31389/lseppr.12
  • Habermas, J. (1975). Legitimation crisis. Beacon Press.
  • Hands, W. (2001). Reflection without rules. Economic methodology and contemporary science theory. Cambridge University Press.
  • Hands, W. (2009). Effective tension in robbins’ economic methodology. Economica, 76(s1), 831–844. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1468-0335.2009.00791.x
  • Hands, W. (2012). The positive–normative dichotomy and economics. In U. Mäki (Ed.), Philosophy of economics (pp. 219–239). Elsevier.
  • Hausman, D., McPherson, M., & Satz, D. (1996/2016). Economic analysis, moral philosophy, and public policy (3rd ed.). Cambridge University Press.
  • Hausman, D. M. (1992/2003). The inexact and separate science of economics. Cambridge University Press.
  • Howson, S. (2004). The origins of Lionel Robbins’s essay on the nature and significance of economic science. History of Political Economy, 36(3), 413–443. https://doi.org/10.1215/00182702-36-3-413
  • Hung, H., & Duggan, J. (2020). A formal theory of democratic deliberation. American Political Science Review, 114(1), 14–35. https://doi.org/10.1017/S0003055419000674
  • Hutchison, T. W. (1938/2003). The significance and basic postulates of economic theory. MacMillan and Co.
  • Hutchison, T. W. (1994/2003). The uses and abuses of economics. Routledge.
  • IGP (Institute for Global Prosperity). (2017). Social prosperity for the future: A proposal for universal basic services. UCL.
  • Jarvie, I., & Pralong, S. (Eds.). (1999/2002). Popper’s open society after fifty years. Routledge.
  • Keynes, J. N. (1891). The scope and method of political economy. MacMillan and Co.
  • Kicking the GDP Habit. (2020, January 16). Project syndicate. https://www.project-syndicate.org/onpoint/kicking-the-gdp-habit.
  • Lamb, W., & Steinberger, J. (2017). Human well-being and climate change mitigation. WIRES Climate Change, 8(6), e485. 1–16. https://doi.org/10.1002/wcc.485
  • Laudan, L. (1984). Science and values: The aims of science and their role in scientific debate. University of California Press.
  • Mäki, U. (2020). Notes on economics imperialism and norms of scientific inquiry. Revue de Philosophie Économique, 21(1), 95–127.
  • Małecka, M. (2020). The normative decision theory in economics: A philosophy of science perspective. The case of the expected utility theory. Journal of Economic Methodology, 27(1), 36–50.
  • Małecka, M. (2021). Values in economics: A recent revival with a twist. Journal of Economic Methodology, 28(1), 88–97. https://doi.org/10.1080/1350178X.2020.1868776
  • Małecka, M. (2022). Economics as value-laden science lessons from the philosophy of science on the normative/positive distinctions and rational choice theory. In S. Badiei, & A. Grivaux (Eds.), The positive and the normative in economic thought (pp. 214–230). Routledge.
  • Mayerfeld, J. (1996). The moral asymmetry of happiness and suffering. The Southern Journal of Philosophy, 34(3), 317–338. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.2041-6962.1996.tb00795.x
  • Mill, J. S. (1836/1967). On the definition of political economy and on the method of investigation proper to it. In J. M. Robson (Ed.), Collected works of John Stuart Mill, volume IV (essays on economics and society) (pp. 309–339). University of Toronto Press.
  • Mongin, P. (1999). Normes et Jugements de Valeur en Économie Normative. Social Science Information, 38(4), 521–553. https://doi.org/10.1177/053901899038004002
  • Mongin, P. (2002). Is there progress in normative economics? In S. Böhm, C. Gehrke, H. Kurz, & R. Sturn (Eds.), Is there progress in economics? Knowledge, truth and the history of economic thought (pp. 145–170). Routledge.
  • Mongin, P. (2006a). A concept of progress for normative economics. Economics and Philosophy, 22(1), 19–54. https://doi.org/10.1017/S0266267105000696
  • Mongin, P. (2006b). Value judgments and value neutrality in economics. Economica, 73(290), 257–286. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1468-0335.2006.00501.x
  • Mongin, P. (2012). Une Conception Néo-Poppérienne de l’Explication en Sciences Sociales et Ses Difficultés Internes. Dialogue (Los Angeles, Calif), 51(3), 503–515. https://doi.org/10.1017/S001221731300005X
  • Mongin, P. (2018). Les Origines de la Distinction entre Positif et Normatif en Économie. Revue philosophique de Louvain, 116, 151–186.
  • Muller, S. (2022). The unacknowledged normative content of randomized control trials in economics and its dangers. In S. Badiei, & A. Grivaux (Eds.), The positive and the normative in economic thought (pp. 167–189). Routledge.
  • Myrdal, G., & Streeten, P. (1958). Value in social theory. Routledge.
  • Nelson, J. A. (1993). The study of choice or the study of provisioning? Gender and the definition of economics. In M. A. Ferber, & J. A. Nelson (Eds.), Beyond economic man: Feminist theory and economics (pp. 23–36). University of Chicago Press.
  • Nelson, J. A. (1996/2003). Feminism, objectivity and economics. Routledge.
  • Notturno, M. A. (2015). Hayek and popper: On rationality, economism, and democracy. Routledge.
  • Nussbaum, M. C. (1992). Human functioning and social justice. Political Theory, 20(2), 202–246. https://doi.org/10.1177/0090591792020002002
  • Nussbaum, M. C. (2011). Creating capabilities: The human development approach. Harvard University Press.
  • O’Gorman, P. F. (2008). Situational analysis and popper’s three world thesis: The quest for understanding. In T. A. Boylan, & P. F. O’Gorman (Eds.), Popper and Economic Methodology: Contemporary Challenges (pp. 33–57). Routledge.
  • Palacio-Vera, A. (2019). ‘Situational analysis’ and economics: An attempt at clarification. Economics and Philosophy, 35(3), 479–498. https://doi.org/10.1017/S0266267118000330
  • Pareto, V. (2014). Manual of political economy. A critical and variorum edition. Oxford University Press.
  • Parfit, D. (1997). Equality and priority. Ratio, 10(3), 202–221. https://doi.org/10.1111/1467-9329.00041
  • Parfit, D. (2012). Another defence of the priority view. Utilitas, 24(3), 399–440. https://doi.org/10.1017/S095382081200009X
  • Pigou, A. (1912). Wealth and welfare. Macmillan.
  • Pigou, A. (1920). The economics of welfare. Macmillan.
  • Polanyi, K. (1977). The livelihood of Man. Academic Press.
  • Popper, K. (1945/2013). The open society and its enemies. Princeton University Press.
  • Popper, K. (1974/2005). Unended quest: An intellectual autobiography. Open Court.
  • Popper, K. (1976). The logic of the social sciences. In G. Adey & D. Frisby (Eds.), The positivist dispute in German sociology (pp. 87–104). Heinemann.
  • Popper, K. (1994). Models, instruments, and truth: The status of the rationality principle in the social sciences. In M. Notturno, & K. Popper (Eds.), The myth of the framework (pp. 154–184). Routledge.
  • Popper, K. (2012). After The open society. Routledge Classics.
  • Putnam, H. (2002). The collapse of the fact/value distinction. Harvard University Press.
  • Putnam, H. (2003). For ethics and economics without the dichotomies. Review of Political Economy, 15(3), 395–412. https://doi.org/10.1080/09538250308432
  • Putnam, H., & Walsh, V. (Eds.). (2012). The End of value-free economics. Routledge.
  • Reinert, K. (2011). No small hope: The basic goods imperative. Review of Social Economy, 69(1), 55–76. https://doi.org/10.1080/00346760802714875
  • Reiss, J. (2017). Fact-Value entanglement in positive economics. Journal of Economic Methodology, 24(2), 134–149. https://doi.org/10.1080/1350178X.2017.1309749
  • Robbins, L. (1932). An essay on the nature and significance of economic science. Macmillan.
  • Robbins, L. (1938). Interpersonal comparisons of utility: A comment. The Economic Journal, 48(192), 635–641. https://doi.org/10.2307/2225051
  • Robbins, L. (1976). Political economy, past and present: A review of leading theories of economic policy. Columbia University Press.
  • Robbins, L. (1981). Economics and political economy. American Economic Review, 71(2), 1–10.
  • Rosenberg, A. (1994/2004). What is the cognitive status of economic theories? In R. E. Backhouse (Ed.), New directions in economic methodology (pp. 218–236). Routledge.
  • Sassower, R. (2006). Popper’s legacy: Rethinking politics, economics and science. Acumen.
  • Scarantino, A. (2009). On the role of values in economic science: Robbins and his critics. Journal of the History of Economic Thought, 31(4), 449–473. https://doi.org/10.1017/S1053837209990253
  • Sen, A. K. (1979). Personal utilities and public judgements: Or what’s wrong with welfare economics. The Economic Journal, 89(355), 537–558. https://doi.org/10.2307/2231867
  • Sen, A. K. (1983). Poor, relatively speaking. Oxford Economic Papers, 35(2), 153–169. https://doi.org/10.1093/oxfordjournals.oep.a041587
  • Sen, A. K. (1987). The standard of living. Cambridge University Press.
  • Sen, A. K. (1992). Inequality reexamined. Clarendon Press.
  • Senior, N. W. (1852). Four introductory lectures on political economy. Longman, Brown, Green, and Longmans.
  • Shearmur, J. (1996). The political thought of Karl Popper. Routledge.
  • Sidgwick, H. (1885). The principles of political economy. MacMillan & Co.
  • Smart, R. N. (1958). Negative utilitarianism. Mind; A Quarterly Review of Psychology and Philosophy, LXVII(268), 542–543. https://doi.org/10.1093/mind/LXVII.268.542
  • Su, H. (2012). Beyond the positive–normative dichotomy: Some remarks on Colander’s lost art of economics. Journal of Economic Methodology, 19(4), 375–390. https://doi.org/10.1080/1350178X.2012.741690
  • Temkin, L. (2003). Equality, priority or what? Economics and Philosophy, 19(1), 61–87. https://doi.org/10.1017/S0266267103001020
  • Thaler, R. (2015). Misbehaving: The making of behavioral economics. WW Norton Company.
  • The Quarterly Journal of Economics. (1886). Wagner on the present state of political economy. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 1(1), 113–133.
  • The Trouble with GDP. (2016, April 30). The Economist. https://www.economist.com/briefing/2016/04/30/the-trouble-with-gdp.
  • Vogel, J., Steinberger, J. K., O’Neill, D. W., Lamb, W. F., & Krishnakumar, J. (2021). Socio–economic conditions for satisfying human needs at low energy use: An international analysis of social provisioning. Global Environmental Change, 69, 102287. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.gloenvcha.2021.102287
  • Walras, L. (1874/1926). Éléments d’Économie Politique Pure ou Théorie de la Richesse Sociale. Raymond Durand-Auzias et Robert Pichon.
  • Walras, L. (1896). Études d’Économie Sociale (Théorie de la Réparation de la Richesse Sociale). F. Rouge and F. Pichon.
  • Wasserman, J. (2019). The marginal revolutionaries: How Austrian economists fought the War of ideas. Yale University Press.
  • Williams, B. (1985). Ethics and the limits of philosophy. Fontana Press.

Reprints and Corporate Permissions

Please note: Selecting permissions does not provide access to the full text of the article, please see our help page How do I view content?

To request a reprint or corporate permissions for this article, please click on the relevant link below:

Academic Permissions

Please note: Selecting permissions does not provide access to the full text of the article, please see our help page How do I view content?

Obtain permissions instantly via Rightslink by clicking on the button below:

If you are unable to obtain permissions via Rightslink, please complete and submit this Permissions form. For more information, please visit our Permissions help page.