3,378
Views
230
CrossRef citations to date
0
Altmetric
Original Articles

The J-Curve: a literature review

Pages 1377-1398 | Published online: 02 Feb 2007
 

Abstract

Due to lag structure, currency devaluation is said to worsen the trade balance first and improve it later resulting in a pattern that resemble the letter J, hence the J-Curve phenomenon. Since its introduction by Magee in Citation1973 (Brooking Papers on Economic Activity, 1, pp. 303–25), a large number of studies have attempted to test the phenomenon using different techniques and different model specifications. The results are at best ambiguous and deserve to be collected together for the future generation of researchers and graduate students. This paper fills such a vacuum in the literature by reviewing the J-Curve related empirical papers.

Acknowledgements

We are grateful for valuable comments of an anonymous referee. However, we alone are responsible for any error.

Notes

According to the absorption approach, devaluation, through its impact on the terms of trade and domestic production, leads to a switch in spending from foreign to domestic goods, and hence, an improvement in the trade balance. Monetarists, in contrast, argue that devaluation reduces the real value of cash balances and/or changes the relative price of traded and non-traded goods, and thus improves the trade balance as well as the balance of payments.

For recent estimate of the ML condition see Rose (Citation1990) and Bahmani-Oskooee and Niroomand (Citation1998).

Intertemporal models imply that there are asymmetries between the current account effects of temporary changes in export and import prices. For example, Chen and Devereux (Citation1994) show that for temporary import price changes, income and substitution effects work in opposite directions while for temporary export price changes, they reinforce. However, many authors often ignore these asymmetries and interpret devaluation as a simple deterioration in a country's terms of trade.

Froot and Klemperer (Citation1989) investigate the pass-through from exchange rates to import prices when firms’ future demands depend on current market shares. They stress that the return a foreign firm expects to earn on its current investment in market share is sensitive to the excepted future exchange rate, and therefore, determines the aggressiveness of their ‘pricing-to market’ behaviour.

Gerlach (Citation1989) investigates the implications of varying degrees of nominal price flexibilities (or rigidities) for the post-devaluation time-path of trade balance. He makes a distinction between higher prices (relative price effect) and rising prices (inter-temporal price effect). While the currently higher domestic currency prices of tradables tend to discourage imports and therefore improves the trade balance, rising domestic prices of tradables encourages agents to prepone their purchases, which tends to worsen the trade balance. If the latter effect dominates, the J-curve results.

Bacchetta and Gerlach (1994) show that a rapid pass-through of exchange rate changes to import prices is not necessary for J-Curves to arise. If import prices are sticky, consumers anticipate future import prices to rise after a devaluation and therefore reallocate their purchases over time. Thus, J-curves can also arise if imported goods are durable and import prices adjust slowly to exchange rate changes and quantities are adjusting freely.

Indeed, using quarterly data from 1973–1985, Bahmani-Oskooee (Citation1989b) finds evidence of a W-Curve for the US current account. Subsequent to depreciation of the dollar, the current account deteriorates for two quarters and then starts improving for five quarters, again deteriorates, and finally improves.

For the price-elasticity of market shares, proportionate changes in market shares are related to proportionate changes in relative export prices; for the price-elasticity of exports, proportionate deviations of exports from a standard set by previously attained market shares are related to proportionate changes in export prices (for a given size of export markets).

Calculations made in volume terms generally confirm those in value terms: Almost 50% of the full effect appears to be realized within the first three years, and about 90% during the first five years.

For theoretical papers see Levin (Citation1983), Gerlach (Citation1989), Kapur (Citation1989) and Krugman (Citation1989).

Sundararajan and Bhole (Citation1988) reinforce Miles’ finding that devaluation improves the balance of payments of India. Their sample covers the period 1960–1961 to 1984–1985.

If the French trade balance improves and the UK trade balance deteriorates by the same amount following a French and British devaluation, then the French devaluation should be judged successful and the UK unsuccessful.

His sample includes Costa Rica, Ecuador, Finland, France, Iceland, Israel, Philippines, Spain, Sri Lanka and UK. The data are comparable to the data used by Miles.

Karadeloglou (Citation1990) finds evidence of an inverse J-Curve for Greek balance of payments.

Their structural equations include demand for and supply of petroleum and non-petroleum exports and imports, changes in reserves, demand for and supply of money (real balances), and output.

Of the 41 countries, they could apply the cointegration technique to only 20 countries for which both the variables were found to be I (1).

The assumptions are: (i) import prices rise immediately, (ii) export prices remain stable, (iii) import volumes begin to decline after some lags, and (iv) export volumes begin to increase, again, after some lags.

The USA may be a special case: trade in primary products and capital assets is typically denominated in major vehicle currencies, such as the US dollar. This delays (or at least weakens) the underlying pass-through. Moreover, foreign exporters may cut profit margins to maintain their market shares in the USA. Also, invoicing and contracting practices themselves may delay an initially perverse J-Curve response in the US case.

Husted (Citation1992) estimates the cointegrating regressions between several measures of US exports and imports and shows that (a) up to about the end of 1983, the US current account tended towards zero; and (b) since 1983, there has been an apparent structural shift in the relationship between the trade flows, resulting in a long run tendency for a deficit in excess of $100 billion.

For example, Rosensweig and Koch (Citation1988) advocated a delayed J-Curve for the USA.

Together these three sectors accounted for about 80% of the volume of nonagricultural exports and about 70% of the volume of non-oil imports in 1987.

While Arndt and Dorrance (Citation1987) thought a J-Curve effect played a role in widening the Australian current account deficit, they also emphasized the importance of long-run import and demand elasticities, competitiveness of Australian tradables, changes in terms of trade, and domestic spending.

See Stern (1973) for the effects of devaluation on the terms of trade and the elasticities conditions.

The J-Curve emerges after a passage of two quarters.

This ratio is unit-free and measures the trade balance in real and nominal terms.

A current account deficit reflects a shortfall between domestic savings and investment. For Australia, Alesina et al. (Citation1991) argue that the link between fiscal consolidation and a smaller current account deficit was severed by a surge in private sector investment – a substantial real depreciation of the Australian dollar would facilitate allocation of this investment between the traded and non-traded sector such as to stabilize the current account. Using vector error correction modelling (VECM) on US data covering the period 1960Q1 to 1994Q4, Dibooglu (Citation1997) demonstrate that macroeconomic variables account for the variation in the current account reasonably well, and the budget surplus, terms of trade, and real interest rates seem to explain a sizable proportion of the variation in current account. Dibooglu's results differ from those of Boucher (Citation1991) for the USA (1974Q1–1988Q2), and Fry (Citation1991) for Korea (1961–1989).

It is assumed that each country faces an infinitely elastic supply of imports.

See Shiells (1985) for details on the estimation of gamma distributed lag functions.

TB t  = exports/imports, M t  = real domestic money supply, MW t  = world money supply in real terms, Y t  = domestic real output, YW t  = world real output, P t  = domestic price level, PW t  = world price level, and E t  = effective exchange rate.

Note that Bahmani-Oskooee (Citation1985) studies the impact of real effective exchange rates on the real trade balance defined as excess of exports over imports (measured in domestic currency) whereas Himarios (Citation1985) measures the trade balance in terms of the US dollar and studies the impact of the nominal bilateral exchange rate on the trade balances.

Except for Egypt, the long-run results of Bahmani-Oskooee and Malixi (Citation1992) and Himarios (Citation1989) do not match.

Consistent with the requirements of a VAR model, they use stationary data.

Koray (1990) analyses the co-movements of the exchange rate and the trade balance within a static two-country equilibrium model of the world economy. He shows that the trade balance may improve or deteriorate in response to a depreciating exchange rate, depending on the relative importance of disturbances caused by domestic and foreign monetary and fiscal policies. The correlation between the exchange rate and the trade balance is determinate once the source of disturbance is specified – some disturbances lead to a negative correlation whereas others cause a positive correlation between the exchange rate and the trade balance. However, he does not investigate the dynamic response of the exchange rate and the trade balance in response to these disturbances.

The sample consists Austria (1964Q1–1990Q1), Canada (1955Q1–1990Q1), Finland (1975Q1–1990Q1), France (1970Q1–1990Q1), Germany (1968Q1–1990Q1), Italy (1970Q1–1990Q1), Japan (1955Q1–1990Q1), Switzerland (1970Q1–1990Q1), United Kingdom (1955Q1–1990Q1) and the United States (1950Q1–1990Q1).

Named after three authors (Harberger, Laursen and Metzler) who derived this negative correlation in a Keynesian framework.

He includes Brazil, Central African Rep., Chile, Cote d’ Ivoire, Cameroon, Congo, Costa Rica, Ecuador, Gabon, Ghana, Greece, Guatemala, Guyana, Hong Kong, Indonesia, Israel, Kenya, Korea, Sri Lanka, Morocco, Mauritius, Malaysia, Nigeria, Peru, Philippines, Papua New Guinea, Portugal, Senegal, Singapore, Somalia, Thailand, Trinidad and Tobago, Tunisia, South Africa and Zambia.

See also Bahmani–Oskooee and Brooks (1999).

Note that it is only a partial equilibrium analysis. In a full general equilibrium model, the variables REX, Y, and Y* are all endogenous.

The current and four lags of both foreign and domestic income are included in all the regressions. Four alternatives are considered for the real exchange rate: including only the current rate, the current and four lags of the rate, current plus eight lags, and current plus 12 lags. The error term is modelled as both white noise and a MA(4) process.

Applying OLS estimation yields some evidence of long exchange rate lags in the German equation, strong evidence of significant exchange rate lags for Italy, and insignificant lags for the other four US trading partners. When aggregate data is used, the choice of estimation technique significantly affects the results: OLS estimates provide weak support for J-Curve; IV estimation confirms the negative findings from bilateral data. Of course, when the regressions are run with data in levels rather than first differences, evidence of significant effects of exchange rates on trade is found in the German, Italian, British and Japanese equations. However, this practice is inappropriate as it yields ‘spurious results’ in the Granger-Newbold sense.

Rosenweig and Koch (Citation1988) check for some of these using aggregate US data, and advocate the concept of the delayed J-Curve.

Except for Italy, all the G-7 countries are included.

They construct instruments for current GNP and unlagged export price; the lag structure is chosen according to both Akaike and Schwartz Information Criteria.

The average adjustment period

.

The S-Curve describes the lead and lag correlation between terms of trade and net exports.

As a robustness check, they also add domestic and foreign money supplies to the right hand side and find no qualitative change in the end results.

Italy is an exception in that the impact of devaluation on the trade balance is significant over the 24 month period but not in the long run (longer than 24 months). Devaluation of the lira may cause domestic prices to rise, and thereby, reverse the long favourable impact of devaluation on the trade balance.

Normally, imports increase as a country's income rises. However, if this rise in income is due to increased production of import-substitutes, then the country would import less, and experience an improvement in the trade balance.

They study US bilateral trade with Canada, France, Germany, Italy, Japan and the UK.

Carter and Pick (Citation1989) and Doroodian and Chulho (Citation1989) are a couple of other studies that have looked at exchange rate sensitivity of the US agriculture trade.

Reprints and Corporate Permissions

Please note: Selecting permissions does not provide access to the full text of the article, please see our help page How do I view content?

To request a reprint or corporate permissions for this article, please click on the relevant link below:

Academic Permissions

Please note: Selecting permissions does not provide access to the full text of the article, please see our help page How do I view content?

Obtain permissions instantly via Rightslink by clicking on the button below:

If you are unable to obtain permissions via Rightslink, please complete and submit this Permissions form. For more information, please visit our Permissions help page.