3,143
Views
27
CrossRef citations to date
0
Altmetric
Original Articles

Formation of Foreign Direct Investment Clustering–A New Path to Local Economic Development? The Case of Qingdao

&
Pages 265-280 | Received 01 Nov 2005, Published online: 11 Mar 2008

Abstract

Jun Yeup Kim and Le-Yin Zhang Formation of foreign direct investment clustering – a new path to local economic development? The case of Qingdao, Regional Studies. This paper investigates the clustering of Chinese electronics manufacturers, large and small, alongside established foreign producers in Qingdao, North China. It examines how the supplier–buyer linkages between foreign invested enterprises (FIEs) and local firms have driven the development of a successful electronic industry cluster around development zones established by the local authority, underpinning the success of the large domestic firms both at home and abroad. It also analyses how FIEs' collaboration with local firms fosters local economic development in Qingdao. By integrating the theoretical perspectives of the hub-and-spoke model from economic geography and flagship-and-five partner's model in the science of strategic management, it develops its own theoretical lens to investigate the inter-firm network between the FIEs and local firms. The secret of the success of the Chinese electronic producers lies in their ability to drive, rather than being subordinate to, this network.

Jun Yeup Kim et Le-YIN Zhang L'agglomération de l'IDE – un nouveau sentier à suivre vers le développement économique local? Etude de cas de Qingdao, Regional Studies. Cet article cherche à examiner l'agglomération des entreprises industrielles électroniques en Chine, à la fois grandes et petites, à côté des constructeurs étrangers établis à Qingdao, en Chine du Nord. On examine comment le rapport fournisseur-acheteur entre les entreprises à capital étranger et les entreprises locales a conduit l'agglomération réussie d'entreprises industrielles électroniques autour des zones de développement délimitées par l'administration locale, étayant le succès des grandes entreprises nationales, à la fois dans le pays et à l'étranger. On analyse aussi comment la collaboration des entreprises à capital étranger avec les entreprises locales encourage le développement économique local à Qingdao. En intégrant les perspectives théoriques du modèle ‘moyeu-rayon’ de la géographie économique et celles du modèle ‘vedette-cinq partenaires’ de la science de la gestion stratégique, on développe un objectif théorique par lequel on peut examiner le réseau interentreprise d'entreprises à capital étranger et locales. La réussite de l'industrie électronique chinoise réside dans sa capacité à conduire le réseau plutôt que d'en être la subalterne.

Investissement direct étranger Agglomération industrielle Rapport acheteur-fournisseur Chine Industrie électronique

Jun Yeup Kim und Le-Yin Zhang Clusterbildung bei ausländischen Direktinvestitionen – ein neuer Pfad zur lokalen Wirtschaftsentwicklung? Der Fall Qingdao, Regional Studies. In diesem Beitrag wird die Clusterbildung unter den großen und kleinen Elektronikherstellern Chinas sowie den etablierten ausländischen Produzenten im nordchinesischen Qingdao untersucht. Wir analysieren, wie die Lieferanten-Käufer-Verknüpfungen zwischen Unternehmen mit Auslandsinvestitionen und einheimischen Firmen in der Umgebung der von den örtlichen Behörden eingerichteten Entwicklungszonen zur Entwicklung eines erfolgreichen Elektronikindustrie-Clusters geführt haben, was den Erfolg der großen einheimischen Firmen sowohl zu Hause als auch im Ausland gestärkt hat. Ebenso untersuchen wir, wie die Zusammenarbeit zwischen den Unternehmen mit Auslandsinvestitionen und den einheimischen Firmen die lokale Wirtschaftsentwicklung in Qingdao gefördert hat. Durch eine Integration der theoretischen Perspektiven eines Naben- und Speichenmodells aus der Wirtschaftsgeografie und eines ‘Flagship-and-Five-Partner’-Modells in der Wissenschaft des strategischen Managements entwickeln wir unser eigenes theoretisches Objektiv zur Untersuchung des Netzwerks zwischen Unternehmen mit Auslandsinvestitionen und einheimischen Firmen. Das Erfolgsgeheimnis der chinesischen Elektronikproduzenzten liegt in ihrer Fähigkeit, dieses Netzwerk anzutreiben statt sich ihm unterzuordnen.

Ausländische Direktinvestitionen Industrie-Cluster Käufer-Lieferanten-Verknüpfungen China Elektronikindustrie

Jun Yeup Kim y Le-Yin Zhang Formación de aglomeraciones de las EIE. Una nueva ruta hacia el desarrollo económico local? El caso de Qingdao, Regional Studies. En este ensayo investigamos las aglomeraciones de empresas electrónicas chinas, pequeñas y grandes, y de los productores extranjeros establecidos en Qingdao, al norte de China. Examinamos cómo los vínculos de suministradores-compradores entre empresas de inversión extranjera (EIE) y las sociedades locales han impulsado el desarrollo de una aglomeración de prósperas industrias electrónicas en zonas de desarrollo establecidas por la autoridad local, respaldando el éxito de grandes empresas nacionales tanto en el país como en el extranjero. También analizamos en qué medida la colaboración de las EIE con empresas locales fomenta el desarrollo económico local en Qingdao. Al integrar las perspectivas teóricas del modelo hub-and-spoke (nodo y derivación) de la geografía económica y el modelo de insignia y cinco socios en la ciencia de la gestión estratégica, desarrollamos nuestro propio objetivo teórico para investigar la red empresarial entre las EIE y las empresas locales. El secreto del éxito en los productores electrónicos en China radica en su capacidad para dirigir esta red más que ser subordinados por ella.

Inversión directa extranjera Aglomeración industrial Vínculos de suministradores-compradores China Industria electrónica

INTRODUCTION

The fact that inflows of foreign direct investment (FDI) into less developed countries (LDCs) are unevenly distributed, often concentrated in urban centres and more developed areas, has been a matter of considerable concern to the scholarly world. However, such a pattern may have perfectly logical explanations, not only by the reason that host governments often set up specially designated zones to attract FDI, but also that necessary conditions, such as infrastructure, required by FDI is confined to urban areas in the host countries. Moreover, there is some evidence that geographical concentration of FDI may represent a more powerful development catalyst than dispersed one (Fromhold-Eisebith, Citation2002; Thompson Citation2002; Zhou and Tong, Citation2003; Zhou, Citation2005). The purpose of this paper is to explore further the relationship between FDI, industrial clusters and local economic development by seeking to cross-link the FDI and clusters literature. It draws insights from a case study of China's most successful electronics cluster in Qingdao (formerly Tsingtao).

China's FDI inflows surpassed those of the USA in 2002 for the first time, making the People's Republic the world's largest recipient of FDI, with manufacturing sectors receiving a lion's share (69.4%) (CHINA STATISTICAL YEARBOOK, Citation2003). Meanwhile, in 2003, China manufactured more than 30% of the world's household electronics goods. In 2004, China produced electronics goods valued at US$296 billion, making it the second largest electronic producer in the world (Lee, Citation2005). Interestingly, however, the relationship between FDI inflows and China's success in the international electronics market is not a simple one. While foreign-invested enterprises (FIEs) account for almost 70% of China's electronic exports, they are not among the largest and most successful household appliance producers and exporters from China. Indeed, that dominant position is occupied by several large Chinese firms, notably Haier from Qingdao and TCL from Guangdong. Qingdao, the home city of Haier, has become a magnet for other important indigenous local electronic producers, such as Hisense and Aucma, as well as a large collection of specialized FIE. In 2001, with a world market share of 5.3%, Haier ranked second in the global refrigerator production industry (PEOPLE'S DAILY, Citation2002).

These features immediately raise several interesting questions: How does FDI affect the success of Chinese electronic enterprises? Why is Qingdao a magnet for electronic producers? What effect does this have on the overseas competitiveness of the Chinese producers? And what is in turn the impact of the latter on the local economy? These are obviously significant questions in their own right, especially because China's phenomenal economic growth in the past quarter of a century is to a large extent propelled by the growth of exports. However, this paper is principally interested in exploring the underlying theoretical issues and empirical evidence at the clustering of FDI.

In theoretical terms, the existing literature on FDI, while recognizing the potential benefits in terms of the inflow of capital and managerial know-how, transfer of technology, marketing expertise and market links, places considerable emphasis on FDI's potentially adverse effect on the domestic market structure, primarily because it is thought that, given their ownership-specific advantages and their size, transnational corporations (TNCs) are likely to dominate the market and hinder competition by exercising their market power although initially they may enhance competition (UNCTAD Citation1995, Citation1997). The question as to whether FIEs are capable of playing a dynamic role in developing local industry is rarely addressed. In the meantime, in development practice, attracting inward FDI constitutes one of the most important development strategies at the local level (Friedmann, Citation2002).

Existing studies have established that most of the positive effects of inward FDI are transmitted through inter-firm linkages, especially through supplier–buyer relationship between local firms and FIEs (Lall, Citation1980; Pacec, Citation1995; Yeung and Li, Citation2000; Tong and Wang, Citation2000; Wang and Tong, Citation2002; Crone and Roper, Citation2001; Dicken, Citation2003). Moreover, the quality and the dynamic nature of the linkages is the key to the extent of the impact. Turok Citation(1993) identifies two different types of linkage structure: development structure and dependency structure. In the former, FIEs share information and technology with local firms, strengthening a sustainable partnership. In the later, by contrast, the main purpose of FDI is to minimize the production costs by exploiting local resources, most notably labour, and therefore information and technology sharing is limited. Apparently then, the crucial question is under what conditions the more desired structure would develop. The case of Qingdao that is examined below may shed useful light on this.

It is further noted that inter-firm relationship is also addressed in the literature from the different perspectives of industrial clusters (Best, Citation1990; Markusen, Citation1996), flagship and five partners model (Rugman and D'Cruz, Citation2000) and global value chains (Bair and Gereffi, Citation2001; Humphrey and Schmitz, Citation2000; Humphrey and Schmitz, Citation2002; Schmitz, Citation2004).

Thompson Citation(2002) argued that the intra- and inter-industry spillover from FIEs into local economies are similar to mechanisms of knowledge and technology transfer identified in the literatures of industrial cluster and development studies. Hence, FIEs' engagement in the local economy can be conceptualized as contributing to industrial clustering, especially through the transfer of knowledge.

However, the literature on clusters generally focuses on the local sources of competitiveness coming from intra-cluster vertical and horizontal relationships, neglecting the potential of firms' networking from outside (Schmitz, Citation1995, Citation2004). In other words, while existing studies on cluster do acknowledge the significance of external linkages, it has been weakly theorized (Humphrey and Schmitz, Citation2002). Nevertheless, recent literature examines in much depth clusters' global linkages and how they affect local relationships (Schmitz, Citation2004). More specifically, Humphrey and Schmitz Citation(2004a) have explained how and why global value chains are governed. They recognize that lead firms, notably global buyers, play an important role in setting and coordinating the parameters under which other firms in the chain operate. Schmitz (Citation2004, p. 3) presents that ‘developing country clusters tend to work to specifications that come from outside’. Schmitz Citation(2004) hypothesizes that the upgrading opportunities of local producers vary with the type of value chain governance. Humphrey and Schmitz Citation(2004b) also emphasize that effective local upgrading strategies build on strong local and global linkages. The network-based chains can help local enterprises to reposition themselves in the global economy.

However, local producers in developing countries rarely find themselves in such chain. Moreover, much of this new literature on clusters focuses on ties with foreign buyers, rather than the interaction between FIEs and local firms. This is evident in both the conceptual works and empirical studies (Bair and Gereffi, Citation2001; Schmitz, Citation2004). There are however partial exceptions. For instance, Altenburg and Meyer-Stamer (Citation1999) identify a Weberian ideal type of cluster composed mainly of TNCs' subsidiaries in Latin America, but find that local firms, as suppliers, were weakly integrated into such clusters because of their lack of technological capacity. Similarly, Lowe and Kenney (1999) confirmed the importance of external linkages between foreign and local firms by investigating why inflows of FDI into the Mexican consumer electronics industry led to the decline of the industry. They argued that weak local and foreign ties were the main reason. Nevertheless, the above examples also point to another weakness of the existing works, namely that local firms are invariably placed in a subordinate and dependent position.

In this paper, with a case study of electronic industry in Qingdao, China, a hither-unexplored scenario is identified in which FIEs' collaboration with local firms, both large and small, actively fosters the development of the local industrial cluster. The essence of the case is that foreign firms do not constitute the core of the cluster, but have made a critical contribution to the development of the cluster by introducing new and more open forms of industrial organization and technological development. More specifically, FIEs act as suppliers to large local firms and buyers for local small firms, thus playing a bridging role in the otherwise fragmented local market precisely because of their firm-specific advantages and their sizes. Moreover, this linkage directly strengthened the competitiveness of large domestic firms both at home and abroad.

This paper is structured as follows. In section two, in order to facilitate the investigation as described above, clusters and global linkages are first conceptualized. The study also attempts to re-examine the scope for infusion between the clusters and FDI literatures. It then develops an analytical framework below by combining the ‘hub-and-spoke’ model in the perspective of economic geography literatures and the ‘flagship and five partners’ model in the international strategic management. This enables the paper to test the hypothesis that, in the context of a large domestic market and extant industrial and organizational capacity, local firms in developing countries can turn FIEs into suppliers and develop independent strength on that basis. Section three briefly describes the electronic industry in Qingdao. Section four presents the main research findings. Section five concludes.

LITERATURE REVIEW AND CONCEPTUAL DEVELOPMENT

The key research question for this study is how the geographical concentration of FIEs could contribute to local industry clusters, and, as a result, to local economic development. Two bodies of literature are relevant. The first is the literature on industry clusters and factors that affect their performance and upgrading. The second is the literature on FDI and its impact on the host economy. These are reviewed below in turn.

Extending the perspective of clusters and global value chains

As stated earlier, the inter-firm relationship between local and foreign firms, which defines the nature of FDI's impact on the local industry, has not been adequately addressed in the extant works. It is therefore necessary to develop an analytical framework that places this relationship at the centre. In doing so, the paper integrates relevant concepts from mainstream literature on economic geography, international business and development economics. This conceptual framework is able to account for two key dimensions: the geographical concentration of specialized firms; the direction of the relationship between foreign firms and local firms.

Conceptualizing cluster and global linkages

The conceptual background of cluster can be traced back to Alfred Marshall's observation of industrial districts in the UK. According to Marshall Citation(1920), the advantages of agglomeration are rooted in the reduced costs that arise from the operation of three sets of ‘localization economies’: first, the growth of various intermediate and subsidiary industries which provide specialized local input; second, the development of a pool of skilled labour; and third, the establishment of dedicated infrastructure and resource (Cumber and Mackinnon, Citation2004). A cluster is defined as ‘a group of geographically concentrated firms specializing along the lines between similar and complementary activities and developing greater skills and productive knowledge’ (Best, Citation1990, p. 233).

More specifically, three types of clusters, namely horizontal clusters, vertical clusters and emerging clusters, have been distinguished. While horizontal clusters are characterized by a common resource base (e.g., skilled labour or infrastructure), the classic, vertical clusters displays considerable evidence of supplier-buyer linkages. So-called emerging clusters may demonstrate wide scope for vertical and horizontal linkages, but not currently well established (Held, Citation1996).

According to Schmitz Citation(1995), the concept of industrial district gained new analytical life when Becattini Citation(1990) used it to make sense of the successful performance of local firms in Tuscany, Emilia-Romagna and nearby regions in what has come to be called the ‘Third Italy’. Becattini went beyond Marshall's economic analysis, however, and stressed the need for an interdisciplinary approach. He defined the industrial district as a ‘socio- territorial entity which is characterized by the presence of both a community of people and a population of firms’ and he adds that ‘in the district, unlike in other environments … community and firms tend to merge’ (Becattini, Citation1990, p. 38). In the ensuing international debate, the stylized model of the Third Italy has become the main reference point. The main components of this model are: geographical and sectoral concentration of predominantly small- and medium-sized enterprises; vertical disintegration at the firm level; cooperative competition; a socio-cultural identity which facilitates trust; active self-help organizations (Schmitz, Citation1995, p. 10).

A special issue of World Development (Schmitz and Nadvi, Citation1999) was devoted to the topic of industrial clusters in developing countries. One of the most crucial findings is the need to explore linkages external to the cluster. Subsequent work on clusters, particularly in developing countries, has concentrated on exploring the way in which firms in clusters are linked to external actors and its impact on the cluster's performance and local development. This endeavour has ushered in the perspective of the global value chain (Schmitz, Citation2004, p. 6): ‘Central to value chain analysis is the observation that there are lead firms, notably global buyers, which set and enforce the parameters under which other firms in the chain operate’.

In this respect, global value chain analysis emphasizes that local producers learn a great deal from global buyers about how to improve their production processes, attain consistent and high quality and increase the speed of response. In other words, global lead firms play an important role in determining the upgrading opportunities of local producers (Humphrey and Schmitz, Citation2002). However, it is evident from the discussion that the global value chain approach has focused on foreign buyers, rather than foreign producers in the locality. The problem with this omission is that it has seriously hampered understanding of how foreign subsidiaries may affect the dynamics of a cluster.

Role of FDI and FIEs in industry clusters

The literature on FDI provides important insights into how FIEs may be incorporated into the studies of clusters. According to Dunning Citation(1993), FDI is characterized by firm-specific advantage in knowledge and technical know-how. This underpins a consensus that FDI brings in not only financial resources, but more importantly knowledge of various kinds. Therefore their presence can have a wider impact on the local knowledge base either through their own research and development (R&D) activities, or engaging in supplier development activities or simply having a demonstrative effect on local firms (Young et al., Citation1988). However, the use of FDI as a means to technology and knowledge is efficient only as long as sufficient absorptive capacity for the technologies exists locally (Borensztein et al., 1998). In addition, though, the right ‘market’ conditions should exist for domestic firms to learn (Dunning and Narula, Citation2004).

Birkinshaw Citation(2000) examines the impact of FDI on the evolution of industrial clusters. He found that the outcome depends on the dynamism of the cluster and the maturity of the industry concerned. While FDI has more limited, though positive impact on well-established clusters in a mature industry, the impact on emerging clusters in a high-growth industry may well be significant.

However, Birkinshaw was clearly more concerned with the financial flows that FDI would bring, although he pays heed to potential technology transfer. On the other hand, he has not really looked into the nature of inter-firm linkages. He has not touched upon the positive externality that FDI may have for the rest of the economy. In this regard, one of the most interesting points from the literature is that normal trading relationships between firms is a network form of organization, and that, in the absence of a highly developed institutional and producer service infrastructure, such collaboration may prove the most important means of technology transfer (Phelps, Citation1996). It has been established that the key linkages which affect the extent and nature of clustering and FIEs include local inputs, notably labour, market linkages with suppliers and sources of other intermediate inputs; interaction with customers; networking, collaboration and competition with firms and organizations other than customers and suppliers; collective learning and creativity (Nachum and Keeble, Citation2001). There is now considerable evidence that the clustering of FDI could amplify the positive effects. Fromhold-Eisebith (Citation2002) shows that clustering of TNCs' branches facilitated upgrading of the local information technology (IT) industry in Bangalore, India, through the labour market and generated positive spillover effects by promoting the development of infrastructure, education and local governance.

In the same line of argument, Zhou and Tong Citation(2003) demonstrates that by merely acting as the application agent for MNCs to start with, local IT firms in Zhongguancun, Beijing – the most important IT cluster in China – have achieved considerable technological learning, which has directly contributed to the success of the cluster in the home market. Moreover, they find that ‘as the relationship between MNCs and local firms are not only hierarchical, but also interdependent and evolutionary the learning capacity of local firms can be significantly improved by the presence of other related companies and R&D facilities, and by a developmental state in a market-oriented spatial cluster’ (Zhou, Citation2005, p. 1116).

Theoretically, this effect could be amplified further in manufacturing, where forward and backward linkages are significant. This is because manufacturing plants purchase a variety of different inputs including raw materials and components, services, machinery and equipment, utilities, and labour. If these inputs are purchased from within the host region, this will provide a boost to the regional and urban economy by stimulating increases in output and employment among the local supply industries (Hirschman, Citation1958). Such suppliers may then start to export to the sister affiliates as well as to other independent external purchasers.

From the literature review, there is a lack of direct evidence in the potential of clustering FDI to facilitate local economic development through supporting the development of local clusters. For instance, Altenburg and Meyer-Stamer (Citation1999) show that clusters of TNC subsidiaries in Latin America induced further inflow of FDI, when suppliers followed the demand for parts and semi-components, and gave rise to positive externalities such as the formation of a local pool of trained workers and the accumulated experience of local authorities and trade associations in dealing with foreign investors. However, local firms were weakly integrated into such clusters as suppliers due to poor technological capacity. On the other hand, Thompson Citation(2002) studied FIEs' technology transfer to local firms by investigating Hong Kong garment firms in China. In his research, technology transfer to local firms by geographically concentrated FIEs was compared with that of geographically dispersed FIEs. He concluded that FIEs enhance technological development of local firms; more specifically, geographically concentrated FIEs were better than dispersed FIEs in transferring technology and managerial skills via training and spill-over to Chinese firms. In another instance, Tong and Wang Citation(2000) documented the case of Dongguan City in South China, where the formation of a local personal computer (PC) manufacturing cluster, involving both local and foreign firms, fuelled sustained economic development in the city. However, in all these cases, local firms have not escaped from their subordinate position.

Moreover, extant studies of the effects of FDI on local clusters have so far confined their attention to transfer of knowledge on one-to-one basis. There is so far no study that explicitly deals with the possibility that FIEs may benefit local firms and industry clusters by reducing fragmentation of the local industry as well as raising level of technology. This is despite of two interesting facts: first, industry clusters in LDCs tend to suffer from fragmentation; second, FIEs often show greater willingness to share knowledge. For instance, Zhou Citation(2005) highlights the lack of inter-firm collaboration, and consequently a high degree of fragmentation in the IT cluster in Zhongguancun, Beijing. The author's survey finds that firms with foreign background tend to take a positive view towards collaborative arrangements such as subcontracting, strategic alliances, partnerships, and information sharing, while indigenous Chinese firms tend to be indifferent to or sceptical of collaboration (p. 1127). Similar observations are noted by Altenburg and Stamer's (Citation1999) study of industry clusters in Latin America. They raise the prospect that FIEs may be able to act as strong transmitters of knowledge other than those associated with the manufacturing process. They have the potential to become a promoter of more open forms of knowledge exchange and an integrator of local industry.

Developing a new analytical framework

The need to account for the direction of the inter-firm linkages between the local and foreign firms can be better addressed by combining the hub-and-spoke model from the perspective of industrial district and insights from the research on the network economy. The hub-and-spoke model from industrial district provides a useful starting point for building the analytical framework that is needed. This model (Markusen, Citation1996) attempts to represent a regional industry by identifying key firms acting as anchors or hubs to the city or regional economy, with suppliers and related activities spread out around them like spokes of a wheel. Examples are Seattle, USA, and Toyota City, Japan. As shown in , a single large firm (e.g. Boeing in Seattle or Toyota in Toyota City) buys from both local and external suppliers and sells chiefly to external customers, who may be large, and masses of individual customers. Thus, the industrial districts of the hub-and-spoke construct are dominated by one or several large, vertically integrated firms, in one or more sectors, surrounded by smaller and less powerful suppliers (Markusen, Citation1996). The ‘hub’ and ‘spoke’ configuration highlights the dominant role played by large producers within a region in managing their needs for production capacity. The dynamism of the hub-and-spoke model is associated with the position of these hubs' organization and their national and international markets. Other local small and medium enterprises (SMEs) tend to have a subordinate relationship to them. Thus, the largest returns for local trade tend to be tied up as retaining earnings in the major hub firms who are efficiently utilizing their global strategic linkages. The Hub-and-spoke model is depicted in .

Fig. 1. Hub-and-spoke model

Fig. 1. Hub-and-spoke model

A similar model, with emphasis on the role of a key firm, is found in strategic management literature. It is the Rugman and D'Cruz (Citation2000) ‘Flagship and five partners’ model, in which the flagship firm, equipped with both the resources and a longer-term perspective, provides leadership to a vertically integrated chain of businesses with which it has established key relationships. The five partners consist of a flagship firm, key suppliers, key customers, competitors, and non-business infrastructure (NBI). The last partner (NBI) refers to the non-traded service sectors, the government, social services and educational institutions. The most important role in NBI is to provide a forum or conference for cooperative exchange (Rugman and D'Cruz, Citation2000).

In such a model, the flagship firm makes ‘the network competitive by bench-marking network activities and processes to global standards, restructuring the production and service operations to different network partners, and adopting a paradigm or relationship-based co-operation. The partners yield the strategic leadership role to the flagship firm often because it is the network's global strategic purpose that prompted the partners to join’ (p. 2). The authors further recognize that key suppliers are often expected to give near or total exclusivity to the flagship firm. In return, they benefit from increased volume and a greater portion of the value added to the product. Crucially, though, Rugman and D'Cruz (Citation2000) confine the definition ‘flagship firms’ to multinational enterprises (MNEs) or transnational corporations (TNCs).

As shown in , the flagship firm lies at the hub of the business network. The relationships are shown by arrows that demonstrate the inter-firm collaboration. Double-headed arrows which cross organizational boundaries show the key partners in the business system. Conventional arm's-length relationships are shown as dotted arrows that stop at organizational boundaries (Rugman and D'Cruz, Citation2000). Key suppliers differ from other suppliers in that they enter into a close network relationship with the flagship firm, sharing strategies, information, resources and responsibility for the success of the network. They can expect to experience increased volumes through the flagship firm's outsourcing for activities. Key customers also develop network relationships with the flagship firm that entails close cooperation and sharing of resources and information (Rugman and D'Cruz, Citation2000). A set of vendors is nestled around a large core firm, either providing inputs to the firm or distributing its inputs.

Fig. 2. The flagship firm and the five partners business system

Fig. 2. The flagship firm and the five partners business system

The ‘dynamic network’ is a network in which a ‘lead firm’ identifies and assembles assets owned largely by other firms (Ritter and Gemunden, Citation2003). It is the flagship firm that provides strategic direction and purpose to the network by orchestrating the relationship among the partners. In this perspective, the ‘flagship network strategy’ based on long-term collaboration and learning with network partners is the organizational mechanisms for overcoming internal resources and capability transfer limits to cross-border resources transfers which are barriers to FDI (Girod and Rugman, Citation2005).

The discussion highlights the crucial (and potentially lucrative) role of the hub or leading firms, which is underpinned by their possession of core skills ranging from manufacturing, R&D, to design and assembly, or even pure brokering (Giroud, Citation2003). According to Jarillo, the TNC has a bundle of competitive advantages that are often unavailable to local indigenous firms. In this sense, this dynamic network is also ‘strategic’, since the ‘hub firm’ sets up network, and takes a proactive attitude in the care of it (Jarillo, Citation1995).

Therefore, the important question to explore is whether it is possible for local firms to play this core role, and more importantly under what conditions this may be possible. The case of Qingdao, to which the paper now turns, provides some answers to this question.

CASE STUDY: ELECTRONIC INDUSTRY AND CLUSTER IN QINGDAO

Method and data collections

The primary data were collected during two phases of fieldwork: preliminary fieldwork between November 2001 and January 2002 and the final fieldwork during December 2003 and April 2004. In addition, secondary data were collected from local government files, documents, and government officials and confidential statistical yearbooks. Preliminary fieldwork involved 33 firm interviews covering various industrial sectors while the final fieldwork investigated 34 firms only from the electric machinery, electronics and telecommunication sector. Data acquired from the preliminary fieldwork helped to establish whether clustering activities existed and which industry is dominantFootnote1 in Qingdao development zones. Given the information from preliminary fieldwork, the final fieldwork could be more sophisticatedly designed. The main source of the primary data from two fieldworks is 83 face-to-face interviews with company managers, local and central government officials, researchers from universities and public research institutes.

The size of firms covered by the interview is varied, ranging from the largest Chinese firms and foreign-invested electronic firms to those with approximately 30 employees. Hence, the sample of firms covered different sizes of firms. The sampled firms were chosen in various sources such as ETDZ STATISTICAL YEARBOOK (Citation2003), QINGDAO STATISTICAL YEARBOOK (Citation2003, Citation2004) and ETDZ's Foreign Invested Enterprise Lists. Most of the company managers interviewed were managers in the supply procurement departments. With some of the companies, multiple interviews were conducted. The interviews were used to collect information on the company's buyer–supplier linkages with other local firms and FIEs and to understand the detailed procedures of local and global procurement of raw materials and components in Qingdao. Because of the sensitive nature of the matter for the company involved, all the interviews were not tape-recorded, although extensive notes were taken at the time of the interviews. The authors promised all interviewees that the information they provided would be used only for academic purposes. A list of the sampled firms in the final fieldwork is provided in the Appendix.

Qingdao city is located in the southwest of the Shandong province on the Yellow Sea coast. Historically, being one of the open coastal cities in China under the Opium War treaties, Qingdao (formerly Tsingtao) had been industrialized relatively early, and Qingdao port is one of China's five most important ports. More recently, Qingdao has been one of the China's fastest growing cities, more than doubling its gross domestic product (GDP) from 64.2 billion Ren Min Bi (RMB) in 1995 to RMB151.8 billion in 2002 at constant prices (1990).

Furthermore, as shown in , the local industry is dominated by two sectors, namely electric equipment and machinery and electronics (including electronics and telecommunication equipment) sectors. In 2002, the two sectors accounted for more than 60% of the city's gross industrial output value and some 27% of the value added. They also provided approximately 12% of the city's total employment.

Table 1. Distribution of gross industrial output value (GIOV), value added (VA) and employment in Qingdao, 2002

History plays a hand in the two sectors' pre-eminence in the local economy. DocumentsFootnote2 provided from Qingdao local authority show that the electronic components industry in Qingdao was born in 1939, under the Japanese occupation, producing recorders, electric indicators, and voltmeters. At that time, most of electronic firms were Japanese-owned. There were only ten Chinese firms in 1941. After the end of the Japanese occupation in 1945, electrical and electronic component industry flourished. Following the establishment of Qingdao Electrical and Electronic Company (Qingdao Micro Electronic Plant) in 1953, more than 110 electronic components plants were built. China's first ‘silicon instrument’ was developed in Qingdao city, which led to the establishment of the biggest silicon plant in China. With this success in silicon development, the electronic components industry grew rapidly in Qingdao. For example, Qingdao Nanhua Components Plant, No. 1 Electronic Component Plant, No. 4 Component Plant started to produce the cordless diversion equipment and micro-connector in the early 1960s. During 1966 to 1969, an industrial agglomeration of electronic component plants took place in the city. These included No. 2 Component Plant, Semiconductor Component Plant, Silicon Lab, Optics Measurement Institute, Qingdao Magnetic Iron Ore Plant, Electronic Counter Plant and Brown-tube Plant. These developments laid a foundation for the tremendous subsequent development of the electrical and electronic industry in the city.

From 1980 to 1985, 101 new electronic component products were invented in Qingdao, whose sales value accounted for 16% of total industrial output in the city (QINGDAO ELECTRONIC ASSOCIATION, Citation2004). The city also imported and utilized a total of 28 technology items from abroad. During this period, the main products were colour televisions, tape recorder components, radars, cameras, air conditioners, television tubes, integrated circuits and turners. In January 1985, the deputy mayor of Qingdao made a historic contract with the Sanyo Company regarding air conditioner technology, marking the start of his city receiving core technology and equipment in a turnkey base project. It was followed by the establishment of a comprehensive air- conditioner assembly line. Afterwards, the technological skills progressed, which resulted in the localization of major electronic components for final goods: in the case of colour television, 80% of components became produced by local technology; 91.6% of components were localized in camera in the early 1990s. Through the absorption of foreign technology, the electronic industry in Qingdao city expanded rapidly.

FORMATION OF ELECTRONIC INDUSTRY CLUSTERS IN QINGDAO

Today, Qingdao is home for three leading electronic producers in China. As of 2003, Haier leads the Chinese electronic market with a major market share in refrigerators (23%), washing machines (24%), vacuum cleaners (18%), air conditioners (21%), while Hisense occupies third place in television market share and Aucma first in special refrigerators in China (CHINA ELECTRONIC INDUSTRY YEARBOOK, Citation2004).

Qingdao's success is underpinned by the expansion and successful upgrading of its electronic industry cluster. A turning point in the process is the establishment of two development zones, namely Economic and Technological Development Zone (ETDZ) and High-tech Industrial Park (HTIP), respectively in 1984 and 1992. The two zones are sponsored by the local authorities and encouraged by central government legislation.

Since its establishment, ETDZ has attracted a large amount of foreign investment and projects. During 2002 alone, the value of actually utilized FDI in ETDZ was US$473 million. In HTIP, the actually utilized value of FDI was US$305 million (). Indeed, as of 2002, total amounts of FDI inflow in both zones accounted for more than 40% of total FDI values in Qingdao city (ETDZ STATISTICAL YEARBOOK, 2003). This fact, therefore, suggests that ETDZ and HTIP are important strategic geographical locations to attract FDI into Qingdao city.

Table 2. Ratio of FDI in GDP in ETDZ and HTIP in Qingdao

also provides information on percentage share of FDI in GDP in HTIP and ETDZ, respectively. From the last column of the table, it is clearly shown that FDI has played a crucial role in financing the two development zones. In ETDZ, during the observed period, the share of FDI in GDP is about 38%, on average, with a peak of 54.9% in 1994. Similarly, the ratio of FDI has been around 25% in Qingdao HTIP.

However, industrial development leadership has remained in the hands of locally-owned producers. In the process, suppliers have co-located around Hisense IT industrial Park and Haier Industrial Park as a part of ETDZ. Since the refrigerator plant of Haier has moved to the outskirt of Qingdao city, its component suppliers also gathered around the refrigerator plant.

This cluster is organized around three large local companies (Haier, Hisense and Aucma), and several large FIEs, including Panasonic electronic components, Mitumi Electronic, and Nanya Electronic. The collaboration between the local firms and FIEs provides the vital ingredient for clustering the electrical and electronic industry in Qingdao. Among the local firms, Haier plays the predominant role, acting as a hub firm of the electronic industry with its major suppliers and related firms. Between 2001 and 2003, Haier transformed the supply network of strategic alliances by selecting and merging 2200 second and third tier suppliers into 721 key suppliers for whole range of products. This transformation is partly influenced by the changing corporate governance of Haier group. Haier's key businesses including washing machines (Haier-Melloni), refrigerators (Haier-Carrier special refrigerator), and commercial air conditioners (Mitsubishi Heavy industry Haier) are produced by ownership of joint ventures. In the case of air conditioning, Haier has benefited from Mitsubishi's global supply network. represents more than 20 foreign invested enterprises in Haier Hi-tech Industrial Park (HTIP) and Haier Industrial Park (located in the ETDZ).

Table 3. Foreign invested enterprises in Haier Group's Industrial Park (ETDZ, HTIP)

Invensys, the global leading firm in the automation and control components for household electronic goods, established local operation in 1997 with its takeover of an existing firm (Qingdao electronics factory-USA Ciba Joint Venture) which previously manufactured similar types of products. The firm is located nearFootnote3 to Haier's hi-tech industrial park. Invensys provides Haier with the core components (control parts) for refrigerators, washing machines, and air conditioners. In 2003, sales value was RMB0.2 billion RMB. The proportion of product sales is 60–70% in Qingdao development zones (HTIP and ETDZ), and other domestic market shares 30–40% of total sales value. Hence, the purpose of investment in Qingdao is to meet local demand, being a strategic location. According to an interview with the purchasing manager, the firm makes an effort to collaborate with Haier and other local suppliers. These efforts build a solid business and technological partnership among suppliers (Fieldwork, 2004).

In this respect, Haier group's JIT (just in time) zero distance policy plays a role in encouraging the clustering, as the main suppliers were encouraged not only to deliver the components timely, but also collaborate with Haier regarding new technology and business administration, which is assisted by E-commerce as well as face to face meeting. All these activities are coordinated by Haier Logistics Ltd, thus accelerating the formation of a household electronic cluster. Haier Logistics has attracted 36 global suppliers including Invensys and Sanyo Electronic Machinery (Compressor) to Qingdao for investment in starting factories and forming all-round supply networks that meet the requirements for quality, cost and delivery period.

As FIEs have played an important part in facilitating supply networks in Qingdao, large local firms have aggressively developed their R&D capacity. For example, Haier's central research centre in Qingdao has built a network with 60 global, regional, and local research institutes around the world. Hisense's R&D centre plays a leading role in Chinese electronic industrial development. The company has 11 research institutes for household appliance, mobile phone, information network technology, intelligent control and optical communication, employing more than 1500 professionals and experts nationwide. By cooperating with Qingdao Semiconductor Research institutes and other Chinese research centres and universities such as Qinghua University and Harbin University, Hisense has developed advanced technologies under the auspices of the State 863 Plan (a nationwide state-sponsored hi-tech research programme). These include the optical communication and PDP module for digital television. Qingdao Semiconductor Research Institute was established in 1965, initially named Qingdao Semiconductor Experimental Lab. In the early days, the institute started with 125 researchers including 20 technicians. Now the human resources are more than quadrupled and they often collaborate with the R&D centre of Hisense group for the development of high value added products such as high-definition television and plasma display television TV. By means of several electronic training colleges established in 1990s, the city also tries to rear talented individuals from these institutions.

THE UNDERLYING DYNAMICS AND THE ROLE OF FOREIGN INVESTORS

Identifying the dynamic change of electronics cluster in Qingdao

The dynamics of the local clustering is found in the specific nature of the supplier–buyer networks in Qingdao. This section presents in-depth information about such networks, on the basis of the field research. The results provide a comprehensive picture of what happens in inter-firm networks between local firms and FIEs, looking at particular types of firms with their strategy and linkages. It also explores how the linkages between foreign and local firms have acted as a catalyst for the development and continuing expansion of the cluster.

Consistent with the conventional view of hub-and-spoke model, it was found that supply networks existed around all major firms. There are however two unexpected features. First, the hub firms are local large firms in Qingdao, while FIEs act as spoke firms. Second, FIEs nevertheless play an important role. Indeed, FIEs play a bridging role between local SMEs and large domestic firms in the buyer–supplier network. The detailed explanations are illustrated in and .

Fig. 3. The structure of supply network in Qingdao during the 1990s

Fig. 3. The structure of supply network in Qingdao during the 1990s

Fig. 4. Inter-firm linkages in Qingdao HTIP and Huangdao ETDZ (interview results)

Fig. 4. Inter-firm linkages in Qingdao HTIP and Huangdao ETDZ (interview results)

represents the structure of the supply networks in Qingdao city during the 1990s when the supply networks were incompletely constructed. At that time, the inter-firm networks were built among local firms; their structure was similar to the conventional hub-and-spoke model where local large firms are hubs and local SMEs are spokes. As illustrated in , around the large firms, the first, second and third tier suppliers built the network as a buyer and supplier relationship. During this period, however, firms were not actively interlinked. Though vertical collaboration existed between each hub-and-spoke firms, horizontal interaction between hub firms was non-existent. So the three leading local firms competed with each other for customers, but did not share the suppliers. Indeed, Haier explicitly prohibited its suppliers to have another contract with Hisense and Aucma (Fieldwork, 2004). However, as shown in , inflows of FDI have transformed the structure of inter-firm linkage, giving rise to sophisticated supply networks.

represents the network between the firms that were investigated in the development zones. It shows that the networks between the surveyed firms have become much thicker and sophisticated with inflows of FDI. Most FDI came to Qingdao in the form of wholly foreign-owned company or joint ventures. Unlike practices elsewhere, however, their main investment purpose was to provide key components and parts to local large firms, which were already major players in the domestic market. Crucially to the development of the cluster, however, when supplying the parts and components, FIEs were able to make contracts with multiple big firms because of their strength. For example, No. 34 firm in supplies goods to six different large firms which are numbered as 1, 2, 3, 4, 5, 30; and No. 25 firm is a supplier for four large firms numbered as 1, 2, 4, 19. Hence, the large firms numbered as 1, 2, 4 now share a foreign subcontractor for their final products. Significantly, in these kinds of networks, it is the local large firms that initiate the contracts.

Moreover, foreign suppliers shared second and third tier suppliers. During the transaction between local large firms and FIEs, numerous second and third-tier suppliers are engaged as well, forming further intricate networks among suppliers. When local second or third tier suppliers receive the purchasing order from FIEs, they are also provided with detailed component specifications. Manufacturing the component allows second and third tier suppliers to achieve the technology which is finally utilized for final product by local large firms. Such transactions among different firms provide an important opportunity for inter-firm cooperation and collaboration. It gives rise to a network covering the entire industry, directly contributing to the formation of the local industry cluster.

Moreover, from this network, local firms, both large and small, have enhanced their technology by receiving competitive components from FIEs. Thus interaction between FDI and local firms has been a win-win partnership. FIEs have played a vital role in building supplier networks. They are not only a supplier to local large firms. They are a bridge between local large firms and SME firms, and a nexus for knowledge sharing and transfer of technology. Hence, the hub-and-spoke model is corroborated in the case of Qingdao, but with an unexpected twist: FIEs can play an important and positive role even if they are not the dominant hub firms.

CONCLUSIONS

The case of Qingdao is characterized by two outstanding features. First, in the web of local industrial cluster, local large firms have played a leading role, whereas FIEs have played a supporting role. Second, the FIEs have nevertheless played a dynamic role by stimulating the integration of the otherwise fragmented local industry through their activities. Both features are significant, as they add to one's understanding of the possible roles, both positive and negative, that may be played by FDI in LDCs.

The case study of Qingdao has highlighted the role of FIEs as supporting, yet dynamic forces. In existing models, positive perspectives on FIEs in local economy emphasize the role of FIEs as hub firms or leading firms in developing local industry, whereas negative perspectives (e.g., dependency school) regard FIEs as exploiters of the local economy. Even in the former, however, the ability for the local economy to retain the economic surplus is limited. In the Qingdao case, however, FIEs are found to be an intermediator between local large firms and local SMEs, precisely because of their economic and technological supremacy. Moreover, by supplying core technology competitively to a collection of local large firms, the FIEs have ensured that the large Chinese firms, such as Haier, are able to deploy the most advanced technology in the world, but still manage to keep the prices down. This is indeed the secret of the success of Chinese electronic producers: Chinese firms like these in Qingdao are not only able to produce cost-efficiently, but also with decent technology, provided by some of the most established vendors in the field.

The bridging role of FIEs in local economy sheds new light on the dynamics of inter-firm linkages. Inter-firm linkages in the case of Qingdao are much more than a supplier-buyer relationship. They are also crucial channels where technological resources and managerial skills are shared among firms since R&D activities and technology transfer take place in the forms of inter-firm linkages. In addition, local firms are able to utilize the global network which is brought in by FIEs. Hence, by FIEs' involvement as spoke firms in inter-firm linkages, relationships between hub firms and local SMEs become dynamically engaged.

So what makes this possible? This is obviously a question that needs to be explored further. Tentatively, though, the authors think that two factors are critical to this development: the considerable local industrial and institutional capacity; and the domestic firms' relative advantage in having access to a large domestic market. The former is manifested in the ability of the local firms such as Haier to orchestrate its complex supplier–buyer and R&D networks and to implement best practices such as the just-in-time, zero distance policy. It is also evident in the local authority's success in establishing and expanding the development zones, around which much of the industrial cluster has developed. However, the role of the large Chinese domestic market cannot be overestimated. It is this market that has lured the FDI in the first place, and it is here where the Chinese firms first perfected their manufacturing and organizational skills.

In concluding, it might be useful to consider the impact of this development on the local economy. depicts the key elements and linkages. FIEs are formally inter-linked with local large firms through joint ventures, strategic alliance, and subcontracting. Based upon the strong link between local large firms and FIEs, second and third tier suppliers are both directly and indirectly connected to local large firms which are the principal buyers and retainers of the economic profits, and the effects of such linkages are multiplied throughout the local economy.

Fig. 5. Qingdao model of local economic development

Fig. 5. Qingdao model of local economic development

The case of Qingdao carries implications for the practice of urban economic development, especially in view of the increasing popularity of industrial clustering as a strategy. The case shows that setting up specialized development zones can work, but only if there is sufficient extant industrial capacity and organizational skills in the area, and if FIEs and local suppliers can be induced to interact in a dynamic and mutually beneficial fashion.

Acknowledgements

The authors are grateful to two anonymous referees for insightful and constructive comments on improving an earlier version of the paper. All remaining errors remain the responsibility of the authors.

Notes

1. These two sectors accounted for more than 60% of the total gross industrial output value in Qingdao.

2. This document is provided by Qingdao Bureau of History and Geography (Qingdao City electrical and electronics industry).

3. This company is located in HTIP but not within Haier Hi-tech Industrial Park (Haier gao ke-ji-gong-yie-yuan).

REFERENCES

  • Altenburg , T. and Stamer , J. 1999 . How to promote clusters: policy experiences from Latin America . World Development , 27 : 1963 – 1713 .
  • Bair , J. and Gereffi , G. 2001 . Local clusters in global chains: the causes and consequences of export dynamism in Torreon's blue jeans industry . World Development , 29 : 1885 – 1903 .
  • Becattini , G. 1990 . “ The Marshallian industrial districts as a socio-economic notion ” . In Industrial Districts and Inter-firm Co-operation in Italy , Edited by: Pyke , F. , Becattini , G. and Sengenberger , W. 37 – 51 . Geneva : International Institute of Labour Studies .
  • Best , M. 1990 . The New Competition , Cambridge : Polity Press .
  • Birkinshaw , J. 2000 . Upgrading of industry clusters and foreign investment . International Studies of Management and Organization , 30 : 93 – 113 .
  • Borenszstein , E. , De Gregorio , J. and Lee , J. W. 1998 . How does foreign direct investment affect economic growth? . Journal of International Economics , 45 : 115 – 35 .
  • China Electronic Industry Yearbook . 2004 . “ China Electronic Association ” . Beijing
  • China Statistical Yearbook . 2003 . “ National Bureau of Statistics of China ” . China Statistics Press .
  • Crone , M. and Roper , S. 2001 . Local learning from multinational plants: knowledge transfers in the supply chain . Regional Studies , 35 : 535 – 548 .
  • Cumber , A. and Mackinnon , D. 2004 . Introduction: clusters in urban and regional development . Urban Studies , 41 : 959 – 969 .
  • Dicken , P. 2003 . Global Shift: Reshaping the Global Economic Map in the 21st Century , 4 , London : Sage .
  • Dunning , J. H. 1993 . Multinational Enterprises and the Global Economy , Wokingham : Addison-Wesley .
  • Dunning , J. H. and Narula , R. 2004 . Multinational and Industrial Competitiveness: A New Agenda , Cheltenham : Edward Elgar .
  • ETDZ Statistical Yearbook . 2003 . Huangdao ETDZ Statistical Bureau . unpublished confidential information
  • Friedmann , J. 2002 . The Prospect of Cities , Minneapolis/London : University of Minnesota Press .
  • Fromhold-Eisebith , M. 2002 . Regional cycle of learning: foreign multinationals as agents of technological upgrading in less developed countries . Environment and Planning A , 34 : 2155 – 2173 .
  • Girod , S. J. G. and Rugman , A. M. 2005 . Regional business networks and the multinational retail sector . Long Range Planning , 38 : 335 – 357 .
  • Giroud , A. 2003 . Transnational Corporations, Technology and Economic Development: Backward Linkages and Knowledge Transfer in South East Asia , Cheltenham : Edward Elgar .
  • Held , R. J. 1996 . Clusters as an economic development tool: beyond the pitfalls . Economic Development Quarterly , 10 : 249 – 261 .
  • Hirschman , A. O. 1958 . The Strategy of Economic Development , New Haven, CT : Yale University Press .
  • Humphrey , J. and Schmitz , H. 2000 . “ Governance and upgrading: linking industrial cluster and global value chain research ” . Brighton : Institute of Development Studies . IDS working paper, No. 120
  • Humphrey , J. and Schmitz , H. 2002 . How does insertion in global value chains affect upgrading in industrial clusters? . Regional Studies , 36 : 1017 – 1027 .
  • Humphrey , J. and Schmitz , H. 2004a . “ Governance in global value chains ” . In Local Enterprises in the Global Economy: Issues of Governance and Upgrading , Edited by: Schmitz , H. 95 – 109 . Cheltenham : Edward Elgar .
  • Humphrey , J. and Schmitz , H. 2004b . “ Chain governance and upgrading ” . In Local Enterprises in the Global Economy: Issues of Governance and Upgrading , Edited by: Schmitz , H. 349 – 381 . Cheltenham : Edward Elgar .
  • Jarillo , J. C. 1995 . Strategic Networks: Creating the Borderless Organisation , Butterworth-Heinemann, Oxford .
  • Lall , S. 1980 . Vertical inter-firm linkages in LDCs: an empirical studies . Oxford Bulletin of Economic and Statistics , 42 : 203 – 226 .
  • Lee , J. 2005 . Global Electronic Enterprise's Strategy in China: Analyses and Implications , LG Economic Research Institute . LGERI Report
  • Lowe , N. and Kenny , M. 1999 . Foreign investment and the global geography of production: why the Mexican consumer electronics industry failed . World Development , 27 : 1427 – 1443 .
  • Markusen , A. 1996 . Sticky places in slippery spaces: a typology of industrial districts . Economic Geography , 72 : 293 – 313 .
  • Marshall , A. 1920 . Principle of Economics , London : Macmillan .
  • Nachum , L. and Keeble , D. TNC linkages in localised clusters: foreign and indigenous firms in the media clusters of central London . Academy of Management Proceedings . pp. G1 – G6 . IM:
  • Pa Cambridge Economic Consultant . 1995 . Assessment of the Wider Effects of Foreign Direct Investment in Manufacturing in the UK , London : Department of Trade and Industry .
  • People's Daily . 2002 . 13 January (available at: http://english.people.com.cn/200201/13/eng20020113_88569.shtml) (accessed on 15 May 2006)
  • Phelps , N. A. 1996 . Collaborative buyer–supplier relations and the formation of centralized networks . Geoforum , 27 : 393 – 407 .
  • Qingdao Electronic Association . 2004 . Electronic Industry in Qingdao , Qingdao Electronic Association .
  • Qingdao Laoshaqu Commerce Investment Guidebook . 2001 . Qingdao HTIP Bureau of Foreign Investment .
  • Qingdao Laoshaqu Commerce Investment Guidebook . 2003 . Qingdao HTIP Bureau of Foreign Investment .
  • Qingdao Statistical Yearbook . 2003 . “ Statistics Bureau of Qingdao City ” . China : China Statistics Press .
  • Qingdao Statistical Yearbook . 2004 . “ Statistics Bureau of Qingdao City ” . China : China Statistics Press .
  • Ritter , T. and Gemunden , H. G. 2003 . Network competence: Its impact on innovation success and its antecedent . Journal of Business Research , 56 : 745 – 755 .
  • Rugam , A. M. and D'Cruz , J. R. 2000 . Multinationals as Flagship Firms: Regional Business Networks , Oxford : Oxford University Press .
  • Schmitz , H. and Nadvi , K. 1999 . Clustering and Industrialization: Introduction . World Development , 27 : 1503 – 1514 .
  • Schmitz , H. 1995 . Collective efficiency: growth path for small-scale industry . Journal of Development Studies , 31 : 529 – 566 .
  • Schmitz , H. 2004 . “ Globalized localities: introduction ” . In Local Enterprises in the Global Economy: Issues of Governance and Upgrading , Edited by: Schmitz , H. 1 – 19 . Cheltenham : Edward Elgar .
  • Thompson , E. R. 2002 . Clustering of foreign direct investment and enhanced technology transfer: evidence from Hong Kong garment firms in China . World Development , 30 : 873 – 889 .
  • Tong , X. and Wang , J. C. Global-local networking of PC manufacturing in Dongguan, China . Paper presented at the IGU Conference in Dongguan . August 8–11 2000 . China
  • Turok , I. 1993 . Inward investment and local linkages: how deeply embedded is ‘Silicon Glen’? . Regional Studies , 27 : 401 – 417 .
  • UNCTAD . 1995 . “ World Investment Report ” . New York, , United Nations
  • UNCTAD . 1997 . “ World Investment Report ” . New York, , United Nations
  • Wang , J. C. and Tong , X. Industrial clusters in China: embedded or disembedded? . Paper presented at the IGU Conferenc . July–2 August 30 2002 . Johannesburg, , South Africa
  • Yeung , Y. M. and Li , X. 2000 . Transnational corporations and local embeddedness: company case studies from Shanghai, China . Professional Geographer , 52 : 624 – 635 .
  • Young , S. , Hood , N. and Hamill , J. 1988 . “ Impact of inward direct investment on the United Kingdom ” . In Foreign Multinationals and the British Economy , Edited by: Young , S. , Hood , N. and Hamill , J. 63 – 101 . London : Croom Helm .
  • Zhou , Y. and Tong , X. 2003 . An innovative region in China: interaction between multinational corporations and local firms in high-tech cluster in Beijing . Economic Geography , 79 : 129 – 152 .
  • Zhou , Y. 2005 . The making of an innovative region from a centrally planned economy: institutional evolution in Zhongguancun Science Park in Beijing . Environment and Planning A , 37 : 1113 – 1134 .

APPENDIX

Table A.1. Final sampled firms

Reprints and Corporate Permissions

Please note: Selecting permissions does not provide access to the full text of the article, please see our help page How do I view content?

To request a reprint or corporate permissions for this article, please click on the relevant link below:

Academic Permissions

Please note: Selecting permissions does not provide access to the full text of the article, please see our help page How do I view content?

Obtain permissions instantly via Rightslink by clicking on the button below:

If you are unable to obtain permissions via Rightslink, please complete and submit this Permissions form. For more information, please visit our Permissions help page.