2,486
Views
4
CrossRef citations to date
0
Altmetric
Regular Articles

‘Waiting for the call to prayer’: exploitation, accumulation and social reproduction in rural Java

&

ABSTRACT

This article analyses processes of exploitation, accumulation and social reproduction in rural Java. Using fieldwork in a primarily agrarian and a predominantly non-agrarian village, it underlines the ways in which pluri-active labouring class households contribute to processes of accumulation through a variety of forms of petty self-employment and wage-labour – above all sharecropping and female homework, which is interwoven seamlessly with reproductive labour. Agrarian accumulation is dominated by traders and absentee capitalist landowners. Forms of exploitation are linked to petty capitalism's relationship to capital-in-general. The article briefly discusses the potential for labouring class collective action given the villages' relatively flat social structures.

Introduction

This article analyses processes of exploitation, accumulation, and social reproduction in rural West Java. In doing so it underlines the ways in which pluri-active labouring class households contribute to processes of accumulation through a variety of forms of precarious, informal wage-labour, and petty self-employment. The article proceeds through a comparative analysis of the specific forms through which ‘unpaid surplus labour is pumped out of the direct producers’ in two villages close to the city of Tasik Malaya – one with a primarily agrarian economy and one with a predominantly non-agrarian economy.

One key mechanism of exploitation is highlighted in each village. In the largely non-agrarian village, it is female homework. This was its most common form of wage-labour, interwoven seamlessly with reproductive labour. In the still primarily agrarian village, sharecropping was the primary mechanism of exploitation. Sharecropping is seen here as a disguised form of wage-labour, which ties the sharecropper to a particular plot of land for the duration of each paddy season. In this village, there were no capitalist paddy farmers and agrarian accumulation was primarily the preserve of traders and absentee capitalist landowners. A third mechanism of exploitation – usurious moneylending – is discussed in relation to both villages. In an Islamic cultural context that frowns on usury, these were often concealed in market transactions such as the sale of agricultural inputs and consumer goods on credit. Both villages were relatively homogenous in socio-economic terms with high levels of exploitation by outside capitalists, prompting questions in the conclusion about potential routes to shifting the balance of power towards classes of labour.Footnote1

The article’s focus, then, is on the contemporary dynamics of exploitation in the region of Tasik Malaya in rural West Java, how they vary across villages where agriculture is more or less important, how they are located in broader capitalist dynamics, and, more briefly, what the political implications might be. In the still primarily agrarian village, which is located further from the city beneath Galunggung volcano, mostly city-based absentee capitalist landowners had bought up sawah (paddy land), which was cultivated through highly iniquitous sharecropping arrangements that yielded profits of around $2000 per hectare per year (see below). And so, although there were no capitalist paddy farmers in the village, paddy production still contributed to the surpluses of absentee capitalist landowners.

The village with a largely non-agrarian economy is located just a few kilometres from the city’s eastern edge and has higher levels of commuting. Here exploitation through non-agricultural wage-labour is more common and female homework has become the most widespread type of wage-labour in recent years. This involves petty urban capital outsourcing production to villages and pushing wage-labour into the interstices of reproductive labour, thereby increasing the surplus labour time from which petty capitalists can extract surplus value. Homework lengthens the working day as women can move seamlessly between this piece-rated wage-labour and heavy reproductive labour burdens without leaving their homes. Homework, then, illustrates how the productive and reproductive spheres are intertwined in the everyday lives of women homeworkers who shoulder the core reproductive work of raising the children who will populate tomorrow’s production sites while simultaneously working full days for today’s capitalists. More broadly, homework further increases the pluri-activity of classes of labour who make up almost 90% of the population in the two fieldwork villages.

Pluri-activity comprises multiple low-income forms of wage-labour and petty commodity production (PCP).Footnote2 In our fieldwork villages, as well as homework and agricultural labour, it includes wage-labour in small nearby food factories, building sites and petty capitalist street-vending operations. The main forms of petty commodity production that it encompasses are small-scale farming and food production and trading. Migration – mostly for street-food vending from one village and factory work from the other – is the subject of another paper (Pattenden and Wastuti Citationforthcoming).

Classes of labour’s long working days across multiple forms of wage-labour and petty commodity production increase surplus labour time and lower local wages (90% of wages in the fieldwork villages were below government-stipulated minimums), increasing capitalists’ profits and ability to compete. Pluri-active classes of labour also contribute to the accumulation of capital-in-general by lowering the costs of capital’s expanded reproduction as a whole. They put downwards pressure on wages in general, and provide cheap goods and services through petty commodity production and wage-labour for small businesses. These low-cost goods and services cut others’ reproductive labour time and the costs of reproduction, further increasing surplus-labour time across society (employees spend less time making food and so have more time to work), and allowing employers-in-general to lower wages. Food sold in and around the village and in the nearby city cuts the reproductive labour time of other labouring class households and of urban middle-class households working for the government or as white-collar employees of larger businesses. So, the production and sale of cheap food increases the availability of labour, reduces wages and lowers reproductive labour time and costs – both locally and for the broader economy.

The few cases of accumulation identified within the villages are mapped in the next section. Although surplus value produced in the countryside was primarily appropriated by urban-based capital, appropriation of surplus value within the villages was still significant – mostly through trade, and the charging of interest on agricultural inputs and basic consumer goods. Nevertheless, the villages were relatively socio-economically homogenous with well over 80% occupying similar socio-economic positions as members of classes of labour. Ninety-nine per cent were Sundanese and 100% were Sunni Muslim. All of the farmers in our fieldwork villages, with one solitary exception in each case, were petty commodity producers rather than petty capitalists. The absence of profit was underlined by farmers and sharecroppers alike with an oft-cited phrase: ‘hasil ti sawah uih deui ka sawah’, which translates roughly as ‘the value that comes from the land goes back to the land’ (see also White Citation2018, 2). Nevertheless, as already noted, the value produced in our fieldwork villages’ sawah added to absentee landowners’ surpluses (by over $5000 per year by our estimate; see below), and so is part of the broader process of capitalist accumulation.

The fact that exploitative activities were mostly pursued by those operating from outside the immediate social context is politically significant as it helps to foster unity within. But collective action in rural settings remains difficult – both due to the long shadow of state violence under Suharto (1965–1998) (e.g. Tornquist Citation2020), and due to the fragmented nature of simple reproduction. Dependence on capital for wage-labour – be it local capitalists or absentee capitalist landowners – creates its own constraints, and especially so in a context where capital-labour relations are socially embedded over long periods (see below).

Collective claims could potentially appeal to relevant existing laws relating to sharecropping (and absentee landownership) and minimum wages. Better minimum wage enforcement would, though, require simultaneous measures to lessen smaller capital’s contribution to larger capital’s profit margins, while better implementation of sharecropping legislation would not necessarily improve labour’s position if the landowner simply shifted to directly hiring wage-labour, or, in the case of absentee landowners doing so through a farm manager. The impacts, though, might be greater where levels of absentee landownership are more widespread, as they are in our fieldwork villages. Even here, though, they would likely be contradictory in the absence of a broader shift in the balance of class forces.Footnote3 Slower moves in the direction of eroding socio-economic and socio-political hierarchies might be facilitated by greater levels of more labour-intensive owner-operated agriculture within the kampung, but this would require broad-based access to loans for the hefty start-up costs.

The arguments advanced here are based first and foremost on fieldwork data collected in 2019 and 2020, but the paper sits within a long tradition of research on agrarian change in rural Java. This has documented various forms of exploitation through sharecropping, wage-labour and usurious moneylending (Hart Citation1986a; Hüsken Citation1989; Stoler Citation1977; White Citation1976, Citation2018; White and Wiradi Citation1989; Wolf Citation1990; or for colonial plunder, see Breman Citation2015). Pluri-activity, which is central to this paper’s findings, has been prominent in Java for decades and carefully documented in earlier studies (e.g. Hart 1986; White Citation1976). In a recent article charting processes of agrarian change from the late 1800s to the 2000s, White (Citation2018, 14) points out that while processes of differentiation and land concentration within villages and through urban absentee landowners have proceeded, this has ‘not produced a large capitalist farmer class’ but growing numbers of sharecroppers and pluriactivity across social classes – all of which resonates very closely with this article’s fieldwork findings. Female homework and the many moves between productive and reproductive labour have also been documented – both in detail (Wolf Citation1990) and in shorter interventions on women’s homework (e.g. Hartiningsih Citation2000). And the literature has also addressed labour circulation for street-vending, agricultural labour and factory work and analysed their political dynamics over time (Breman Citation1995; Breman and Wiradi Citation2002; Mather Citation1983; Saptari Citation2008; Silvey Citation2003).

The paper proceeds with a brief outline of research methods. It then introduces and compares the overall patterns of accumulation and simple reproduction in the two fieldwork villages (henceforth kampungs, or hamlets, as Java’s villages are made up of multiple hamlets). The following two sections develop the article’s exposition of dynamics of exploitation and social reproduction through discussion of female homework and non-agricultural wage-work more generally and of sharecropping and agricultural labour. A shorter section on moneylending follows these. The final section concludes.

Wage-labour, petty commodity production and capital in two West Java villages

This section’s overview of simple and expanded reproduction in the two kampungs sets the scene for the ensuing analysis of mechanisms of exploitation. The next section focuses on homework in Kampung 1 and the following one on agricultural wage-labour in Kampung 2. Street-food production is also touched upon. Readers who are more interested in questions of social reproduction, or of exploitation in agriculture may wish to skip this section. Around 75 hours of semi-structured interviews were conducted by the authors in August–September and November–December 2019. There were 49 household interviews (21% of all households), 12 follow-up interviews and multiple interviews with key informants. Interviews focused on economic activities and relations but extended into life histories and intra- and inter-household socio-political dynamics.Footnote4 Fieldsites were selected after visits to a number of villages in 2018 and 2019. Surveys of all 233 households in early 2019 provided a basis for selecting interviewees according to socio-economic position, occupation, and street and kinship cluster. Covid-19 prevented a third fieldwork phase, but a handful of additional interviews were completed in early 2021.

Kampung 1’s greater proximity to the city and urban labour markets, slightly higher levels of PCP, and sparser capital-labour relations, translated into slightly greater socio-political equity. This was demonstrated through the smaller share of paddy appropriated by landowners and the somewhat higher agricultural wages (see below). Expanded reproduction in both kampungs was limited to a handful of households. Outmigration from Kampung 2 was more likely to be permanent than circular. In Kampung 1 it was more likely to be circular. People mostly migrated from the latter to sell street-food and from the former for factory work (see Pattenden and Wastuti Citationforthcoming).

Flows of capital and labour in Kampung 1

Less than 20% of households in Kampung 1 primarily made a living from agriculture. Most of its 5 hectares (12.5 acres) of paddy land (sawah) and most of its approximately 8 hectares (20 acres) of dry hilly land were owned by landowners from other villages and from cities (see ). Ten people (five women and five men) rented and managed up to 0.42 hectares in the kampung or in nearby kampungs. Two groups of 4–5 women primarily worked as agricultural labourers and a further handful of men and women worked part-time. Since a prolonged drought in 2017, paddy land had been rented out for 2 kg of dried paddy per bataFootnote5 – equivalent to around 45% of the harvest, and 1.43 tonnes per hectare. Prior to that, sharecropping on a 50/50 basis – known as nengah or ‘halves’ – had predominated.

Table 2. Land use and forms of rent/sharecropping in the two Kampungs (c.=approximately).

Kampung 1 residents as a whole only owned around 1.25 hectares, and the government owned an additional hectare (tanah bengkok), which was rented out in tiny parcels by the kampung’s representative on the village council (lurah). Nobody made a profit from paddy, which was mostly consumed in the kampung. The largest landholding was less than one-third of a hectare and only five households had enough land to meet their rice needs – a number that drops with each passing generation.Footnote6 The mostly uncultivated wooded dryland provided firewood and fodder and was used by a handful of people to supplement incomes by growing durian, rambutan, banana, cassava, and timber. Two of the three outside landowners used it to grow rubber and coffee.Footnote7

The outside landowners were mostly HajisFootnote8 who had accumulated from kiridit businesses in cities like Bandung, or from krupuk production in Sumatra. Krupuk are cassava crisps, while kiridit refers to door-to-door sales of consumer goods on credit at high interest rates – in other words, a form of short-term loan masked by the trading of consumer goods in a cultural context where usurious moneylending involving the collection of interest (riba) is frowned upon. From the 1980s to the early 2000s these were the main activities of those who migrated to accumulate. Some went bankrupt and came home empty-handed, some built large houses or bought land on their return, and one, who had employed 40 sellers at one point, came home with a clutch of rooms for rent in Jakarta that he still lives from. A few never returned. Instances of krupuk production were fewer and more likely to be attempted in the home area.

The most common form of PCP in Kampung 1 was the production and trading of street food, followed by farming. Non-agricultural labour – within the village, in the nearby city and as migrants – was over four times more common than agricultural labour. The most common form of wage-work in the kampung was female homework – either packing krupuk or making toys from balloons. Others worked in small food factories. Construction work, which had been more prominent earlier, was mostly done by older men who had worked on large projects in Jakarta and Bandung before returning home to work on smaller jobs where, according to one veteran construction worker, owners showed them more respect. Younger men now mostly migrated as street vendors, working for the handful of petty capitalist operators from the kampung or nearby villages (see Pattenden and Wastuti Citationforthcoming). There were a handful of higher-waged labourers working locally – mostly mechanics.

Households were involved in multiple activities, with the poorest working in more – typically four or five. One of the poorest households in the kampung was involved in local food factory work, migrant street-vending, home krupuk-packing, and coconut selling, and also ran a small back-street kiosk. A slightly better-off household combined construction work, food factory work, agricultural labour, street-food production and trading, and, as a fall-back, fodder collection from the forest. A still slightly better-off household, which had formerly worked as migrant street-vendors, now mixed home krupuk-packing and toy-making with rubbish collection, animal-rearing and farming on rented land. Another slightly better-off household combined farming on leased land with buffalo ploughing and home toy-making, as well as local construction labour as a fall-back. The best-off labouring household encountered was made up of a young couple who worked as a mechanic and a cake-maker. The best-off PCP household owned 0.14 hectares, leased 0.42 more, raised a couple of goats and traded small amounts of fertiliser.

Table 3. Bases of simple and expanded reproduction in the fieldwork villages.

Flows of capital and labour in Kampung 2

The second kampung was beyond comfortable commuting distance from the city. Here most households had primarily land-based livelihoods, and over two-thirds depended to some degree on its always canal-irrigated paddy fields, vegetable fields and fishponds. Like Kampung 1 most of its land was owned by a handful of absentee landowners. They were outnumbered by small owner-cultivators, who were in turn outnumbered by those sharecropping the land of the absentee landowners, who were in their turn outnumbered by agricultural labourers who worked both in the kampung and nearby. A similar proportion of Kampung 2’s households belonged to classes of labour, but a greater proportion of those households primarily made a living from wage-labour as opposed to PCP: 74% as opposed to 59% in Kampung 1 (see ).Footnote9

Table 1. Some Characteristics of Kampung 1 and Kampung 2.

A clear generational divide marked out middle aged and older women and men who mostly worked in agriculture, and younger workers who were more likely to work in factories, as street-food vendors in the city, or as fish workers in the village. The latter was a male-dominated domain that encompassed village ponds and city markets, and touched networks of premans – the quasi-gangsters who operate protection rackets, and regulate market space physically and socially.

Petty agrarian capitalism was a little more prominent in Kampung 2. There was a solitary capitalist dryland farmer-trader who usually employed around ten workers (dryland farming required more than twice the amount of labour as rice fields). One of two large store owners also did dryland farming. They were close relatives of a petty contractor-cum landowner-cum fish producer whose wife, a daughter of one of the kampung’s two wealthiest households in the 1980s, added to her income as a government school teacher by running a petty kiridit business in the kampung. This might be defined as pluri-active petty capitalism, with a number of activities threaded together to facilitate expanded reproduction.

As well as the government teacher, two fishpond managers and a fish trader earned at high enough levels to diversify into forms of petty accumulation, but did not appear to do so, and so are understood here as petty commodity producers rather than petty capitalists. The two fish producers operated in three ways – cash rent, ical-lepas (sell and release) that simply involves providing baby fish and selling it when grown, and cepengan, which is the fishpond equivalent of sharecropping with the value of fish sales split 70:30 in favour of the landowner. Nearby there was a petty capitalist duck egg trader, two paddy traders and a fertiliser trader who all played a notable role in the kampung (see below).

In spatial terms, there were three types of capitalist operating in and around the kampung: firstly, agrarian traders who accumulate by appropriating surplus vale from kampung residents, and thrive on a relative lack of competition. Secondly, there are those who break out of the confines of the locality to accumulate through networked operations across the region – above all the fish and vegetable traders. And thirdly there are absentee landowners who invest in the countryside as part of a portfolio of accumulation-facilitating investments.

The absentee landowners included a road contractor and builder from the kampung who had long lived in Tasik; a resident of Jakarta whose wife was from the kampung and who owns and rents out rooms and runs a printing business in the capital, as well as owning close to 20 hectares of land in the vicinity of Kampung 2; a civil servant who comes from the kampung but lives and works on the island of Batam; a buildings supplies trader from a nearby kampung; the wife of a former provincial governor and senior military figure (known as ‘Ibu Governor’ or ‘Mrs Governor’); and the family of one of the largest businessmen in Tasik, also from the vicinity of Kampung 2, who had made his mark in passenger transport and sunk some of his excess capital into land. Two of these owned rice hullers kept in a neighbouring kampung.

The three types of capitalist occupy three different social spaces. The locally-focused traders and moneylenders occupy the social space of the kampungs and are very close to the farmers. The absentee landowners mostly occupy middle class and wealthy urban social spaces. The networked fish producers and traders, and their workers, occupy a distinct third social space. Their workspaces tucked away on the edge of the kampung double as drinking dens, with the drinking culture acting as part of a strategy of labour control. Frequent journeys are made to cities across the region where some rub shoulders with urban preman. As well as drinking, fishing competitions are often an integral part of this culture. Endang, a three-decade fish trader who says he feels sixteen, employs a local body-builder. While we talk to him an older man saunters in and whispers something in his ear about a haul of fish in a nearby village that is ready for collection. Unlike the limitations of place-based accumulation, this third type has more possibilities, but becoming rich requires negotiating a complicated politics.

Kampung 2 has more balong (fish ponds) than Kampung 1 and over double the amount of sawah. Nineteen out of 23 hectares of land in Kampung 2 are used for paddy and fish production. Around two-thirds of the land is owned by the five absentee landowners. Of the one-third that is owned by kampung residents, the largest holding is 0.42 hectares and the average is around 0.14 hectares. An owner-cultivator with 0.14 hectares may earn $11.7 (160,000 IDR) for each day of work (over treble a labourer’s income) but his average monthly income is not enough to survive let alone accumulate. The kampung’s PCP farmers sell labour-power as much as buy it. This does not mean that there is no exploitation by farmers in the kampung. There are two badegas who go regularly to take care of water levels in the sawah, mostly at night. They also fix bunds, hoe, and harrow, and are paid one-tenth of the harvest. Over three-quarters of paddy produced in Kampung 2 is sold – generally as wet paddy that traders from nearby kampungs collect direct from the fields.

Non-agricultural labour: homework in the interstices of social reproduction

White (Citation1976, 275) found that women in a Central Java village worked a total of 11.1 hours per day in 1972–1973. Women in this article’s fieldwork villages reported working for up to 16 hours in 2019, with the bulk of the difference being due to increased time spent on wage-labour and petty commodity production. This adds weight to one of this article’s central arguments about how the dynamics of capitalism have increased surplus labour time through low-paid pluri-activity. It is this appropriation of time from classes of labour which allows petty capitalists – the main employers of those in our fieldwork villages – to stay afloat in the Indonesian economy, and helps larger capital increase profits and compete in the national and global market-places.

Women are disproportionately affected. Wage-labour in Kampung 1 was immediately notable for its low wages, especially women’s wages (see ). Lower wages mean that a greater amount of surplus value is extracted from women relative to men. And women’s surplus labour time is also lengthened by the extension of their working days across the spheres of production and reproduction (see below). Within the latter women prepare and repair children and husbands for the workplace. Reproductive labour, in other words, is foundational to capital accumulation and conditioned by patriarchal ideology as well as capitalist dynamics (see Pattenden Citationforthcoming).

Table 4. Wage-Rates in Kampungs 1 and 2 arranged from lowest to highest.

Women’s working days encompass reproductive labour, petty forms of self-employment related to street-food production, and wage work. Unlike in Kampung 2 where agricultural labour predominated, the most common form of wage-labour in Kampung 1 was female homework – in the form of krupuk-packing and toy-making (see ).Footnote10 While factory work was preferred by those whose children had grown up, or those yet to become mothers, homework facilitated frictionless movement between childcare, housework and the labour process without any spillage of potential labour time during journeys to work. Homework allowed small capitalists to squeeze wage-labour into the interstices of social life and the pauses in reproductive labour when household tasks abated. In doing so they expanded surplus labour time, pushed down labour costs, and stayed afloat on a perpetual high tide of competition.Footnote11

As well as wage-work in their homes, women were also involved in petty commodity production – above all the production and sale of street-food, which reduced the reproductive labour time and costs of others. And so women workers, as well as the daily and intergenerational provision of workers for capital through their own reproductive labour, and contributions to capitalist accumulation as low waged workers, also reduced others’ reproductive labour burdens, thereby increasing their availability for wage-labour and lowering the costs of capitalist reproduction in general.

Gorengan and cilokFootnote12 made in the kampung mostly found their way to school gates and the urban periphery. This both lengthened the working day of pluri-active labouring class households in the kampung and trimmed the overall reproductive labour time of the city in ways that are differentiated by both gender and class. The less well-off were more likely to prepare food for others, while the better-off were more likely to buy food. The transfer of surplus labour time is by now hard to unravel between reproductive labour and the labour process, but amongst the jumble of ‘reproductive’ and ‘productive’ labour time, there is a transfer of reproductive labour from the working class to the middle class, as well as from women to men.Footnote13

Homework wages were the lowest wages in Kampung 1 and subject to an estimated 20% cut by two intermediaries (one inside the kampung, herself a packer, and the delivery man). The disparity with the wages of men who worked in the krupuk factories (that supplied the krupuk for the women to pack) was much greater than the disparity in agricultural wages. In part, this was because homework is relatively invisible – most of those involved were identified as housewives in our survey (see Mies Citation1982), and also highly individualised. But perhaps more than anything the low wages were due to the way that homework slipped seamlessly in with women’s reproductive work.

Most of those involved in homework – whether as krupuk-packers or street-food makers – get up around 3.30 am. Novi gets up at 2 am because the reproductive labour burden of caring for an infant is even greater than caring for a husband and older children, but also because a significant part of her husband’s wage is lost through helping his mother make interest payments to the moneylender she has been in debt to perpetually for nine years. Novi squeezes ten hours of tedious wage-work into her 16-hour working day, sealing 2000 plastic bags with the flame of an oil-lamp, at the rate of one every 20 seconds. Her daily wage brings her an income of $1.45 (20,000 IDR). And within her other six hours of work she washes her husband’s clothes and prepares the meals that propel him through a 14-hour working day in the factory.

Then there is Eli. She does two types of homework – krupuk-packing and balloon toy-making. Her husband has a morning job collecting rubbish from the market on the edge of town. Afterwards, he spends three hours looking after goats obtained by looking after others’ goats (a kind of goat ‘sharecropping’). They also breed a handful of chickens and marmots, selling eggs and meat. In addition, the two of them cultivate 1/14th of a hectare of tanah bengkok exclusively with their own labour, which provides half their annual rice needs.

Eli gets up at 3.30 am and fits nine hours of balloon work into her day, as well as some krupuk-packing. On the days when she does both, she subcontracts parts of the process out to neighbours. She earns 48,000 ($3.49) for nine hours of toy-making, and 15,000 ($1.09) for five hours spent sealing 1000 small krupuk packets. Interestingly she admits that she does not need to work as much as she does – she and her husband make 100,000 ($7.27) per day on average – more than is required for everyday needs. She says that she is ‘used to working’. It seems that the ease with which homeworking fits into a day of housework and childcare normalises long working days in ways that would not be the case for those who work outside of their homes. Eli never seems to stop – neither when she is talking to the authors nor on the many occasions, we pass her house. Homework disciplines the working body in a particular way, conditioning it to work during idle moments.

Aldora does over seven hours of wage-work, and over 4 hours of petty commodity production and trade every day as well as all of the housework tasks. Her husband’s contribution to household costs is limited, and Aldora has become accustomed to long working hours, in part due to supporting her daughter’s higher education. She prepares three different types of street-food in the hours before dawn, during the afternoon and in the evening before she sleeps. After praying and preparing breakfast she packs krupuk until midday prayers. In the afternoon she does two and a half hours working at a creche reading the Koran to children. A series of moves between krupuk-packing, housework and street-food preparation follow before the working day ends at 10 pm. Five hours of krupuk-packing are squeezed in overall, and, like Eli, she sub-contracts crisp packing to neighbours on days when reproductive labour burdens are higher. On these days, surplus labour time spills out into cracks and crevices of potential surplus labour time elsewhere in the neighbourhood. Those one step further down the chain receive a lower income and the main packer keeps up with her usual quota.

These are some of the ways in which the multiple moves between reproductive labour and the labour process stitch wage-labour and petty commodity production into the rhythms of reproductive labour to maximise surplus labour time. Returning to the article’s starting point of exploitation, surplus value is extracted from the labour process and distributed along commodity chains and across society. Reproductive labour not only underpins this by providing workers for the labour process, but is interwoven into the labour process and the dynamics of surplus value distribution. The initial positioning of reproductive labour in a linear formulation (reproductive labour→ labour process→surplus value extraction and distribution) is re-worked to become a much more messy dynamic where reproductive labour seeps into the chain of surplus value extraction and distribution, altering the dynamic as it works its way through social life. The linear relationship between reproductive and productive labour has been lost, and while reproductive labour and productive labour maintain their analytical distinction, they are no longer discrete.

Beyond homework

Besides homework, migrant street-vending is the most rapidly growing form of wage-labour in the fieldwork villages. It is not always distinguishable from street-vending PCP or petty capitalism. Most street-vendors who sold locally were petty commodity producers because they produced what they sold. Most migrant street-vendors, on the other hand, worked for petty capitalist producers and earned a piece-rate daily wage (see Wolf Citation1990, 53; Pattenden and Wastuti Citationforthcoming).

Food factory work has long been a prominent form of wage-labour for those commuting within their local area. These are small factories producing krupuk in most cases, but also cakes, sweets and cheese-sticks. Cake-making was mostly done by women who did not yet have children, sweets were made mostly by teenage boys and girls, and cheese-sticks and krupuk mostly by men in their late teens and twenties. Wages of between 80,000 and 100,000 required working days of up to 14 hours. Cake-making factories paid slightly higher wages – perhaps because cake-making was less competitive than krupuk-making and profit margins were higher for what was a luxury item. Of the almost 90% of households in the two kampungs that belonged to classes of labour, only 10% accessed higher-waged work that surpassed the minimum wage and provided noticeably higher living standards (e.g. better furnished or slightly larger houses) and allowed households to pursue fewer jobs and work shorter days.

Disguised wage-labour in the fields: sharecroppers, labour gangs and absentee landowners

In predominantly agrarian Kampung 2, iniquitous sharecropping was the primary mechanism of exploitation. It was above all through this that absentee landowners extracted surplus value, traders appropriated it, and inequality and poverty were (re)produced. Over three-quarters of the kampung’s sawah is cultivated on a sharecropping basis and sharecroppers from the kampung (known locally as panyawahs) cultivate almost as much again in surrounding kampungs. Transplantation and weeding is mostly done by female labour gangs, which are criss-crossed with kinship connections. The mostly male sharecroppers hoe, harrow, fix bunds, manage ploughing, make the transplantation lines, spread fertilisers, and maintain water levels. Men and women harvest and thresh together, and women dry the paddy.

Capital-labour relations

With the exception of one or two better-off sharecroppers who do not play a significant role in the labour process, sharecroppers are for all intents and purposes disguised wage-labourers. They shoulder the strains of management, wait four months to be paid, and are in effect tied to particular kotaks (fields or ‘squares’ of land) for the duration of each paddy season. Most sharecroppers work with agricultural labourers from their household, and many work as agricultural labourers for others as well as doing the ‘male agricultural tasks’ on the land they sharecrop.

Most work the same fields for many years, and in many cases ‘inherit’ them from parents. Some families had been cultivating the same kotaks since at least the 1960s. Sharecropping provides stable access to wage-labour at rates of around 45,000 per day (see ) for around 108 days per year for a sharecropper of around 0.42 hectares but spread over more than double the number of days given the repetitive part-time nature of much of the work. The wage rate was lower than the usual casual wage rate for male agricultural labourers.

On a day-to-day basis, sharecroppers’ responsibility for managing labour sharpens the focus on intra-labour relations and obscures those between labour and capital. Landowners off-load the stresses and strains of paddy cultivation and sub-contract out the intensification and extension of the working day to the exploited classes themselves in the form of the sharecropper. If the crop fails, the sharecropper faces greater losses – of both time and money. And by holding down the sharecropper’s share, the owner pushes down agricultural wages as a whole, even providing advantages for other capitalists who feed their labour process into the gaps in the working day that remain, and into the deficit in simple reproduction that leaves labouring class households stretched across multiple forms of wage-labour and petty commodity production (see above).

It was noted earlier that more remote Kampung 2’s steeper socio-political hierarchies were manifested in lower agricultural wages and the appropriation of a greater share of the crop by landowners.Footnote14 The latter was around 45% in Kampung 1, but close to 50% or 60% in Kampung 2 depending on whether the sharecropping arrangement was nengah (halves) or merlima (fifths).Footnote15 Merlima, which has slightly higher levels of surplus labour appropriation (see ), was more likely to be imposed on slightly worse-off sharecroppers. No reference has been found to merlima in other studies, but nengah (also referred to as parohan) has been widely reported elsewhere (Ambarwati et al. Citation2016, 281; Blackwood Citation2008, 26; Pincus Citation1996, 153). Some respondents linked the emergence of merlima, which reduces the sharecropper’s share to 40%, to landowners increasing their share of the crop to offset the costs of clearing land after nearby Galunggung volcano erupted in 1983.

Table 5. Distribution of Value in the Paddy/Rice Commodity Chain: Estimated Distribution of Value from 0.5 Hectares (357 Bata) Paddy Per 4 month Season in US Dollars.a

Labour relations at harvest time were also different across the Kampungs. The distribution of paddy was more opaque in Kampung 2, and there were more harvesters, which increased the pressure to accelerate (intensify) the process. The longer periods spent weeding in Kampung 1 may also indicate less intensive working patterns. In addition, the constant supply of canal-water in Kampung 2 led to a more staggered harvest, which increased the availability of labour and decreased its bargaining power. Where many fields are harvested in the same week, fewer labourers are available and landowners’ bargaining power decreases.

An overview of the estimated distribution of value within the paddy chain helps to frame the ensuing discussion of mechanisms of surplus-value extraction from sharecroppers, agricultural labourers and, to a lesser extent, PCPs. If land is sharecropped on a merlima basis, as most is, the owner gets close to three times as much paddy as the sharecropper, or over double in the case of nengah (see ). To lay bare the inequalities involved, for a day spent procuring inputs and overseeing the distribution of the harvest on 0.28 hectares of land, absentee landowners receive 85 times more than a female agricultural worker’s daily wage. Their profit from one hectare is around $2000 per year (see ). For one of the larger absentee landowners with landholdings reputed to be around 10 hectares, this amounts to close to $20,000 per year ($40,000 for the one reputed to hold 20 hectares), although the average is closer to $10,000 in Kampung 2 and $5000 in Kampung 1 where absentees’ landholdings tended to be smaller. Kampung 1 was closer to the city and there were more prospective buyers in nearby kampungs.

The sharecropper’s costs vary depending on how much work he does, whether or not pesticides or herbicides are needed, whether or not he can manage without hiring male labourers, how many times weeding gangs need to be hired, how much bunding work there is, and how much work is done by family members who are less likely to be paid with cash and instead receive paddy for the family pot at harvest time. Most, but not all, sharecroppers buy inputs on credit ( assumes that they do), which increases costs, and, last but not least, harvest wages vary depending on the size of the bowl, and the relative size of bowls (kobak) and buckets (ember). Grain is collected in ember, and the embers are then sub-divided by the sharecropper into a certain number of bowls for each labourer/labouring couple. In Kampung 2 some labourers said they got 1/12 of the harvest and others said 1/15 (the table uses a figure of 1/14th).

Our figures for the shares of value appropriated by traders are based on what farmers and sharecroppers received from the village paddy traders, what a large trader/miller in Tasik who sourced paddy from the area around Kampung 2 told us he paid to those same traders, and then what he sold on to wholesalers for, and what consumers pay in the market. The bottom line is that all of the labourers and the sharecropper combined received around 22%, the four traders in the chain around 40%, and the landowner a shade under 30%, with the rest going on the labour and machinery costs of traders, millers and tractor/plough owners.

The distribution of value between landowner and sharecropper are estimates as almost no two owner-sharecropper relations were exactly the same. The only rule is that landowners’ spending on inputs is slightly more with merlima and the distribution of value less fair. Sharecroppers are always responsible for ploughing and all labour costs, so the variations centre on who pays for fertilisers and seeds.

As well as being more likely to cultivate on a merlima basis, poorer sharecroppers are also more likely to buy inputs on credit (usually from the paddy trader but sometimes from the landowner), and lose a greater share of income to interest payments. This amounts to as much as 10% of their income (at an interest rate of 112% per annum). Squeezed by the input trader on one side and by the landowner on the other, some sharecroppers get caught in long-term debt. For one such sharecropper, the mental pressures of managing both production and his own debts were worse than the physical pressure. Meanwhile, land sales were an increasing source of revenue for the area’s landowners, with prices rising rapidly in 2019. Sharecroppers in Kampung 2 informed absentee landowners about pieces of land coming up for sale.

Both forms of sharecropping run contrary to the 1960 Basic Agrarian Law and Law 2/1960, which sets out shares of costs and outputs and prohibits absentee landownership, and the 1959 Share Tenancy Regulations Act, which stipulates that production costs should be shared in the same proportions as the sharing of the crop (Ambarwati et al. Citation2016, 266; White and Wiradi Citation1989, 282). The still high proportion of land cultivated on a merlima basis in Kampung 2 related to landowners’ greater bargaining power in a place where landlessness was high and urban labour markets relatively inaccessible.

Intra-labourer relations

The squeezed sharecropper squeezes others in his turn. In his capacity as a mini labour contractor, he may push the labour gang to complete weeding more rapidly and he might delay wage payments to reduce the need for cash outlays. This is most easily done by maximising the share of planting and weeding work done by female household members whose wages can be withheld until harvest time. After labourers receive their wet paddy at harvest time, women dry it at home, which takes at least two days during which time they have to keep a careful watch. If they don’t then gusts of wind can blow away part of their wages, and chickens can literally peck them away at them. Though not arduous, drying paddy is stressful.

In this ‘poverty chain’, then, the sharecropper, and especially the poorer and more socio-politically disadvantaged among them, claw back some of what has been lost to capitalist exploitation by pooling the wages of those with even less socio-political power – above all those of his own female family members. Intra-household dynamics and varying degrees of dependence and control between sharecroppers and landowners all play a role in the details of labourers’ conditions. But while relations between sharecroppers and daily wage-labourers take centre stage, the fundamental contradiction between capital and labour is obscured.

Sharecroppers can also easily squeeze labourers’ share of the harvest because their bucket (ember) and the labourer’s pot (kobak) vary in size, obfuscating the distribution. One female labourer claimed that the sharecropper with the biggest ember distributed paddy with the smallest kobak.Footnote16 This particular sharecropper, one of the best-off in the kampung with no siblings and three sons working in a Yamaha factory, did little work in the fields herself, which was unusual among sharecroppers.

An older labourer whose advancing years and slowing work-rate restricted her workdays only received enough paddy to last her two weeks, meaning that she had to buy rice for 14 weeks per season. Other agricultural labourers hardly had to buy rice at all between harvests, indicating that they worked around 180 days per year including in nearby kampungs. Rather than indicating relative wealth, their higher incomes often indicated greater poverty and difficult intra-household relations. Epong, a woman in her fifties who had been an agricultural labourer from the age of 12 and whose son-in-law and daughter were severely underemployed, worked through increasing joint pains in part to feed a neglected grandchild. She underlined how every day she waited for the muezzin to call time on the day’s exertions by signalling the start of midday prayers. It is Epong’s evocation of the everyday grind of exploitation – the effects of which are physically intensified as the morning advances and the years of agricultural and reproductive labour progress – which gave rise to this article’s title.

Nevertheless, underemployment was widespread. A middle-aged woman in Kampung 2 whose ability to work was restricted by health problems commented that ‘work is hard, but no work is worse’. And on this, it is notable that the amount of more labour-intensive vegetable farming had declined. Profits are up to 10 times higher than paddy farming but more erratic due to price volatility and pest-vulnerability. Poorer households are excluded by the high start-up costs, and most others can’t ride out the bad seasons even if they maximise family labour and delay wage payments.Footnote17

The rice harvest, as the agricultural labourer’s single largest wage-payment, reflects not only the social relations of production within the kampung but also broader relations in the area, region and country. Rice harvests channel more local dynamics of political economy (see Stoler Citation1977; White Citation2000), with the harvest shares received by agricultural labourers ebbing and flowing over the decades, as well as varying within the same village at a particular point in time – by as much as ten-fold (White Citation2000). And Hart (Citation1986a, 290) has persuasively argued that growing levels of exclusionary harvest arrangements in the late 1960s related to the brutal suppression of progressive agrarian movements in the 1960s, which shifted socio-political dynamics in landowners’ favour.

The erosion of wages through usurious moneylending

Usurious moneylending took a variety of forms. In Kampung 2, it was mostly concealed behind socially acceptable activities such as paddy and input trading, duck egg trading and sales of consumer goods. Here, further from the city, intrusions by outside moneylenders were more conspicuous, and so moneylending was largely internal to the village – an important reminder that there were still elements of exploitation within the village, even though surplus value was more mostly appropriated from the kampung by outside capitalists.

Several forms of moneylending were identified, mostly involving forms of ijon (tied sales) that allowed the village’s petty capitalists to chip away at the incomes of labourers and petty commodity-producing farmers. Most farmers and sharecroppers in Kampung 2 borrow from the paddy trader for inputs with the amount being deducted on the day of the harvest in a system known locally as ‘yarnen’ – an abbreviaton of ‘dibayar panen’ or ‘paid at harvest’. The appropriation of interest is partly concealed by a price ‘adjustment’. Some landowners lent to sharecroppers for the same purpose, claiming it back with interest, like the paddy trader, at harvest time – a moment when trader, owner, sharecropper and labourers assemble in the fields to divide the spoils. One landowner, a former road contractor and sometime paddy trader, was said to be particularly willing to lend money for inputs, with one of his sharecroppers losing around 10% of his income to the resulting hidden interest payments.Footnote18

Input traders located close to Kampung 1 also advanced agricultural inputs on credit. One elderly construction worker now struggling to make ends meet had borrowed the inputs to produce kale, which can be harvested seven times in a season. The input trader took the first two harvests as repayment and interest, and turned his nose up at the third, citing a glut, prompting the farmer to give the kale to his neighbours to feed their goats.

The second form of moneylending in Kampung 2 involved two women selling consumer goods to poorer families on credit at twice the going rate. Both were closely related to one of the kampung’s handful of capitalists and were part of what had been one of the village’s two wealthiest families in the 1980s. The third form of moneylending identified were loans made through duck egg trading. A moneylender from a neighbouring kampung began by providing ducks, which debtors paid for (with interest) by collecting eggs. Further loans were paid for the same way – the moneylender concealing the interest rate by paying for the eggs at a rate 25% below the market rate. Reputed to have 50 egg suppliers, the duck egg trader could be estimated to be making around 2 million rupiah ($145) a week in interest payments hidden, quite literally, in egg baskets.

One of the poorest sharecroppers, ensnared in long-term debt to the duck egg trader, said that he divided his money between ‘the duck man’ and his family. His working day had been further extended as he now slept in the sawah every other night to guard his ducks and their eggs. As a sharecropper who receives harvest payments every four months he is considered credit-worthy – unlike the poorest agricultural labourers in the village who struggle to meet basic needs, but who are still targeted by those selling consumer goods on credit. We never found clear-cut evidence of what we suspect was a fourth form of moneylending: loans of rice made against future labour by better-off sharecroppers and some petty commodity producing farmers – in effect advance wages in kind that can nudge down production costs by lowering wages.

Classic high-interest informal moneylending through Kosipas (short for Koprasi Simpan Pinjam)Footnote19 declined in prominence during the fieldwork period due to a microcredit operation that had set up three groups in Kampung 2 in 2019 and 2020, with over 40 members, and one group in Kampung 1 in 2020 with 20 members. Women were loaned around $150 over a year at an interest rate of a little over 20%. Nevertheless, a few of the poorest households in Kampung 1 still owed money to kosipas at interest rates that spanned from 180% to over 400% depending on the duration of the loan – anything from daily repayment to eight weeks. Different agents touted the different types of loans on different days of the week in what seemed to be organised incursions. Those caught in debt were losing somewhere between five and ten percent of their incomes to interest payments.Footnote20

We received information indicating that up to 10% of the poorest households in Kampung 1 had been in debt to kosipas until recently. PKH cards,Footnote21 which entitle poor households to a range of government social payments, were taken as security, jeopardising their quarterly government payment.Footnote22 One of the moneylenders’ agents’ tactics was to visit small kiosks and offer to help the owners expand and modernise their stock. A shopkeeper who had been in debt for nine years had earlier been used by a moneylender to draw other people into debt. Her tiny back-street shop could not keep up with the interest payments, so she regularly drew on the wages of two of her sons, taking around a quarter of what they earned. Perhaps it was a conscious move on the part of agents to seek out those with wage-earning children as potential long-term debtors. In this case, as well as transferring part of her sons’ wages to the moneylenders, she also involved most family members in krupuk-packing, extending their working days in a bid to keep up with payments.

Three other forms of moneylending were identified in Kampung 1, all of which related to agriculture. First, there was gadai, which is when a loan is made in exchange for the use of a piece of land until the loan is repaid (a mortgage). The second is called tutung and was identified in Kampung 1 through the widowed sister of men who had migrated to East Java to set up a kiridit business. She was a petty capitalist by proxy who also leased in land cultivated exclusively with hired labour. Tutung involves a relatively large loan set against a number of future harvests – typically 10.Footnote23 The loan is usually repaid after three harvests, meaning that seven harvests acts as interest at a rate of over 50% per annum.Footnote24

Conclusion

This paper has sought to analyse socio-political dynamics and material conditions in contemporary Indonesia by comparing the specific forms through which ‘unpaid surplus labour is pumped out of the direct producers’ in a predominantly agrarian and a predominantly non-agrarian village. It has focused on two central dynamics of exploitation: (i) the extraction of surplus labour from labourers through sharecropping and agricultural wage-labour and (ii) the expansion of surplus labour time, lowering of labour costs and transfer of reproductive labour time through female homework and, more generally, pluri-activity, which involves the extension of working days across multiple precarious forms of wage-labour and petty commodity production. These, it has been argued, are central to broader dynamics of accumulation in Indonesia and beyond. Globally over 60% of labourers work informally (ILO Citation2018) and pluri-active labouring class households, including small farmers, make up the majority of the population in the Global South (Pattenden Citation2016).

Reducing surplus labour time and increasing wages requires analysis of capitalist (re)production in general, and the ways in which larger capital appropriates surplus value through smaller-scale capitalism, as well as transfers in reproductive labour from pluri-active classes of labour, and above all the women among them. It also requires analysis of the particular forms of patriarchy in contemporary Indonesia. This is less intense than in countries where residence is usually patrilocal and inheritance patrilineal, and perhaps less obvious in ideological terms than was the case when the New Order regime (1965–1998) pumped out crude hymns of ‘housewifeization’ (Blackwood Citation2008, 32–3; Robinson Citation2009, 5), but still central to contemporary capitalism’s systematic underpayment of wages to women and to the longer hours of surplus labour extracted from labouring class women in the spheres of production and reproduction (Pattenden Citationforthcoming).

As noted at the outset, usurious moneylending and the exploitation of wage-labour and sharecroppers have been widely documented in Java (Hart 1986; White and Wiradi Citation1989), as has female homework, both in Indonesia and beyond (Hartiningsih Citation2000; Mies Citation1982; Wolf Citation1990). This article has assessed these dynamics at the turn of the 2020s in villages where landlessness, pluri-activity and non-agrarian forms of reproduction, have become even more pronounced.

The means through which unpaid surplus labour is being ‘pumped out of the direct producers’ in the predominantly non-agrarian village no longer primarily take place through agriculture, but in the more agriculture-oriented village labour exploitation is channelled above all through sharecropping and often linked to concealed forms of moneylending embedded in personalised relations. The oppressiveness of the forms of exploitation on display, and their clear material consequences, remind us how far removed Geertz (Citation1963) was from ‘the actual relations of production’ (emphasis added) and their ‘specific political form’ (White Citation2000).

Gillian Hart (Citation1986a) located her fine-grained analysis of labour relations in the Javanese countryside in Indonesia’s broader political economy. The rise of more oppressive forms of labour relations in the late 1960s reflected broader realignments of the distribution of power after the United States-backed government-led massacres of between half a million and a million people (some leftists, many not) in 1965–1966. Over half a century later, Indonesia has still not shrugged off this legacy, and the ripples of activism that fanned out over the decade after Suharto’s demise have largely been calmed.

Given that exploitation is primarily external to rural villages, and the internal social structure is relatively flat with nearly 90% of households in this article’s fieldwork villages belonging to classes of labour, there is clearly vast latent potential, in spite of the world-historical pressures of Indonesia’s evolving position in the global economy, to challenge the mechanisms of exploitation identified in this article. And although it has been pointed out above that the impacts of increasing implementation of existing legislation might be contradictory, an intensified focus on sharecropping and the wages paid to pluri-active classes of labour could provide a basis for organising in rural Java, and might disrupt the existing dynamics of accumulation and exploitation.

Acknowledgements

The authors would like to thank Ben White, Bridget O’Laughlin and the anonymous reviewers for comments on the first draft, and also the editor of JPS.

Disclosure statement

No potential conflict of interest was reported by the author(s).

Correction Statement

This article has been republished with minor changes. These changes do not impact the academic content of the article.

Additional information

Funding

This work was supported by the University of East Anglia Quality Related Global Challenges Research Funds (QR GCRF RR1018-4).

Notes on contributors

Jonathan Pattenden

Jonathan Pattenden is at the University of East Anglia in the UK. His research on the political economy and political sociology of rural India has been published in journals such as Development and Change, the Journal of Peasant Studies and the Global Labour Journal. He is the author of the monograph Labour, State and Society in Rural India and editor of Class Dynamics of Development and of the Journal of Agrarian Change.

Mia Wastuti

Mia Wastuti is a freelance researcher interested in issues of rural development, poverty, and political change in Indonesia. She has studied in Bandung, Yogyakarta and Rotterdam and been active in a variety of organisations seeking to improve conditions and enhance democracy in both rural and urban Java.

Notes

1 Those involved in combinations of wage-labour and petty commodity production, including farming (see Bernstein Citation2006).

2 Petty forms of self-employment that produce goods or services at a level that contributes part or all of a household’s living, but without any accumulation.

3 With thanks to Ben White for making us reflect more on the complexities of enforcing sharecropping laws.

4 We initially planned to interview 30% of households, but covid-19 prevented this. Not all activities are mentioned during a first interview, and repeat interviews were only conducted with some respondents. Another thorny issue is at what point a migrant ceases to be counted as a member of a household. Those intending to return to the kampung and who send back part of their city wage were included in this paper’s household data.

5 A bata is equivalent to 14 m2. 714 bata make up one hectare. 289 bata are equivalent to one acre. During the drought those cultivating through nengah still had to repay landowners for seeds. Under the new system the tenant pays for the seeds, and only pays the landowner after harvest.

6 Putting this in a broader context, 99.2% of households in Kampung 1 were landless or owned less than a quarter of a hectare of sawah, compared to 65% across nine Javanese villages in the early 1980s (White and Wiradi Citation1989, 278). Stoler (Citation1977, 79) found that 77% of 478 Central Javan households did not have enough land to meet household rice needs. And Wolf (Citation1990, 86–90) found that 89% owned less than 0.57 hectares in her fieldwork village. She characterised the 54% with average landholdings of 0.135 hectares as predominantly proletarian, and those with average holdings of 0.355 hectares (34%) as predominantly agrarian. One to two generations later, our findings simply indicate that the latter have merged with the former, whose landholdings have in their turn become even smaller. In fact Wolf’s figure of 89% is exactly the proportion that we found to be predominantly proletarian – in our terms ‘classes of labour’.

7 For a detailed analysis of dryland (kebon), see Kosuke et al. (Citation2013).

8 Mostly better-off and male individuals who had visited Mecca.

9 74% and 59% are estimates. The data are accurate for the households we interviewed, but for those that were only surveyed it was not always possible to be sure whether incomes from wage-labour or PCP were greater. The margin for error might be as much as 5%.

10 In contrast, homework was just starting in Kampung 2. A handful of women had started to pack crisps in August 2019 shortly before we began interviews.

11 There is a long history of this type of work in Indonesia and beyond. See, for example, Hartiningsih (Citation2000) and Wolf (Citation1990).

12 Deep-fried vegetables and cassava dumplings.

13 Wolf (Citation1990, 98) makes a similar point.

14 The difference between the kampungs is not as high as it first seems as there is somewhat more harvest work in Kampung 1. Here the bulk of paddy is carried to homes and dried and the relatively small share of paddy that is sold is sold dry. In Kampung 2 most of the paddy is sold as wet paddy directly from the fields. Most of what is not sold are labourers’ in-kind wages.

15 2–2.4 tonnes per hectare. Rents for Kampung 1 were lower than the norm in the early 1980s, while rents in Kampung 2 were higher (White and Wiradi Citation1989, 279). Mertelu/morotelu (see Ambarwati et al. Citation2016, 281; Hart 1986, 179; Hüsken Citation1989, 324) had predominated earlier.

16 White and Wiradi (Citation1989, 286, 289) have also noted the existence of different harvest shares in the same village. See also Hart (1986); Pincus (Citation1996, 100–126); Wolf (Citation1990, Chapter 2). But above all, see White (Citation2000) where in a wide-ranging review of literature shares as disparate as 1/5 and 1/36 are referred to.

17 Up to 38.6 million IDR per year on 0.14 hectare.

18 And of course this emerges from long-term personalised forms of patronage and control between sharecropper and landowner (e.g. Blackwood Citation2008, 27–30).

19 Koprasi Simpan Pinjam roughly translates as Savings and Borrowing Group. They were encouraged by Indonesia’s first President Sukarno, but over time became increasingly controlled by individuals and came to resemble informal moneylending operations.

20 This is a rough estimate – the upper figure assumes half a week of male agricultural labour and a full-time krupuk-packing income, and the lower figure assumes a combination of street-vending and krupuk-packing incomes. Interest rates also varied, and so the estimate is based on an average of the shortest-term 24 day loan, which had the highest rate of interest (50,000 per week), and the longest term 10 week loan with the lowest rate of interest (25,000 per week).

21 Short for Program Keluarga Harapan or Family Hope Programme. Ironically the PKH system includes measures to facilitate access to credit.

22 PKH facilitates free access to education up the age of 18, to some amount of healthcare, to a monthly payment of 110,000 for buying rice (enough for 11 kilos), and to small payments for the elderly and those with disabilities.

23 In the case we identified, the loan was 10 million for an area of 0.14 hectares. Other informants indicated smaller loans for smaller pieces of land, indicating that interest rates increased as the amount advanced declined – as was the case for moneylending by outside actors.

24 See Hart (Citation1986b, 687) for discussion of a similar arrangement in central Java whereby two-thirds of the crop is yielded for a specified number of seasons.

References

  • Ambarwati, Aprilia, Harahap Ricky, Sadoko Isono, and White Ben. 2016. “Land Tenureand Agrarian Structure in Regions of Small-Scale Food Production.” Chap. 12 in Land and Development in Indonesia: Searching for the People’s Sovereignty, edited by J. McCarthy and K. Robinson, 265–294. Singapore: ISEAS.
  • Bernstein, Henry. 2006. “Is There an Agrarian Question in the 21st Century?” Canadian Journal of Development Studies 27 (4): 449–460.
  • Blackwood, Evelyn. 2008. “Not Your Average Housewife: Minangkabau Women and Work.” In Women and Work in Indonesia, edited by M. Ford and L. Parker. London: Routledge.
  • Breman, Jan. 1995. “Work and Life of the Rural Proletariat in Java’s Coastal Plain.” Modern Asian Studies 29 (1): 1–44.
  • Breman, Jan. 2015. Mobilizing Labour for the Global Coffee Market: Profits from an Unfree Work Regime in Colonial Java. Amsterdam: Amsterdam University Press.
  • Breman, Jan, and Gunawan Wiradi. 2002. Good Times and Bad in Rural Java: Case Study of Socio-Economic Dynamics in Two Villages Towards the End of the Twentieth Century. Leiden: Brill.
  • Geertz, Clifford. 1963. Agricultural Involution. Berkeley: University of California Press.
  • Hüsken, Frans. 1989. “Cycles of Commercialization and Accumulation in a Central Javanese Village.” In Agrarian Transformations: Local Processes and the State in Southeast Asia, edited by Gillian Hart, Andrew Turton, and Ben White, 303–331. Berkeley: University of California Press.
  • Hart, Gillian. 1986a. Power Labor and Livelihood: Processes of Change in Rural Java. Berkeley: University of California Press.
  • Hart, Gillian. 1986b. “Exclusionary Labour Arrangements: Interpreting Evidence on Employment Trends in Rural Java.” Journal of Development Studies 22 (4): 681–696.
  • Hartiningsih, Maria. 2000. “Women Workers in the Putting-Out System: An Undemanding and Unrecognised Labour Force.” In Indonesian Women: The Journey Continues, edited by Mayling Oey-Gardiner and Carla Bianpoen, 203–223. Canberra: ANU.
  • ILO. 2018. Women and Men in the Informal Economy: A Statistical Picture. Geneva: ILO.
  • Kosuke, M., S. S. Mugniesyah, A. S. Herianto, and T. Hiroshi. 2013. “Talun-Huma, Swidden Agriculture, and Rural Economy in West Java, Indonesia.” Southeast Asian Studies 2 (2): 351–381.
  • Mather, Celi. 1983. “Industrialization in the Tangerang Regency of West Java: Women Workers and the Islamic Patriarchy.” Bulletin of Concerned Asian Scholars 15 (2): 2–17.
  • Mies, Maria. 1982. The Lacemakers of Narsapur. London: Zed.
  • Pattenden, Jonathan. 2016. Labour, State and Society in Rural India: A Class-Relational Approach. Manchester: Manchester University Press.
  • Pattenden, Jonathan. Forthcoming. “The Patriarchy of Accumulation: Homework, Fieldwork and the Production-Reproduction Nexus in Rural Indonesia”.
  • Pattenden, Jonathan, and Mia Wastuti. Forthcoming. “Between Kampung and Kota: Labour, Migration, and the Political Economy of Accumulation in Java”.
  • Pincus, Jonathan. 1996. Class, Power and Agrarian Change: Land and Labour in Rural West Java. Basingstoke: Palgrave Macmillan.
  • Robinson, Kathryn. 2009. Gender, Islam and Democracy in Indonesia. Abingdon: Routledge.
  • Saptari, Ratna. 2008. “The Politics of Workers’ Contention: The 1999 Mayora Strike in Tangerang, West Java.” IRSH 53: 1–35.
  • Silvey, Rachel. 2003. “Spaces of Protest: Gendered Migration, Social Networks, and Labor Activism in Wet Java, Indonesia.” Political Geography 22 (2): 129–155.
  • Stoler, Ann. 1977. “Rice Harvesting in Kali Loro: A Study of Class and Labour Relations in Rural Java.” American Ethnologist 4 (4): 687–697.
  • Tornquist, Olle. 2020. “The Legacies of the Indonesian Counter-Revolution: New Insights and Remaining Issues.” Journal of Contemporary Asia 50 (4): 635–652.
  • White, Benjamin. 1976. “Population, Involution and Employment in Rural Java.” Development and Change 7: 267–290.
  • White, Benjamin. 2000. “Rice Harvesting and Social Change in Java.” Asia Pacific Journal of Anthropology 1 (1): 79–102.
  • White, Benjamin. 2018. “Marx and Chayanov at the Margins: Understanding Agrarian Change in Java.” Journal of Peasant Studies 45 (5–6): 1108–1126.
  • White, Benjamin, and Gunawan Wiradi. 1989. “Agrarian and Non-Agrarian Bases of Inequality in Nine Javanese Villages.” In Agrarian Transformations: Local Processes and the State in Southeast Asia, edited by Gillian Hart, Andrew Turton, and Ben White, 266–302. Berkeley: University of California Press.
  • Wolf, Diane. 1990. Factory Daughters: Gender, Household Dynamics, and Rural Industrialization in Java. Berkeley: University of California Press.