644
Views
1
CrossRef citations to date
0
Altmetric
Research Article

Contracted Coercion: Land, Labour and Gender in the Swedish Crofter Institution

ORCID Icon
Pages 593-614 | Received 18 Jul 2022, Accepted 30 Apr 2023, Published online: 25 May 2023

ABSTRACT

In the early modern rural setting, labour was organized with varying degrees of coercion depending on landowning, social standing, and gender. This article analyses the crofter institution, characterized by corvée labour (obligatory work as payment), from the perspective of gender and coercion. The purpose is to answer the question of how the crofter institution was created, shaped, enabled and questioned. The right to establish a croft made the position as head of household available for men but it also increased social stratification. While crofters were masters of their households in contract signing, their position was ambiguous when it came to the organization of labour. Regarding physical integrity, crofters could be forced by physical violence and were subject to rules not connected to work, such as subservience. I argue that this was made acceptable through marriage and allowing the position as head of household to landless men. Crofters held an intermediate position, caught between the market logic of leasehold of land and the coercive logic of labour extraction, and this continued to colour the crofter institution until its final dissolution in 1943.

Introduction: Contracted coercion

In the early modern agrarian setting, labour was organized and structured with varying degrees of coercion depending on landowning, social standing, and gender. Crofters (Sw: torpareFootnote1) were a rural social group situated between peasant farmers with secured landholding and the landless population who relied only on their labour. The defining characteristic of the crofter institution was payment through corvée work for the croft (obligatory work specified in number of days, specific tasks and/or unregulated when called for by the landowner), which was specified in the contract in gendered ways. Crofters were part of the labour force of a landowner, but at the same time they made up independent households with a married couple at the centre.Footnote2 Thus, crofters were neither dependent live-in servants, nor ‘double free workers’ in the Marxian sense,Footnote3 but rather part of parallel labour relations. In this article, the institutional structure for labour extraction in the Swedish crofter institution is analysed from the perspective of coercion in work and gender. The question to be answered is: how was the position of the crofter and the crofter household created, shaped, enabled and questioned.

This is important in three ways, which are addressed here. The first is the conspicuous research gap regarding the institutional framework of the Swedish crofter institution. Crofters are well known in Swedish rural history, but in previous research the group has mostly been studied as part of the labour force of manors or in analyses of the group’s demographic pattern, as well as in studies on croft buildings as material artefacts.Footnote4 A newly published study has analysed the living standards of crofters through probate inventories, which provides an illuminating analysis of the changing position of the group during the 18th and 19th centuries as ‘proletarianization without pauperization’.Footnote5 Nevertheless, there is a tangible lack of studies on the social relations created in the crofter institution.Footnote6 The briefly mentioned presentations of the legal frame of the crofter institution have sometimes been based on century-old misunderstandings which have continued to colour the view of the crofters.

Secondly, there is a modernization focus in the historiography of labour, as discussed in the introduction to this Special Issue, in which the ‘double free’ worker of industrial capitalism is seen as the endpoint towards which the previous development was inevitably heading. This is also prevalent in Swedish rural historiography. Rather than assuming that free markets will render ‘free’ labourers, this article analyses the coercive structures of the laws regulating labour extraction in the crofter institution.Footnote7

Thirdly, there is a need for a gender perspective to understand the crofter institution. Ongoing research regarding the gender division of labour in crofters’ households points to an institution experienced very differently by men and women. The work obligations differed between estates, but on average, women did around ten per cent of the total share of the household’s labour duties to the landowner.Footnote8 Nevertheless, to my knowledge there is no study analysing the institutional framework of Swedish crofters from a gender perspective.

The gender perspective here means both that men and women were differently positioned in regard to the crofter institution, and that certain features of the institution carried connotations of masculinity and femininity which enabled, but also prevented, various kinds of development. Crofters were married to a very high degree, and I understand marriage as a gendered institution. The relationship between marriage and gender in early-modern societies has been a much-debated issue in recent works. The debate is fundamental for gender history since it deals with the core question of to what extent it is useful to understand ‘women’ as a separate, analytical category.Footnote9 Since the pioneering works which uncovered the hidden history of women in the 1970s and 1980s, the theoretical development has been profound and can hardly be summarized here.Footnote10 The intersectional approach of understanding gender as interacting with other categorizations, most frequently class, ethnicity and sexuality, has been indispensable for the field. Furthermore, there is an influential strand of research understanding marriage as a structure separate from gender; a structure that outmanoeuvres gender since there could be larger differences between married and unmarried women (or men) than between married men and married women in regard to labour extraction.Footnote11 However, I take another approach in this analysis and argue that for crofters, gender was a basis for labour extraction for both men and women, and it was organized through marriage.

The other theoretical tool is based on the framework for this Special Issue, the new direction in social and labour history analysing coercion in work. More specifically, I use the analysis presented by Robert Steinfeld in The invention of free labor, in which he points to the existence of parallel structures of coerced labour and capitalistic market economy.Footnote12 In essence, a croft was established because a landowner had excessive land, tilled or not, and a need for more labour. A croft thus included a relationship between a landowning person and a landless person or someone with insecure landholding, based on the two analytically distinct features which Steinfeld discerns: market exchange and submissive labour extraction. The crofter contract included a market exchange of land through a leasehold contract resembling that made between a present-day landlord and tenant. It also involved a coercive labour relation in which the contract stipulated an unregulated work duty, and with the landowner holding power over the crofter’s person. Thus, crofters are an ideal group to study in order to understand the ambiguities of rural hierarchies and labour extraction through the lens of coercion.

The aim of this study is to increase the understanding of early modern labour relations, more specifically how gender and coercion in work shaped the crofter institution. This is done through an analysis of laws, regulations, contracts and debates regarding the position of the semi-landless group of crofters in the Swedish 18th and 19th centuries. Why would laws and debates tell us about the lived experience of people? My argument here is twofold. Firstly, although people obviously did not always act according to laws and contracts, it is not possible to analyse practices without an understanding of regulations and norms. A systematic study of the legal structures provides a frame for understanding other aspects of the institution; such a study is lacking in the case of Swedish crofters, and is therefore necessary. Secondly, laws, debates and written contracts are not disconnected with what people actually did, but rather part of an ongoing societal negotiation, where new laws are based on an understanding of the actual doings of people. Laws are normative, but not in the meaning of being detached from everyday actions, they are part of these actions although do not correspond exactly to them.

The article proceeds in the following way. After a brief presentation of the demographic features of the Swedish crofter institution and research on equivalent groups in other Nordic countries, the analysis is structured around three aspects of the institutional structure of labour extraction in the crofter institution. Through the lens of coercion in work and gender, the article discusses, in turn: who had the right to establish a croft; what rights to demand labour came with it; and what it meant to the physical integrity of the crofter. All three sections follow a chronological structure, meaning that some laws are mentioned several times. In order to facilitate reading, the most important laws and regulations regarding the crofter institution are listed in . Throughout the article, the statements made in previous historiography are evaluated.

Figure 1. The most important laws, decrees and regulations regarding crofters’ position in Sweden, 18th-20th centuries (shortened and translated titles, see Bibliography for full titles)

Sources: See Bibliography: Law texts. Author’s adaptations.
Figure 1. The most important laws, decrees and regulations regarding crofters’ position in Sweden, 18th-20th centuries (shortened and translated titles, see Bibliography for full titles)

Crofters in the Nordic region

The Swedish crofter institution has generated comparatively little interest compared to the other Nordic countries, although certainly not because of the groups’ insignificance. In the mid-18th century Sweden, crofters were a relatively small group of ca 28 000 households, as compared to 187 000 peasant farmer households. At its height in 1860, there were 100 000 crofter households, while the group of peasant farmers had only increased to 223 000, a situation which sheds light on the proletarianization process. In 1900, the number of crofter households had diminished to 72 000.Footnote13 When the crofter institution disappeared in legal terms in 1943, only a fraction of the former number persisted, 5000 in 1940, down from 35 000 in 1920.Footnote14

The Danish laws have been thoroughly studied from the perspective of the master’s right by Anette Faye Jacobsen, who puts the social relationship at the centre.Footnote15 Danish agrarian relations have also received recent attention. In this context, the older historiography of understanding crofters and tenant farmers as not subject to serfdom under stavnsbånd has been criticized as a romanticization.Footnote16 The institutional structure of the Icelandic rural labour relations has been treated by Gudmundur Jónsson.Footnote17 The Norwegian historiography regarding crofters certainly stands out regarding its quantitative precision and level of detail. What is salient in this rich literature is the great interest in comparisons between laws and practices, regional variations, and the origins of the crofter system.Footnote18 Anna Tranberg has ambitiously studied the gender division of labour in the Norwegian crofter institution.Footnote19

Finland was part of the same realm as Sweden until 1809, and thus had the same laws until then, and many of them were kept under Russian sovereignty. The position of Finnish crofters became a central political issue, and unlike their Swedish counterparts, Finnish crofters organized themselves to protest against the leasehold laws. The Finnish structure meant that more crofters had a peasant farmer as landlord rather than a person of rank. This led to fierce antagonism between different parts of the rural population, and Matti Peltonen has argued that the inadequate political solutions to the crofter issue were one important reason for the Finnish civil war in 1918.Footnote20 In the Finnish historiography, Pirjo Markkola and Ann-Catrin Östman have studied the crofter issue from a gender perspective. More specifically, this concerns how the dependent and non-owning position of the crofter was perceived as a threat to masculinity, and thereby one reason for the political rise of the labouring classes.Footnote21

Land, labour and gender in the Swedish crofter institution

To take up a position as a crofter had obvious benefits for the large and growing landless population for whom freeholding was out of reach. It offered a place to live, a plot of land to till, and the possibility for members of the household to find extra work for wages. Day labouring beyond the contracted corvée labour could mean an important extra income for the crofter household, but the contracts did not usually contain any entitlement to this, but it was contingent on the landowner. Just as important, the crofter position protected the household from accusations of vagrancy. The early modern labour market was characterized by a major coercive feature, called laga försvar (literally legal protection), which forced landless people into compulsory service in a landed household, under threat of being accused of vagrancy. Holding a croft, like being a freeholder or parish artisan, offered protection from being considered a vagrant.Footnote22 Although a married landless person might be accused of vagrancy, being married could also function as a protection. Marital status was an important distinction between crofters and servants, which means that a comparison between the legal position of the two groups will prove fruitful to the understanding of gendered features both of the rural hierarchy and of labour extraction.

Agreements on land

This section deals with the right to establish a croft, which differed between the nobility and the freeholders,Footnote23 and the requirements for the crofter contracts. It is relevant for an understanding of coercion, since it established who could coerce whom in the rural hierarchy. The institutional framework of the nobility’s crofts had its roots in noble privileges formulated for their tax-exempt land: they were allowed to make their land as profitable as they could (göra sitt gods nyttigt).Footnote24 This included the right to build and populate crofts in order to establish a suitable work force, without the interference of the Crown. Crofts on tax-exempt land could be built as the landowner thought suitable, and were free from taxes and, importantly, its inhabitants were free from conscription, which increased the attraction of taking up a position as a crofter for a noble landowner.Footnote25 This means that the nobility’s right to establish crofts and apply what terms they thought appropriate and could reach agreement on was far-reaching.

Crofts on freeholders’ land and the importance of marriage

Three principles guided freeholders’ right to establish crofts: their duty to keep their farm large enough to be able to pay taxes to the Crown; forest decrees to save the common resources, which created a conflict of interest between the nobility and the peasant farmers on land use; and the Servant Acts, curbing the right of the peasantry to employ more than a certain number of labourers, which included crofters. The contested issue was what land ownership should include. In 1719, a regulation based on an appeal from the peasant farmers’ estate meant the first step towards allowing freeholders to build and keep crofts on their land.Footnote26 The mid-18th century involved further increases in peasant farmers’ ownership rights, which were strengthened and confirmed by the end of the 18th century.Footnote27 There was a convergence in what the landowning nobility and the freeholders could do with their land. This rise of the political and economic force of the peasant farmers and especially the freeholders is well known in Swedish historiography, but is usually understood in relation to the other estates,Footnote28 the nobility, the clergy and the burghers, although it established hierarchies based on labour extraction between the landed peasants and their landless neighbours as well.

The argument that would substantially increase the freeholders’ rights was a demographic one: the belief that the population of Sweden was too small. Three 18th-century decrees based on these demographic concerns pointed to the role of marriage in the establishing of crofts. In 1762 a decree confirmed the right of freeholders to establish cottages and houses for their married servants. In 1770, ‘permanently settled and married’ people could be exempt from the previous requirement for those without other suitable occupation of becoming servants under the Servant Acts.Footnote29 The physiocratic idea behind this was a wish that servants should be able to establish a household, get married and have children earlier in their lives in order to increase the rural population, even if they could not become freeholders. At the same time, the perceived lack of people made it legitimate to limit the number of workers or servants on each holding.Footnote30 As crofters were part of the workforce of a landowner, the establishment of crofts was limited on the basis of this principle. However, the intermediate position of the crofter also acknowledged them as separate households, which entitled them to certain rights. The third decree, issued in 1764, allowed crofters to employ servants, which underlines both the complexity of rural hierarchies and the importance of marriage in establishing that hierarchy.Footnote31 Thus, with marriage, the position as head of household became available to a man, which in turn legitimated other rights, such as employing servants, and not being forced to become a servant. Yet in spite of these rights, the fact that the crofter did not form an independent household, effectively undermined that position in various ways explored further below.

Crofters’ contracts and the leasehold law 1800

The governing principle regulating the relationship between landowners and crofters was stated in the general law of 1734, in the Land Code (Jordabalken), which assured the parties the right to make contracts freely, and stated that any contracted terms overruled the laws.Footnote32 Crofters were understood as leaseholders, and thus targeted by the leasehold law issued in 1800. However, this was primarily adapted to people of standing who were leasing large areas of land, and aimed to protect their right to make agreements freely. The only right that was not possible to withhold from the leaseholders through a contract was the right to stay until the general moving day (laga fardag) if they were dismissed.Footnote33 Thus, this law did not deal with the main feature that set crofters apart from other leaseholders: the labour duties. This is a conspicuous difference compared to the careful regulation of servants, which restricted agreements on length of contracts, wages and living arrangements.Footnote34

The 1800 law also demanded written contracts which were to be filed by the local court.Footnote35 Being a rather formalistic requirement, it is likely that many landowners and crofters relied on custom and social proximity in order to uphold the contracted terms. It also seems likely that many agreements continued to be made orally, since this was a recurrent theme in the debate even a century later. Indeed, some scholars have claimed incorrectly that written agreements were required for the first time in 1907 or 1943.Footnote36 My interpretation is that the law of 1800 stipulated written contracts, but that it was characterized by weak compliance. More importantly, when public interest in the crofter institution rose at the end of the 19th century (see below), written contracts were seen as a solution to the poor situation of crofters, a solution which did not threaten fundamental power relations. It was a non-threatening measure to suggest – however, it was not so non-threatening that it was fully enforced even after the intense debate that ended with the law of 1907.Footnote37

The Swedish crofter institution was less coercive than the Danish before the 1788 tenant reforms (landboreformernaFootnote38), since the Swedish crofters were not tied to the land or the specific landowner but could move. However, in Sweden the right to stay on the croft was severely curtailed by the principle that contracts took precedence over laws. Landowners used a formulation in contracts called ‘reciprocal termination’.Footnote39 While ‘reciprocal’ sounds like an agreement, in practice this meant that landowners could evict crofters at any time, leaving the crofter household without a home and nothing to live on. The crofter’s right to terminate the contract equalled the right to move (i.e. not being tied to the land as serfs). Waves of evictions did take place from time to time and aroused despair and anger, although it seldom led to organized resistance.Footnote40 It was not until 1907 that arbitrary reasons for terminating the contract or ‘home-made’ termination clauses in contracts were prohibited.Footnote41

The right to stay at the croft was a gendered issue as well. According to the 1734 law, a widow had the right to keep the contract after her husband died, as long as she was already married to him when the contract was signed in the first place. If she remarried, the landowner had the right to cancel the contract.Footnote42 For a man, the loss of his wife did not alter his contract. This shows how marriage as a basis for labour extraction was differently organized for men and women, since women’s right to the status as crofter was contingent on her gender and civil status.

Parallel structures of land agreements: The 20th century

At the end of the 19th century, the debate concerning crofters’ poor and insecure position intensified, and resulted in a new law in 1907.Footnote43 However, the most prominent feature of this law was its continuation of the older laws – it did not deliver the changes requested in the debate. The much-debated question of whether crofters should be compensated for improvement work on the croft holding resulted in a weak compromise: only the cost for pipes used for pipe draining was to be compensated.Footnote44 However, another leasehold law was issued only two years later, with a radically different content. It became known as Norrlandslagen, the law of northern Sweden. Northern Sweden was by this time dominated by huge forest companies buying up large areas of forests from landowners (sometimes by unfair methods), but also acting as leaseholders in order to make use of the forests. This law strengthened the position of the leaseholders, at the expense of landowners, which mirrored the economic power of the parties – the leaseholders were the powerful companies, while the landowners were rather insignificant peasant farmers.Footnote45 This means that there were two leasehold laws with totally different outcome for the parties, illuminating the circumstance pointed out by Steinfeld that different principles regarding free/unfree dimensions could exist side by side.

It was not until a law was issued in 1918 that the position of crofters changed in a more profound way. This new law gave crofters rights to buy their crofts, if certain requirements were met, even against the will of the landowner. However, by this time, crofters were expressing their view of the crofter position by abandoning the institution altogether and turning to industrial work or emigration.Footnote46

Right to demand labour

Crofters were heads of households, ‘free men’ capable of signing or denying the contract, but once the contract was signed, their own and their whole household’s labouring capacity were at the disposal of the landowner. The peculiar feature of this labour contract was that it could – and often did – include a paragraph that permitted unlimited work, and that the specified days could be used at any time. This could be written like in this example from Torpa estate in western Sweden: ‘… and the user [the crofter] must whensoever requested perform extra corvée labour’ (bold in original).Footnote47 It might seem like an unattractive contract to sign, but for a married couple during proletarianization of the 19th century, alternatives were scarce. The contracts also resembled those made by manorial tenant farmers, who often had even more corvée labour in their contracts.Footnote48 Moreover, since the contract included the whole household, I argue that a marriage and gender theoretical perspective provides new insights into the coercion of labour extraction in the crofter institution and why this position could be accepted.

Servants were regulated in such ways that they were forced to do any reasonable work demanded by the master; all work they did, they did with the master’s approval, and they did not have duties to others.Footnote49 Crofters on the other hand had many duties but could not plan the work themselves since they were subject to decisions by the landowner and needed to fit in both specified and unspecified chores, some as piecework, some as day work. They had duties towards the community and the obligation to restore buildings, but when called upon by the landowner, the crofter household always had to prioritize that work. This example of a contract from Ryholm’s estate in western Sweden, signed by the crofter Eric Ericsson in 1864, is fairly typical. His household was obliged to: take care of the croft’s buildings, fields and ditches, do 156 days of male corvée work and 8 days of female corvée work per year when called for, deliver post according to a certain structure, do extra days of work, provide transport and produce charcoal as demanded, transport charcoal to the estate, guard the forest from damage, bring their own tools to work and pay all taxes and insurances.Footnote50

When the crofter signed a contract, he did so as head of household and therefore in control of other people’s labour. While servants were dependent and deprived of self-determination, they were eligible for certain rights, such as the right to receive sufficient food and wages on time, as well as the right of not being forced out from their position unless something extraordinary had happened.Footnote51 Crofters had no such protection in the law, but were left, as household heads, to fend for themselves in negotiating contracts with landowners. This position of being responsible for certain tasks but at the same time deprived of the means to plan for it, could be illustrated by one of the very few parliamentary debates about crofters before the end of the 19th century.Footnote52

When the Building Code (Byggningabalken) of the general law of 1734 was discussed, it led to a conflict between the estate of the peasant farmers and the other three estates, especially the estate of the nobility. The issue concerned participation in the organized search and hunt for predators threatening the livestock, which was an obligation for all inhabitants owning cattle. The peasant farmer estate considered it necessary that crofters be part of the search as well. The estate of the nobility, on the other hand, argued that crofters should not be called upon to search separately, but only on the orders of the landowner since they were part of the landowner’s work force. Thus, the nobility argued that as noble landowners they should organize the men going to search, without interference from the law. In the end, the language of the law concluded that every second crofter should take part in the hunt.Footnote53 This is interesting since it points to the intermediate standing of male crofters: as their own head of household, often owning some cattle, but at the same time not really their own masters with the right to make decisions regarding their labouring capacity.

For women, this intermediate position was characterized by another level of coercion. A wife was expected to work for the benefit of the household, and the household position was determined by the husband’s position. A wife was explicitly forbidden to serve someone else without the consent of her husband, but when the husband had signed a crofter contract with unlimited corvée labour, he could not freely give such a consent.Footnote54 The ultimate decision about the labour of all members of the crofter household was then in the hands of the landowner. Once again, the position of the crofter was an intermediate one. Marriage did not give the right to a husband to force his wife to certain work, but a crofter contract often included the work of the wife.Footnote55 If a male crofter had signed such a contract, he could be deemed liable for damages if the wife did not perform the work – but he as a husband could not force her. However, if he employed a servant, the position as master gave the right to lend the servant to others.Footnote56 On the one hand, the crofter’s wife had fewer days of corvée labour, as mentioned in the introduction, meaning fewer days under the surveillance of the landowner and more subsistence work, presumably a less coerced form of labour.Footnote57 On the other hand, the wife was legally obliged to obey her husband, and contractually obliged to obey the landowner.

When servants’ unfree position was discussed in public during the 18th century, it was their unmarried status and the lack of future prospects of becoming head of a household that were at the centre of the debate. As servants they could not reach this important milestone of manhood and marriage, and were thus to be pitied. Others argued that since servants could get married after their period in service, and for example become crofters, servanthood was an acceptable position.Footnote58 I argue that for crofters, marriage played a role that mirrors the debate about servants, although crofters’ position was not debated until the end of the 19th century. The crofter institution was perceived as ‘natural’ through its complementary organization of the household, when husband and wife could help each other out and the wife could do her tasks in close connection to the home and the children.Footnote59 Since independence for the male crofter was signified by marriage, it was not the lack of independence that led to the questioning of the poor status of crofters, but the perceived impossibility of this position. When the hard work of the couple could not offer a reasonable living or even survival, when the crofter household was too strongly governed by the landowner and the crofter could not secure his position or the future of his household, he could not meet the standards for manhood.Footnote60

The 20th century: Continuation of coercive labour

The intense debate concerning the position of crofters at the end of the 19th and beginning of the 20th century occurred in the context of national economic worries about crofters being poor workers and the fear that workers in agriculture would leave the countryside or even the country altogether. There was a growing social democratic belief that crofters and other workers in the countryside needed better terms. The law issued in 1907 was one of the most important outcomes of this debate. Although the continuity in regard to the position of the crofters was strong, as discussed above, it made one important change. In 1907, the right to demand an unregulated workload was abandoned and the landowners could no longer order labour more or less as they pleased. Crofters had to be called for day labouring at least two days in advance – this was strongly opposed by the wealthy landowners in the upper chamber.Footnote61 However, a parliamentary investigation carried out in 1918 revealed that corvée labour was still common and that many landowners violated the 1907 law and its prohibition against unregulated day labour duties and duties unevenly distributed over the year.Footnote62 Although cash payments gradually became more common than corvée labour after the end of the 19th century, it was not until 1943 that corvée labour was forbidden.Footnote63

The master’s right: Physical discipline in the crofter institution

The master’s right (husbonderätten) was the right of the head of household, as master of his family and other subservient members of the household. This was a patriarchal right including the administration of chastisement and the enforcing of religious worship for all members of the household, and the right to expect the subordinate to be subservient, diligent and obey the master.Footnote64 In crofters’ households, the male crofter was head of his own household, but also part of the extended household of the landowner. This intermediate position was part of the contract, which often ended with a paragraph in which the crofter promised that, ‘not only he himself was to be faithful, diligent, sober, obedient and polite to the master or his representative, but also to ensure the same behaviour among his subservient people’.Footnote65 Thus, the position as male household head gave power over ‘his’ people, while at the same time the position as a head of a crofter household made the male crofter subservient – a situation hard to endure, as shown in the Finnish debate by Markkola and Östman.Footnote66

The subservience of the crofter was manifested in two features of the crofter institution: the right of the landowner to use physical violence towards crofters, and the right to prevent crofters from leaving the position. The development of these regulations further brings into question the modernization approach in previous research.

In Sweden the right of the nobility to exercise judicial power (gårdsrätt) over their subordinates was never particularly strong, unlike in Denmark (hals- og håndsret).Footnote67 However, in the 17th century the noble estate fought to achieve this right but they were opposed by the Crown and the Commoner estates.Footnote68 The noble privileges of 1723 implied a compromise, and the judicial rights of the Swedish nobility over tenants’ and crofters’ persons were never further extended. These specified the right to physically chastise crofters and other subordinates for ‘minor crimes, insubordination, and neglect’. It was the same principle as discussed above, which involved that a noble person had the right to make use of his holdings and labour force without the interference of the Crown.Footnote69 This right of the nobility to chastise their crofters was not repealed until 1864, when a new penal code was implemented. Thus the privileges of 1723 neither protected the rights of crofters nor abolished chastisement. They only slightly limited the judicial rights of the nobility.Footnote70 The abolition of chastisement of adult servants by their masters, as a comparison, came into effect in 1858 after a long and heated debate in which the position of servants was discussed in detail.Footnote71

Crofters (like servants and tenant farmers) were especially severely punished if they committed a crime against the landowner/head of household/master; that is, harder than if committing the same crime against someone else. In 1776, a specific regulation made the penalty more rigorous for tenant farmers, crofters and male servants if they deliberately, in order to take revenge for a supposed injustice, committed a theft or tried to kill their master. The law defined the subjects of the regulation – tenant farmers, crofters and male servants – in two ways. Firstly, it specified that ‘servants or subordinates’ were in essence, in their very position, ‘connected to the master in faithfulness’ and therefore a crime against a master was especially serious. Secondly, servants, tenant farmers and crofters were in a specific relationship because they served the master with ‘work or corvée day labour’.Footnote72 This means that work duties were connected to subservience – it was because the tenant, crofter or servant worked for the landowner that he stood in a specific relationship to him or her. This regulation was reissued with only insignificant changes in 1841.Footnote73 Rather than work being a market exchange and limited in time, for crofters it was connected to coercion and subservience. Thus, through the theoretical lens of coercion, it is possible to challenge the meaning of modernity as a development towards free labour markets.

The obligation to stay in the crofter position constituted another aspect of physical coercion. This was specified in the Land Code. The Land Code seldom explicitly mentions crofters, the term used is landbo, this means a person living on the land of the landowner, which includes crofters. The rule was that if a runaway landbo, or crofter, was found, the landowner could take him back by force. If he put up resistance, and he or any person helping him were hurt, there were no legal penalties for the landowner. If the landowner or his assistant were hurt, the crofter was punished with double fines. If the crofter had already found a new place, he could not be taken back violently, and the landowner could only demand fines.Footnote74 After 1845, this rule was changed so that the landowner was not allowed to use violent measures himself, but had to go through a public official to bring back the crofter.Footnote75 This means that the violent enforcement measures connected with the servant position applied to the crofter as well, while the crofter did not have the same rights to nourishment and clothing as included in the servants’ subservience. Moreover, it means that it was only in the mid-19th century that the landowner ceased to be able to physically force the crofter to return if the latter ran away.

The combination of the weak protective rights for crofters, such as contracts overruling the laws and the master’s right, meant that it was possible to continue to demand subservience if it was included in contracts. This option was indeed used by the landowners in contracts that spanned all the decades of the 19th century.Footnote76 The 19th century is thought of as heading towards industrialization and liberalization of the labour market, but the crofters were not considered to be in need of protection until 1907, and subservience and labour services continued to be demanded in the crofter institution until 1943.Footnote77

Conclusions

Crofters were an intermediate group, neither belonging to the feared masterless vagrants,Footnote78 nor inhabitants of taxable units of interest to the Crown. The crofter institution was part of an increasing social stratification by which peasant farmers strengthened their position both vis-à-vis the nobility through a convergence of rights to make use of their land, and vis-à-vis proletarianized groups through enhancing their ability to make use of other peoples’ labour.Footnote79 Furthermore, crofters was an intermediate group governed by two distinct logics: market exchange of land, and coercive features of labour extraction. This article has provided the first comprehensive analysis of the legal and contractual position of the Swedish crofter institution and the social relations of which it was part. The article has revealed how the group’s legal status was characterized by its lack of regulations, whereby crofters were left to negotiate contracts with landowners and did not enjoy the same protective rights as servants. The development of the crofter institution involved the organization of land use, labour extraction, and the physical integrity of the crofter’s person, and these were combined in a way that illustrates Steinfeld’s point about parallel structures. Rather than following a general trend of liberalization of labour markets, the labour extraction in the crofter institution continued to follow a specific trajectory of combining coercion in work and market exchanges of land well into the 20th century.

Furthermore, through a gender analysis, this article has provided an explanation for the lack of interest in regulating and debating the crofter institution. For rural landless men, to become a crofter was to become head of a household; this was a trade-off between the subservient position in relation to the landowner and the superior position in his household. This has been contrasted with the position of unmarried, live-in servants, for whom the lack of household supremacy was understood in the contemporary debate as difficult to endure for grown-up men. Thus, labour extraction in the crofter institution was based on gender and organized through marriage.

This article has provided a correction to the modernization approach in rural history, as discussed in a broader perspective in the Introduction to this Special Issue. The notion that the 18th century was a period when repressiveness peaked, and was replaced by a liberalization of labour relations during the 19th century, does not fit the story of crofters.

Special Issue

This paper is part of the Special Issue of Scandinavian Journal of History, titled “Labour and coercion in the Nordic region in the early modern period: Connections, ambiguities, practices“, edited by Vilhelm Vilhelmsson, Johan Heinsen and Hanne Østhus.

Disclosure statement

No potential conflict of interest was reported by the author.

Additional information

Funding

This work was supported by the Swedish Research Council under Grant no. 2020-02523, “Challenging the domestic. Gender division of labour and economic change studied through 19th century crofters’ households”.

Notes on contributors

Carolina Uppenberg

Carolina Uppenberg (b. 1982) is an economic historian with a doctoral degree from the University of Gothenburg 2018, with the thesis I husbondens bröd och arbete. Kön, makt och kontrakt i det svenska tjänstefolkssystemet 1730–1860 [Servants and masters. Gender, contract, and power relations in the servant institution in Sweden, 1730–1860]. She is currently researcher and PI for the project “Challenging the domestic. Gender division of labour and economic change studied through 19th century crofters’ households”, a three-year project funded by the the Swedish Research Council, at the Department of Economic History and International Relations at Stockholm University. Her main research interests are agrarian social relations during the 18th and 19th centuries, gender history and labour history. She is a participant in the COST Action funded network Worlds of Related Coercions in Work. https://www.su.se/english/profiles/cali2396-1.315409

Notes

1. Translated terminology is complicated, and not much has been written in English about the Swedish group I am studying here. I follow the terminology in a relatively recent collection by influential Swedish agrarian historians Myrdal and Morell, The Agrarian History of Sweden, see Gadd, “The Agricultural Revolution in Sweden,“ 140–1 for terminology regarding the landless groups. Other translations for torpare or Norwegian and Danish husmenn are: cotters or cottars. I reserve the term cottager for the poorer backstugusittare, a group who stood in a looser relation to the landowner and, at least before the mid-19th century, were often not fully able-bodied.

2. For a general overview of crofters, see Gadd, “The Agricultural Revolution in Sweden,” 140–3; Morell, “Agriculture in Industrial Society,“ 176–8; Elgeskog, Svensk torpbebyggelse; Jonsson, Jordmagnater, landbönder och torpare, 41–71; Svensson et al., “Empowering Marginal Lifescapes“; Lindström, “Labouring Poor“.

3. Marx, Capital, ch. 6, esp. 244.

4. Bäck, Början till slutet; Elgeskog, Svensk torpbebyggelse. For crofters and tenant farmers on large estates, see Olsson, Storgodsdrift; Nyström, Potatisriket; Jonsson, Jordmagnater, landbönder och torpare; Magnusson, Ty som ingenting angelägnare är; Dribe, Olsson, and Svensson, “The Agricultural Revolution“, for demographic and economic patterns, see Gadd, “The Agricultural Revolution in Sweden“; Morell, “Agriculture in Industrial Society“; Nordström, “Torp och backstugebebyggelsens framväxt“; Persson, “Något om torp och torpare“. For crofts as material artefacts, see Lagerqvist, Torpets transformationer; Svensson et al., “Empowering Marginal Lifescapes“.

5. Bengtsson and Svensson, “The Living Standards,“ 63.

6. For short discussions on the lack of studies analysing crofters as a social group, see van Bavel and Hoyle, “Introduction,” 13–6; Næss, “The Crofters as a Social Group“.

7. Introduction to this Special Issue. See also Steinfeld, The Invention of Free Labor, 3–9. For influential Swedish historiography Utterström, Jordbrukets arbetare, 825; Lundh and Olsson, “Tenancy Contracts in Scania“; Myrdal and Morell, The Agrarian History of Sweden.

8. Manuscript under review: Uppenberg and Nilsson, “The crofter is a woman”. In the ongoing research project “Challenging the domestic. Gender division of labour and economic change studied through 19th century crofters’ households” (Swedish Research Council, no. 2020–02523), crofters’ contracts from about ten large estates in southern and western Sweden are being compiled, and examples given in this article are based on this compilation. Research project web page: https://www.su.se/english/research/research-projects/challenging-the-domestic.

9. The classical essay is Scott, “Gender: A Useful Category”. For an argument of historicizing the gender category further, see Boydston, “Gender as a Question“.

10. For a recent overview with a Nordic perspective, see Arnberg, Larsen, and Östman, “Gender and Economic History”.

11. Ågren (ed.), Making a Living.

12. Steinfeld, The Invention of Free Labor.

13. Myrdal and Morell, The Agrarian History of Sweden, 286.

14. Hyrenius, SOU 1944:65, 21; SOU 1946:42, 125.

15. Jacobsen, Husbondret. See also Kook Lyngholm “Absolute Obedience“.

16. Henningsen, Stavnsbåndet, 15–6, 74–9, 96–8.

17. Jónsson, “Institutional Change“.

18. See for example Heimen 2/2004, vol. 41, Special issue on husmenn; Dørum, “Fikk overgangen til selveie betydning?“; Næss, “The Crofters as a Social Group“; Sogner, “Freeholder and Cottar“; Dyrvik, “Husmannsvesenet i Norge“; Prestesæter, Husmannskontrakter og lovregulering and the recent compilation by Østrem, En kort introduksjon. There is even an ambitious Wikipedia compilation of studies on crofters, husmannsvesenet: https://lokalhistoriewiki.no/wiki/Husmannslovgivning#Bibliografi, pointed out to me by Hanne Østhus.

19. Tranberg, Ringsakboka III; Tranberg, “’Ledighed taales ikke’”.

20. Peltonen, “Från osäkerhet till hat”.

21. Markkola and Östman, “Torparfrågan tillspetsas”. See also Östman, “Gendered Understandings“.

22. Servant Acts 1723 §1; 1739 art. 1 §1; 1805 art. 1 §1; 1833 art. 1 §1.

23. Wohlin, Emigrationsutredningen, 7–12.

24. Noble privileges 1723 §25.

25. Noble privileges 1723 §8–9.

26. Royal decree 3 June 1719 regarding peasantry’s appeal §3; Bäärnhielm, “Arrende och agrarpolitik,” 42; Lindström, “Skattelandbor och hälftenbrukare,“ 62.

27. Royal letter 18 Feb. 1757 regarding croft establishment; Royal decree 21 Feb. 1789 regarding sales of Crown land to freehold, §2; Royal confirmation 4 April 1789 of the rights of the peasantry, §7 (unrestricted number of servants).

28. Olsson and Morell, “Scandinavia, 1750–2000,” 331–7; Christensen, “Radikalism som strategi“; Winberg, “Another Route to Modern Society“.

29. Royal decree 20 July 1762 regarding married servants; Royal decree 8 March 1770 regarding improved agriculture.

30. Servant Acts 1686 §2; 1723 §3; 1739 art. 3 §1–3.

31. Royal decree 25 June 1764 regarding crofters’ servants.

32. General law of Sweden 1734, The Land Code (Jordabalken) ch. 16, 6§. Sw: “Leger man ut eller till lega tager gods och gårdar med vilkor, rätte sig båda sidor efter det, som aftaldt är”.

33. Royal decree 13 June 1800 regarding leasehold, §1; Wohlin, Emigrationsutredningen, 17–20.

34. Uppenberg, I husbondens bröd och arbete, 89–115.

35. Royal decree 13 June 1800 regarding leasehold, §3. Sw: ”det mellan Arrendator och Jordägare uprättade Contract skal sist wid det Ting, som infaller sex månader sedan Contractet slöts, för Härads-Rätten upwisas, der offenteligen upläsas och uti Intecknings-Protocollet til hela innehållet intagas”.

36. Gadolin, Öfversikt af jordlegorättens, 52–4; Elgeskog, Svensk torpbebyggelse, 224, believed that the law of 1800 demanded written contracts, while the 19th century authors Wahlberg, Om lega af jord, 132–4; Tisell, Äro några förändringar önskvärda, 9–10, considered that no written contracts were demanded at the time they wrote their texts (in 1892 and 1870). Agrarian historians Morell, Jordbruket i industrisamhället, 70, and Olsson and Morell, “Scandinavia, 1750–2000,“ 319, writes that it was the 1907 law on leasehold that demanded written contracts for the first time, although acknowledging that this could be negotiated out of the contract, while legal historian Bäärnhielm, “Arrende och agrarpolitik,“ 53, mentions the 1943 law as the moment when written contracts were required.

37. Lundqvist, “Striden om en modern arrendelag,” 48–9. Although in an unpublished bachelor thesis, it is to my knowledge the only detailed study of the debate concerning the 1907 leasehold law. She concludes with clear references that the 1907 law did not demand written contracts, although it was one of the most desired changes in the debate. However, in some cases written contracts had a stronger legal validity. Cf Tranberg, Ringsakboka III, 170–1 finds that written contracts were demanded in 1750 for crofts on common land, and in 1792 for crofts on enclosed land.

38. Jacobsen, Husbondret, 111ff.

39. Sw: “ömsesidig uppsägning”. See note 8.

40. See Olsson, “Manorial Economy”; Olofsson, Tullbergska rörelsen, on evictions of tenant farmers in southern Sweden during the 19th century. Cf. Peltonen, “Från osäkerhet till hat“ for the analysis that the dissatisfaction among crofters was one reason for the Finnish civil war.

41. The expression ’home-made termination clauses’ comes from Bäärnhielm, “Arrende och agrarpolitik,“ 50 (’”hemmagjorda” uppsägningsklausuler’). See also Undén, Arrendators rättigheter, 11–3.

42. General law 1734, Jordabalken, ch. 16, §2–3; Wahlberg, Om lega af jord, 158–9.

43. Bäärnhielm, “Arrende och agrarpolitik,” 46–50; Lundqvist, “Striden om en modern arrendelag“; Edling, Det fosterländska hemmet, 63–9, 179–83; SFS 1907:36.

44. SFS 1907:36, §17; Lundqvist, “Striden om en modern arrendelag,“ 46–8. Once again, different scholars presents divergent statements about the content of this compensation. Morell, Jordbruket i industrisamhället, 70, says that crofters were compensated, while Wästfelt, “Arrende och annan nyttjanderätt,“ 23, says they were not. Probably the weak compromise is the reason for this diverging statements.

45. Bäärnhielm, “Arrende och agrarpolitik,“ 51; Undén, Arrendators rättigheter, 5–6.

46. SFS 1918:569.

47. Sw: “… samt skall brukaren när så påfordras utgöra öfver-dagsverken“ (bold in original). GLA, Torpaarkivet C22, F2:4 (the same wording in many contracts in this file, but see for example contract signed by crofter Frans Johansson 28 Nov 1887).

48. Olsson, Storgodsdrift.

49. Servant Acts 1739 art. 7 §1; 1805 art. 2 §3, art. 3 §6; 1833 art. 2 §5, art. 3 §10.

50. Sw: ansvara för ”all åbyggnads underhållande, jordens häfd och dikning, samt ägornas hägnande”; ”156 Mansdagsverken”; ”8 Qvins dito”; ”postförning […] i tur med det öfriga godset, såsom tillförene”; ”dagsverken, körslor samt kolningar utöfver hvad här är bestämdt, åligger brukaren, efter erhållande befallning, verkställa efter nedanstående betalning”; ”åligger Brukaren, om så påfordras, verkställa sommarkolningar och kolen framköra till Bruket”; ”Brukaren åligger att tillse freden å skogen”; ”håller till arbetet erforderlig redskap”; ”Brukaren åligger sjelf alla personella utskylder till Kronan och Prest m. m. […] samt brandstodsafgiften”. Contract signed by Eric Ericsson 12 March 1864, GLA, Ryholms gård C111:1, vol F1:3.

51. Uppenberg, I husbondens bröd, 97–105, 147–54.

52. There are few mentions of crofters in the Diet’s minutes. In 1812 the estate of the clergy mentions the decree regulating crofters corvée labour to the priest, which they did instead of paying tithes, however this led to no debate and no decision, and I have not included it since it does not deal with the relation between landowner and crofter although it was a part of crofters’ total workload. In 1817/1818 and in 1823, there were memoranda from the peasant farmer estate about the relation between poor laws, servant acts and crofters. The peasant farmer MP stated that too many crofters would lead to impoverishment and increased costs for poor relief. This was not debated and the committee rejected the memorandum by stating that there were already enough regulations against taking in too many workers. Finally, in 1850/1851, there was a discussion on older crofters duty to pay a certain tax, mantalspenningar. Register for minutes from the Diet of the Four Estates, 1809–1866, search term ’crofter’ (Torpare), 869–70.

53. Minutes from the Estate of the Nobility, April 29, 1731, 249. See also Riksarkivet, Svenska riksdagsakter, 6–7; Minutes from the Estate of the Peasant Farmers, April 29 1731, 187–8; General law of Sweden 1734, The Building Code (Byggningabalken), ch. 23 §2.

54. Winroth, Svensk civilrätt, 15–24.

55. See note 8.

56. Winroth, Svensk civilrätt, 20–4.

57. See note 8; Nordström, ”Kvinnans roll”.

58. See for example Schönberg, Bref til C.R.W.H.H.A., who considered that servants were free enough, debating this with for example Chydenius, Swar på den af. I have analysed this debate in Uppenberg, I husbondens bröd, 205–18.

59. Tisell, I arbetarefrågan, 33–4.

60. Tisell, Om en tidsenlig arrendelag; Wästfelt, “Arrende och annan nyttjanderätt,” 23; Tisell, Äro några förändringar önskvärda; Utterström, Jordbrukets arbetare, 781–9.

61. SFS 1907:36; Lundqvist, ”Striden om en modern arrendelag,” 50–1.

62. Olsson, “Varför har Sverige,” 77–8.

63. SFS 883:1943 § 45–46; Skarstedt, Ekberg, and Anderberg, Arrendelagstiftningen av år 1943, 25, 76.

64. Steinfeld, The Invention of Free Labor, 55–7.

65. Sw: “Brukaren förbinder sig, att icke allenast sjelf vara trogen, flitig, nykter, lydig och höflig emot husbonden eller den i hans ställe förer dess bud och befallningar, utan ock att hålla sitt folk till detsamma, och ansvara för dess uppförande”. For example a contract signed by Sven Andersson in 1843, GLA, Ryholms gård C111:1, vol. F1:1. This was a common wording in the contracts, see also contracts in GLA, Torpaarkivet F3:1–4 and LLA, Knutstorps godsarkiv SE/LLA/31031 C:1:1–5 (the latter kindly made available to me by professor Mats Olsson, Lund University). See also a compilation on this demand in tenant farmers’ contracts in Olsson, Storgodsdrift, 97.

66. Markkola and Östman, “Torparfrågan tillspetsas”.

67. Jacobsen, Husbondret, 124–7.

68. Scherp, De ofrälse och makten, 230–45.

69. Sw: ”små förbrytelser, upstudsigheter och försummelser”, Noble privilegies 1723 §31.

70. SFS 1864:11.

71. Uppenberg, ”Masters Writing the Rules,” 251–5.

72. Royal decree 16 July 1776 regarding punishment for harming masters. Quotations in Swedish: ”Tjenstehion eller Underhafwande”; ”til trohet emot honom [husbonden] äro besynnerligen förbundne”; ”enskildte Tienare, Bönder eller Torpare, hwilka betiena med arbete eller dagswerken”.

73. SFS 1841:21.

74. Jordabalken ch. 16, §7–8; Servant Act 1739 art. 6 §4, 1805 art. 8 §8, 1833 art. 8 §52.

75. SFS 1845:11.

76. See note 65.

77. Wahlberg, Om lega af jord, 142–43; Utterström, Jordbrukets arbetare, 825. It was possible to demand labour services in contract even after 1943, but only for cash payment, not as part of the leasehold. This means the contract resembled an ‘ordinary’ labour contract, SFS 883:1943 § 45–6.

78. Cf. Vilhelmsson in this Special issue.

79. See also Sogner, “Freeholder and Cottar” for a theoretical discussion on the role of crofts and cottages in stratification.

References

  • LLA (Landsarkivet i Lund, Swedish National Archives in Lund), Knutstorps godsarkiv.
  • GLA (Landsarkivet i Göteborg, Swedish National Archives in Gothenburg), Torpaarkivet.
  • GLA, Ryholms gård.
  • Riksdagstryck: Sources from the Diet of the four estates (chronological order)
  • Minutes from the Estate of the Nobility, printed as Sveriges ridderskaps och adels riksdagsprotokoll från och med år 1719, sjätte delen, första häftet, 1731 års protokoll, Stockholm: Kongl. Boktryckeriet, P.A. Norstedt & söner, 1881.
  • Minutes from the Estate of the Peasant Farmers, printed as Bondeståndets riksdagsprotokoll, på Riksgäldskontorets uppdrag utgivna av Sten Landahl, vol 2 1731–1734, Uppsala: Almqvist & Wiksell Boktryckeri AB, 1945.
  • Register for minutes from the Diet of the Four Estates, 1809–1866, printed as Sakregister till rikets ständers protokoll med bihang för tiden från och med 1809 till och med 1866, andra bandet L-Ö, Stockholm: Central-tryckeriet, 1892–1893.
  • Minutes from the Diet 1817/1818 (Electronically available at riksdagstryck.kb.se)
  • Law texts: Svensk författningssamling (SFS) (chronological order)
  • Servant Act 23 Nov. 1686. Kongl. Maj:ts stadga och förordning, angående tienstefolck och legohjon, samt åtskillige härtils där wid förelupne missbruk och oordningar. Dat. Stockholm den 23 novemb. anno 1686.
  • Royal decree 3 June 1719 regarding peasantry’s appeal. Kongl. Maj:ts Nådige Resolution och Förklaring, Uppå de allmänne beswär och klage Puncter som des trogne Undersåtare, af Riksens menige Allmoge uti Swerige och Finland, hos Kongl. Maj:t igenom sine til denne wäl öfwerståndne Riks-Dagen Utskickade Fullmächtige, i underdånighet ingifwa och andraga låtit. Gifwen Stockholm den 3 Junii 1719.
  • Noble privileges 1723. Privilegia utaf then stormächtigste Konung Friedrich, Sweriges, Göthes och Wändes Konung, stadfästade Sweriges Rikes Ridderskap och Adel, uppå Riksdagen i Stockholm åhr 1723.
  • Servant Act 6 Aug. 1723. Kongl. Maij:ts förnyade stadga och förordning angående tienstefolck och lego-hjon, gifwen Stockholm i rådkammaren den 6 augusti, 1723.
  • General Law of Sweden 1734, the Land Code (Jordabalken).
  • General Law of Sweden 1734, the Building Code (Byggningabalken).
  • Servant Act 21 Aug. 1739. Kongl. Maj:ts förnyade stadga och förordning, angående tienstefolck och legohion. Gifwen Stockholm i råd cammaren then 21 augusti, 1739.
  • Royal letter 18 Feb. 1757 regarding croft establishment. Kongl. Maj:ts Nådige Bref Til Samtelige Landshöfdingarne, angående Torps och Nybyggens anläggande på Hemmans Ägor, 18 feb 1757.
  • Royal decree 20 July 1762 regarding married servants. Kongl. Maj:ts Nådige Förordning, At Jord-Ägare och Hemmans brukare å Landet måge för Gifte Legohjon, å sine Ägor, upbygga Backstufwor och Boningsrum, 20 juli 1762.
  • Royal decree 25 July 1764 regarding crofters’ servants. Kongl. Maj:ts Nådige Förordning, Angående huruwida Torpare måge få nyttja Tienstefolk eller mantalsskrefne Barn sig til hjelp. Gifwen Drottningsholm i Råd-Cammaren then 25 Junii 1764.
  • Royal decree 8 March 1770 regarding improved agriculture. Kongl. Maj:ts förordning, angående upmuntringar till jordbrukets uphjelpande, 8 March 1770.
  • Royal decree 16 July 1776 regarding punishment for harming masters. Kongl. Maj:ts Nådiga Förordning, Om Straffets skärpande för Frälse-Bönder, Torpare och Drängar, hwilka, i upsåt, at hämnas förmente oförrätter, eller at stiäla, af stadgadt råd, i försåt, söka att afhända theras Husbonde-folk lifwet. Gifwen Ekolsund then 16 Julii 1776.
  • Royal decree 21 Feb. 1789 regarding sales of Crown land to freehold. Kongl. Maj:ts Nådiga Förordning, om Krono-Hemmans försäljande til Skatte samt the Förmoner och Wilkor, hwarunder Skatte-Hemman hädanefter skola innehafwas. Gifwen Stockholms Slott then 21 Februarii 1789.
  • Royal confirmation 4 April 1789 of the rights of the peasantry. Kongl. Maj:ts Öpna och Nådiga Försäkran och Stadfästelse å Swenska och Finska Allmogens Fri- och Rättigheter, 4 April 1789.
  • Royal decree 13 June 1800 regarding leasehold. Kongl. Maj:ts Nådiga Förordning På hwad sätt Med Städsel och Lego af Jord på Landet, hädanefter förhållas bör. Gifwen Norrköpings Slott på Riks-Salen den 13 Junii 1800.
  • Servant Act 15 May 1805. Kongl. Maj:ts nådiga lego-stadga för husbönder och tjenstehjon. Gifwen Stockholms slott den 15 maji, 1805.
  • Servant Act 23 Nov. 1833. Kongl. Maj:ts förnyade nådiga lego-stadga för husbönder och tjenstehjon: gifwen Stockholms slott den 23 november, 1833.
  • SFS 1841:21 regarding punishment for assaulting masters. Kongl. Maj:ts Nådiga Förordning angående straff för husbondefolks försåtliga öfwerfallande: Gifwen Stockholms Slott å Riks-Salen den 10 Juni 1841.
  • SFS 1845:11 regarding changes in the Land Code §7-8. Kongl. Maj:ts Nådiga Förordning, om ändring af 7 § och upphäfwande af 8 § i 16 Kapitlet Jorda-Balken; Gifwen Stockholms Slott å Rikssalen 19 Maj 1845.
  • SFS 1864:11 new penal code. Kongl. Maj:ts Ny Strafflag, Stockholms slott 16 Februari 1864.
  • SFS 1907:36 law on usufruct to real estate property. Lag om nyttjanderätt till fast egendom, given Stockholms slott den 14 juni 1907.
  • SFS 1918:569 law on the right to buy in crofts. Lag om rätt i vissa fall för nyttjanderättshavare att inlösa under nyttjanderätt upplåtet område, given Stockholms slott den 28 juni 1918.
  • SFS 1943:883 changes in the 1907:36 law. Lag angående ändring i vissa delar av lagen d. 14 juni 1907 (nr 36 s. 1) om nyttjanderätt till fast egendom, 22 december 1943.
  • Ågren, Maria, ed. Making a Living, Making a Difference: Gender and Work in Early Modern European Society. New York: Oxford University Press, 2017.
  • Arnberg, Klara, Eirinn Larsen, and Ann-Catrin Östman. “Gender and Economic History in the Nordic Countries.” Scandinavian Economic History Review 70, no. 2 (2022): 113–122. doi:10.1080/03585522.2022.2078403.
  • Bäärnhielm, Mauritz. “Arrende och agrarpolitik i Sverige. En historisk översikt.” In Att bruka men inte äga. Arrende och annan nyttjanderätt till mark i svenskt jordbruk från medeltid till idag, edited by Anders Wästfelt, 40–60. Stockholm: Kungl. Skogs– och lantbruksakademien, 2014.
  • Bäck, Kalle. Början till slutet: laga skiftet och torpbebyggelsen i Östergötland 1827–65. Borensberg: Noteria, 1992.
  • Bengtsson, Erik and Patrick Svensson. “The Living Standards of the Labouring Classes in Sweden, 1750–1900: Evidence from Rural Probate Inventories.” The Agricultural History Review 70, no. 1 (2022): 49–69.
  • Boydston, Jeanne. “Gender as a Question of Historical Analysis.” Gender & History 20, no. 3 (2008): 558–583. doi:10.1111/j.1468-0424.2008.00537.x.
  • Christensen, Jan. “Radikalism som strategi. Bondepolitik vid 1800-talets mitt.” Historisk tidskrift 126, no. 4 (2006): 727–747.
  • Chydenius, Anders. Swar på den af Kgl. Wetenskaps academien förestälta frågan: Hwad kan wara orsaken, at sådan myckenhet swenskt folk årligen flytter utur landet? och genom hwad författningar det kan bäst förekommas? Inlemnat år 1763; men nu allmänhetens granskning underkastadt. Stockholm: Peter Hesselberg, 1765.
  • Dørum, Knut. “Fikk overgangen til selveie betydning for fremveksten av husmannsvesenet ca. 1660–1850?” Historisk tidsskrift Norge 74, no. 2 (1995): 145–170.
  • Dribe, Martin, Mats Olsson, and Patrick Svensson. “The Agricultural Revolution and the Conditions of the Rural Poor, Southern Sweden, 1750–1860.” The Economic History Review 70, no. 2 (2017): 483–508. doi:10.1111/ehr.12378.
  • Dyrvik, Ståle. “Husmannsvesenet i Norge - regionale mønster.“ In Huse og husmænd i fortid, nutid og fremtid: småbrugets udbredelse of vilkår i Norden, edited by Per Grau Møller and Helle Damsgaard, 93–105. Odense: Universitetsforlag, 1989.
  • Edling, Nils. Det fosterländska hemmet: egnahemspolitik, småbruk och hemideologi kring sekelskiftet 1900. Stockholm: Carlsson, 1996.
  • Elgeskog, Valter. Svensk torpbebyggelse från 1500-talet till laga skiftet: en agrarhistorisk studie. Stockholm: LT förlag, 1945.
  • Gadd, Carl-Johan. “The Agricultural Revolution in Sweden 1700–1870.” In The Agrarian History of Sweden. From 4000 BC to AD 2000, edited by Janken Myrdal and Mats Morell, 118–164. Lund: Nordic Academic Press, 2011.
  • Gadolin, A.W. Öfversikt af jordlegorättens historiska utveckling uti den svensk-finska lagstiftningen. Helsingfors: Kejserliga senatens tryckeri, 1912.
  • Heimen. Tidsskrift for lokal og regional historie 41, no. 2 (2004): Special Issue on crofters (husmenn).
  • Henningsen, Peter. Stavnsbåndet: 100 Danmarkshistorier. Aarhus: Aarhus Universitetsforlag, 2020.
  • Hyrenius, Hannes. SOU 1944:65 Jordbrukets framtida tillgång på arbetskraft. Utredning verkställd på uppdrag av 1942 års jordbrukskommitté. Stockholm: Jordbruksdepartementet, 1944. https://weburn.kb.se/metadata/754/SOU_1428754.htm.
  • Jacobsen, Anette Faye. Husbondret: Rettighedskulturer i Danmark 1750–1920. København: Museum Tusculanums forlag, Københavns universitet, 2007.
  • Jonsson, Ulf. Jordmagnater, landbönder och torpare i sydöstra Södermanland 1800–1880. PhD thesis., Stockholm University, Almqvist & Wiksell [in Komm.], 1980.
  • Jónsson, Gudmundur. “Institutional Change in Icelandic Agriculture, 1780–1940.” Scandinavian Economic History Review 41, no. 2 (1993): 101–128. doi:10.1080/03585522.1993.10415863.
  • Kook Lyngholm, Dorte. “Absolute Obedience: Servants and Masters on Danish Estates in the Nineteenth Century.” International Review of Social History 68, no. S31 (2023): 177–195. doi:10.1017/S0020859022000918.
  • Lagerqvist, Maja. Torpets transformationer: materialitet, representation och praktik från år 1850 till 2010. PhD thesis Stockholm University, 2011. http://nbn-resolving.de/urn:nbn:se:su:diva-61861.
  • Lindström, Jonas. “Skattelandbor och hälftenbrukare. Jordägare och arrende under 1600- och 1700-talen.” In Att bruka men inte äga. Arrende och annan nyttjanderätt till mark i svenskt jordbruk från medeltid till idag, edited by Anders Wästfelt, 61–73. Stockholm: Kungl. Skogs– och lantbruksakademien, 2014.
  • Lindström, Jonas. “Labouring Poor in Early Modern Sweden? Crofters and Lodgers in Västmanland in the 17th Century.” Scandinavian Journal of History 44, no. 4 (2019): 403–429. doi:10.1080/03468755.2018.1532926.
  • Lundh, Christer and Mats Olsson. “Tenancy Contracts in Scania from the Middle Ages to the Nineteenth Century.” In The Development of Leasehold in Northwestern Europe, C. 1200–1600, edited by Bas van Bavel and Phillipp R. Schofield, 113–137. Turnhout: Brepols, 2008.
  • Lundqvist, Annacarin. “Striden om en modern arrendelag 1891–1907: agrar socialpolitik och jordägarintressen i riksdagen.” Unpublished thesis, Stockholm University, 1992.
  • Magnusson, Lars. Ty som ingenting angelägnare är än mina bönders conservation: godsekonomi i östra Mellansverige vid mitten av 1700-talet. PhD thesis Uppsala University, Stockholm: Almqvist & Wiksell, 1980.
  • Markkola, Pirjo and Ann-Catrin Östman. “Torparfrågan tillspetsas. Frigörelse, oberoende och arbete – 1918 års torparlagstiftning ur mansperspektiv.” Historisk Tidskrift för Finland 97, no. 1 (2012): 17–41.
  • Marx, Karl. Capital: A Critique of Political Economy. Vol. 1: The Process of Production of Capital. Translated from the Third German Edition by Samuel Moore and Edward Edited by Friedrich Engels, London: Electric book Co, 2001. https://ebookcentral.proquest.com/lib/sub/detail.action?docID=3008518.
  • Morell, Mats. Jordbruket i industrisamhället, 1870–1945. Svenska jordbrukets historia, bd. 4. Stockholm: Natur och Kultur/LTs förlag i samarbete med Nordiska museets förlag och Stiftelsen Lagersberg, 2001.
  • Morell, Mats. “Agriculture in Industrial Society, 1870–1945.” In The Agrarian History of Sweden. From 4000 BC to AD 2000, edited by Janken Myrdal and Mats Morell, 165–213. Lund: Nordic Academic Press, 2011.
  • Myrdal, Janken and Mats Morell, eds. The Agrarian History of Sweden: From 4000 BC to 2000 AD. Lund: Nordic Academic Press, 2011.
  • Næss, Hans Eyvind. “The Crofters as a Social Group in South-Western Norway: The Early Phase 1590–1660.” Pathways of the Past. Essays in Honour of Sølvi Sogner, edited by Hilde Sandvik, Kari Telste, and Gunnar Thorvaldsen, 125–138. Oslo: Novus forlag, 2002.
  • Nordström, Olof. “Kvinnans roll i de sydsvenska brukens arbetsorganisation under preindustriell tid.” Rapporter och notiser. Lund: Institutionen för kulturgeografi och ekonomisk geografi vid Lunds universitet (1988).
  • Nordström, Olof. “Torp och backstugebebyggelsens framväxt i den sydsvenska skogs- och bruksbygden.” In Huse og husmænd i fortid, nutid og fremtid: småbrugets udbredelse of vilkår i Norden, edited by Per Grau Møller and Helle Damsgaard, 63–69. Odense: Odense Universitetsforlag, 1989.
  • Nyström, Lars. Potatisriket: Stora Bjurum 1857–1917: jorden, makten, samhället. PhD thesis University of Gothenburg, 2003.
  • Olofsson, Magnus. Tullbergska rörelsen: striden om den skånska frälsejorden 1867–1869. PhD thesis Lund University: Sekel, 2008.
  • Olsson, Mats. Varför har Sverige saknat en jordreform?” In Att bruka men inte äga. Arrende och annan nyttjanderätt till mark i svenskt jordbruk från medeltid till idag edited by Anders Wästfelt 74–83. Stockholm: Kungl. Skogs- och lantbruksakademien, 2014.
  • Olsson, Mats. Storgodsdrift: godsekonomi och arbetsorganisation i Skåne från dansk tid till mitten av 1800-talet. PhD thesis Lund University, Stockholm: Almqvist & Wiksell, 2002.
  • Olsson, Mats. “Manorial Economy and Corvée Labour in Southern Sweden 1650–1850.” The Economic History Review 59, no. 3 (2006): 481–497. doi:10.1111/j.1468-0289.2006.00336.x.
  • Olsson, Mats and Mats Morell. “Scandinavia, 1750–2000.” In In Social Relations: Property and Power, edited by Bas van Bavel and Richard Hoyle, 315–347. Turnhout: Brepols, 2010.
  • Östman, Ann-Catrin. “Gendered Understandings of Agrarian Population in Early Finnish Social Studies.” In In Experts We Trust: Knowledge, Politics and Bureaucracy in Nordic Welfare States, edited by Åsa Lundqvist and Klaus Petersen, 249–268. Odense: University Press of Southern Denmark, 2010.
  • Østrem, Nils Olav. En kort introduksjon til husmannsvesenet. Oslo: Cappelen Damm, 2022.
  • Peltonen, Matti. “Från osäkerhet till hat. Torparfrågans moraliska ekonomi i sekelskiftets Finland.” Bebyggelsehistorisk tidskrift: Småjordbrukets tid. Småbruk och egnahem under de senaste hundra åren 35 (1998): 91–98.
  • Persson, Christer. “Något om torp och torpare i Locknevi socken. En longitudinell studie av torpare på några utvalda torp i norra Småland 1800–1900.” In Huse og husmænd i fortid, nutid og fremtid: småbrugets udbredelse of vilkår i Norden, edited by Per Grau Møller and Helle Damsgaard, 71–92. Odense: Odense Universitetsforlag, 1989.
  • Prestesæter, Pål. Husmannskontrakter og lovregulering: regulering av avtaleforholdet mellom husmann og gårdbruker 1687 til 1851 – særlig sett i lys av kontraktspraksis fra Toten. Oslo: Institutt for offentlig rett, Univ. i Oslo, 1998.
  • Riksarkivet. Svenska riksdagsakter jämte andra handlingar som höra till statsförfattningens historia Ser. 2 Tidehvarfet 1719-1800, D. 3. Afd. 1 1731–1734. Utgifven af Riksarkivet genom Theodor Westrin. Stockholm: Norstedt, 1917. https://weburn.kb.se/riks/metadata/76/21799176.html.
  • Scherp, Joakim. De ofrälse och makten: en institutionell studie av riksdagen och de ofrälse ståndens politik i maktdelningsfrågor 1660–1682. PhD. thesis Stockholm University, 2013.
  • Schönberg, Anders. Bref til C.R.W.H.H.A. i anledning af sacellanens wid Nedervitil capell, herr magister Anders Chydenii af trycket utgifna swar til Kongl. Wetenskaps academiens, om orsakerna til swenska folkets utflyttning. Stockholm: Kongl. tryckeriet, 1765.
  • Scott, Joan W. “Gender: A Useful Category of Historical Analysis.” The American Historical Review 91, no. 5 (1986): 1053–1075. doi:10.2307/1864376.
  • Skarstedt, Sigfrid, Seve Ekberg, and Einar Anderberg. Arrendelagstiftningen av år 1943: kommentar. Stockholm: Norstedt, 1945.
  • Sogner, Sølvi. “Freeholder and Cottar. Property Relationships and the Social Structure in the Peasant Community in Norway During the Eighteenth Century.” Scandinavian Journal of History 1, no. 1–4 (1976): 181–199. doi:10.1080/03468757608578902.
  • SOU 1946:42 Riktlinjer för den framtida jordbrukspolitiken. Betänkande, avgivet av 1942 års jordbrukskommitté. Del 1. Stockholm: Jordbruksdepartementet, 1946. https://weburn.kb.se/metadata/265/SOU_2013265.htm.
  • Steinfeld, Robert J. The Invention of Free Labor: The Employment Relation in English and American Law and Culture, 1350–1870. Chapel Hill: University of North Carolina Press, 1991.
  • Svensson, Eva, Hilde Rigmor Amundsen, Ingunn Holm, Hans Hulling, Annie Johansson, Jan Löfgren, Pia Nilsson, Stefan Nilsson, Susanne Pettersson, and Vigdis Stensby. “Empowering Marginal Lifescapes: The Heritage of Crofters in Between the Past and the Present.” International Journal of Heritage Studies 24, no. 1 (2018): 17–34. doi:10.1080/13527258.2017.1362579.
  • Tisell, Halvar. I Arbetarefrågan med afseende fäst på jordbruksarbetaren. Linköping: C. F. Ridderstads boktryckeri, 1885.
  • Tisell, Halvar. Om en tidsenlig arrendelag. Ett anförande vördsamt tillegnadt Södermanlands läns kongl. hushållningssälskap. Nyköping: Gustafsson & Hellmans boktryckeri, 1885.
  • Tisell, Halvar. Äro några förändringar önskvärda i afseende å nu vanligen gällande bestämmelser rörande jordarrende? Föredrag vid Kongl. Landtbruks–Akademiens sammankomst 19/10 1891. Stockholm: Aftryck ur Landtbruks-Akademiens Handlingar och Tidskrift, 1892.
  • Tranberg, Anna. “‘Ledighed taales ikke’. Plassfamilien på gardsarbeid.” Historisk tidsskrift Norge 69, no. 4 (1990): 512–536.
  • Tranberg, Anna. Ringsakboka III: korn og klasseskille 1660–1840. Bygdebok for Brøttum, Veldre, Ringsaker. Moelv: Ringsaker historielag, 1993.
  • Undén, Östen. Arrendators rättigheter enligt 1907 års allmänna arrendelag: en populär framställning. Stockholm: Tiden, 1916.
  • Uppenberg, Carolina. I husbondens bröd och arbete: kön, makt och kontrakt i det svenska tjänstefolkssystemet 1730–1860. PhD thesis University of Gothenburg, 2018. https://gupea.ub.gu.se/handle/2077/55921.
  • Uppenberg, Carolina. “Masters Writing the Rules: How Peasant Farmer MPs in the Swedish Estate Diet Understood Servants’ Labour and the Labour Laws, 1823–1863.” The Agricultural History Review 68, no. 2 (2020): 238–256.
  • Uppenberg, Carolina and Malin Nilsson. Manuscript under review: “The Crofter is a Woman. How Gendered Divisions of Labour Shaped Proletarianization, Sweden 1800–1900.” The Economic History Review.
  • Utterström, Gustaf. Jordbrukets arbetare: levnadsvillkor och arbetsliv på landsbygden från frihetstiden till mitten av 1800-talet. Del 1. Stockholm: Tiden, 1957.
  • van Bavel, Bas and Richard Hoyle. “Introduction: Social Relations, Property and Power in the North Sea Area, 500–2000.” In Social Relations: Property and Power, edited by Bas van Bavel and Richard Hoyle, 1–23. Turnhout: Brepols, 2010.
  • Wahlberg, Casper Johan. Om lega af jord å landet enligt svensk civilrätt. PhD thesis Uppsala University, 1870.
  • Wästfelt, Anders. “Arrende och annan nyttjanderätt till mark i lantbrukets historia.” In Att bruka men inte äga. Arrende och annan nyttjanderätt till mark i svenskt jordbruk från medeltid till idag, edited by Anders Wästfelt, 15–39. Stockholm: Kungl. Skogs– och lantbruksakademien, 2014.
  • Winberg, Christer. “Another Route to Modern Society. The Advancement of the Swedish Peasantry.” In Agrarian Society in History. Essays in Honour of Magnus Mörner, edited by Mats Lundahl and Thommy Svensson, 48–67. London; New York: Routledge, 1990.
  • Winroth, Alfred Ossian. Svensk civilrätt Vol. 2 Äktenskaps rättsverkningar Stockholm: Norstedt, 1901.
  • Wohlin, Nils. Emigrationsutredningen, Bilaga 11, Torpare-, backstugu- och inhysesklasserna: öfversikt af deras uppkomst, tillväxt och aftagande med särskild hänsyn till torparklassens undergräfvande. Stockholm: Norstedt, 1908.