743
Views
4
CrossRef citations to date
0
Altmetric
Articles

A categorisation and evaluation of rhino management policies

&

ABSTRACT

Rhino populations are at a critical level and new approaches are needed to ensure their survival. This study conducts a review and categorisation of policies for the management of rhinos. Twenty-seven policies are identified and classified into in-situ (reserve-based) and ex-situ (market-based) policies. The policies are then evaluated based on four target areas: poachers/hunters, consumers, intermediaries and the game reserves themselves. The study finds that protected area management policies seem most beneficial in the short run, in particular the enforcement of private property rights over resource utilisation, as well as the establishment of wildlife sanctuaries that act as sustainable breeding grounds for rhino populations.

1. Introduction

The threat of the ongoing and intense levels of rhino poaching on the continued survival of rhinos around the world is a cause of great concern (Kagande & Musarurwa, Citation2014). South Africa is regarded as the major custodian of the world’s remaining African rhino populations (‘t sas-Rolfes, Citation2012), conserving 93% of Africa’s White Rhino population and 41% of Black Rhinos alive today (Emslie & Knight, Citation2014). Rhino horns, made of keratin, are a sought-after commodity on the Asian markets, notably Vietnam and China (Milliken & Shaw, Citation2012) and are used in traditional medicine, hence the market for rhino horns. Rhino horn poaching in South Africa has escalated dramatically in the past five years. In 2014, 1215 rhinos were poached, up from 83 in 2008 (DEA, Citation2015). If such trends continue, South Africa’s free-roaming rhino population could be extinct in the next 20 years (Di Minin et al., Citation2015). Radical solutions are required to stem the illicit slaughter of these majestic animals.

Much of the current debate around rhino management and associated policy recommendations are based on economic principles (e.g. Bulte & Damania, Citation2005; Biggs et al., Citation2012; Collins et al., Citation2013). In that regard a number of policy instruments have been recommended to either change the behaviour of market participants, the behaviour of intermediaries or the behaviour of poachers. At the same time, traditional wildlife management policies that include in-situ management of wildlife resources should certainly not be neglected. The challenge, therefore, is to analyse policies within a holistic framework (Kagande & Musarurwa, Citation2014) which takes both economic as well as traditional wildlife policies into consideration, as well as the different participants in the rhino horn supply chain. One way of doing this is by drawing on the literature of illegal exploitation (Clark, Citation1990). The literature of illegal exploitation emphasises, amongst others, the modification of hunter incentives, and illegal exploitation as an economic activity (Milner-Gulland & Leader-Williams, Citation1992). The literature is therefore aligned with the current economic emphases in rhino conservation, while at the same time expounding on the contribution of in-situ management of natural resources.

The approach of this study, therefore, is to identify, categorise and evaluate policies for rhino conservation across a wide range of target groups and type of policies. While most research so far has focused on one or a few aspects of rhino management, this article makes a unique contribution to the literature by using a holistic framework that takes into consideration wildlife, bio-economic and economic policies drawn from the aforementioned literature of illegal exploitation. The approach undertaken is as follows: first, a framework for categorising policies is presented; second, a selection of policies from each policy category is discussed with reference to rhino conservation; and third, recommendations are made on the way forward.

2. Typology of wildlife policies

The framework used to classify different rhino conservation policies is based on Crookes & Milner-Gulland (Citation2006). This framework considers firstly the incidence of the policy (who is targeted – consumers, game reserves or poachers), and then asks a number of key questions associated with each category of policy (see ). The key question related to direct market interventions, for example, is whether it affects the use of rhino horns by consumers in Asian countries. Another example is the set of policies targeting poachers that is evaluated on whether the poacher’s behaviour is affected. This framework recognises the need to compensate those who are adversely affected, through the promotion of alternative livelihood activities.

Table 1. Framework for policy evaluation

Table 1 presents a framework for a meta-analysis of policies. Policies are defined very broadly in this study to encompass all intentional acts that aim at affecting the behaviour of target groups. These policies therefore include international, national, provincial and local legislation, as well as non-legislative policies such as ‘moral suasion’, and include both the legislative instrument as well as the ‘will’ by all parties to adhere to the policy (see for example McHenry, Citation1993). This definition of policy is therefore different from the use of policy in the traditional sense, in that it includes binding and non-binding instruments, as well as strategies. The policies target four groups: consumers, game reserves, hunters/poachers and the whole supply chain. Although the framework identifies 27 potential policies, these are in fact clustered within two groups: in-situ policies and ex-situ policies. By in-situ policies we mean policies aimed at the hunting locality itself, which include policies of game reserves as well as hunters/poachers. Ex-situ policies are those aimed at the markets. We will now consider how these relate to rhino conservation.

3. Application to rhino poaching

3.1 Ex-situ (market) policies

Market policies are those that target Asian consumers of rhino horns. Two market policies are discussed in greater depth: trade bans and consumer behaviour modification.

The Convention on International Trade in Endangered Species established a trade ban on rhino horn in an attempt to reduce the demand (CITES, Citation2013). However, it seems that rising incomes in Asian countries, in particular Vietnam, are actually increasing demand (Milliken & Shaw, Citation2012). Consequently, the price of rhino horn has risen so dramatically that it rivals the value of other high-value goods such as gold and narcotics (Biggs et al., Citation2012). The standard economic argument for lifting the trade ban is that the resultant increase in rhino horn supply would flood the market, thereby reducing its price.

While lifting the trade ban attempts to target consumer demand through price, another means of targeting consumer demand is by affecting behaviour (Litchfield, Citation2013). This is achieved by educating consumers through, for example, marketing campaigns that highlight the negative aspects of poaching or demonstrating the absence of any medical benefits of rhino horns.

As noted previously, the important question here is whether these policies will affect consumer behaviour. The reality of the situation is that the effect of such policies on demand is uncertain (Collins et al., Citation2013). Given the uncertainties and therefore risks associated with these and other market policies, it is necessary to consider other policy options as well. It is thus necessary to consider in-situ management options that target poachers and traders directly. These will be considered in the next section.

3.2 In-situ management

In-situ management consists of both protected area management as well as hunter behaviour modification. The difference between these two factors is that the first is implemented by reserve managers while the second is enforced by wildlife authorities. Under protected area management, two policies will be discussed: extreme command and control measures, and enforcing private property rights.

Command and control measures target poachers directly using military style tactics to track, identify and, if necessary, eliminate poachers in protected areas. The extreme measures proposed by Kalron (Citation2013) include doing away with scientific services at game reserves and establishing fully equipped military centres for combatting poaching. Command and control measures also include the use of biotechnologies such as acoustic traps, mobile technology, mikrokopters, radio-frequency identification tags, encrypted data digital networks, camera traps, DNA testing, radio collars, metal scanners and satellite imagery (UNEP, Citation2014). Shoot to kill strategies are argued by some (e.g. Messer, Citation2010) as the only viable policy in low-income countries with high economic benefits from endangered wildlife. Some progress has been made in this regard – for example, the recent 2014 South Africa–Mozambique hot pursuit agreement which allows South African police units to pursue poachers into Mozambique, and the 2014 Memorandum of Understanding that was signed between South Africa and Mozambique – but there remains some concerns over the commitment of the South African government to enforce these agreements given their desire to legalise the trade in rhino horns.

Command and control policies represent one in-situ policy. Another is private property regimes. Hardin’s ‘tragedy of the commons’ (Hardin, Citation1968), developed more formally in the Gordon–Schaefer bio-economic model (Clark, Citation1990), argues that ‘commons’ or open access harvesting produces less than optimal resource use compared with private property regimes. Although the theory has its criticisms, most of these criticisms revolve around the definitions of ‘commons’, where the definition of common pool resources are much broader than the open access definition of commons implied by Hardin, and includes communal resources that would not necessarily be subject to Hardin’s theory (Hardin, Citation1998; Ostrom et al., Citation1999). The important point of the theory is not the management regime that is in place, but rather the nature of the resource management that occurs within such a system which defines the nature of the common pool resource (Edwards & Steins, Citation1999). In spite of criticisms, the theory remains relevant. In a review of Hardin’s theory 22 years later, Feeny et al. (Citation1990:Citation2) conclude that ‘in the intervening years, the ideas that Hardin popularised have become the most widely accepted explanation for overexploitation of resources that are currently held’.

The open access solution is at a lower level of stock than the profit-maximising solution, and also the biological optimum of maximum sustainable yield. What this means is that a regime based on private property provides a more sustainable wildlife population compared with management levels based on open access and even biological principles. Although Crookes (Citation2016) found that profit maximising does not necessarily produce the optimal resource outcome, this theory nonetheless indicates that private property is preferred to open access from a conservation perspective.

Figure 1. Policy effect of an Anthropogenic Allee Effect Notes: At certain price ranges, the figure shows that a reduction in demand from D to D1 results in an increase in price from P to P1, and an increase in yield from Y to Y1.

Figure 1. Policy effect of an Anthropogenic Allee Effect Notes: At certain price ranges, the figure shows that a reduction in demand from D to D1 results in an increase in price from P to P1, and an increase in yield from Y to Y1.

The major consequence to emerge from Hardin’s tragedy of the commons theory is therefore that resources should not be managed as open access resources but rather that private property rights should be enforced. This can be explained with the example of a house. If there are valuables inside a house, then the private owner’s rational response is to ensure that sufficient security is in place to keep intruders out. Unfortunately, because of the size of many reserves, private property rights are difficult to enforce, and resources are effectively managed as ‘common property’, even though they might be ‘private’. What is meant by this is that entrants have relatively free access to the resource even though in a legal sense the ownership may be in private or State hands. An example is the large Transfrontier parks between South Africa and a number of its neighbouring countries. While these Transfrontier parks had the benefit of providing greater rangeland areas for South Africa’s megafauna, the removal of fences allowed free access to poachers of South Africa’s wildlife resources. Kruger National Park, one such Transfrontier park, has the highest incidences of rhino poaching in South Africa, namely 68% of all rhinos poached in 2014 were from this reserve (DEA, Citation2015). Some of the concerns with Transfrontier parks have been raised in the recent Southern African Development Community (SADC) Transfrontier Conservation Areas guidelines document (Zunckel, Citation2014), which indicates, for example, that Transfrontier Conservation Areas may not be suitable in situations of conflicting laws between neighbouring countries – in particular, in the areas of sustainable utilisation of wildlife, with hunting bans and the legalisation of the trade in rhino and ivory products specifically mentioned as areas where problems may arise (Zunckel, Citation2014:3). But this is the case not only in the public sector but also the private sector. An example is Sabi Sand game reserve, a reserve abutting Kruger National Park comprising eight private game farms (Stay in Africa, Citation2014), with no fences between the farms and no fences between the game reserve and Kruger National Park (And Beyond, Citation2014). Although in some instances fences have been re-erected (e.g. Kruger National Park), the fact that poaching has continued to escalate indicates that open access conditions still hold. There is therefore still a great need to enforce private property rights, and this requires political buy-in and commitment. In many instances, reserves are understaffed and this perpetuates the open access problem.

A third form of in-situ management involves modification of hunter behaviour; for example, through the imposition of hunting seasons, species restrictions and gear restrictions (i.e. only allowing a certain type of firearm to be used). In general these types of policies, although widespread in the fisheries industry, are less effective in the conservation of rhinos given the difficulties in enforcing these policies.

These types of policies are likely to be far more effective at reducing the supply of rhino horn to Asian markets. It is crucial, however, that social upliftment programmes also target poachers and their families. This will have the added benefit of reducing the incentive to poach.

4. Evaluation

While it is not possible to evaluate all policies within the present study, we may evaluate each broad category, namely those targeted at poachers, game reserves and consumers, and the whole supply chain.

4.1 Game reserves

The economic theory of open access resources was originally developed by HS Gordon (Citation1954) for fisheries, although it may be applied to many other biological resources where the conditions are met (Clark, Citation1990). The model utilises a logistic growth formulation for biological population growth, which was frequently by fisheries biologist MB Schaefer (Citation1957), hence the coining of the term Gordon–Schaefer model to describe this type of model (Clark, Citation1990). We develop a simple Gordon–Schaefer model for assessing the effects of varying policies (prices for horns, costs) on rhino abundance. It is then possible to estimate the equilibrium level of poaching effort under different property rights regimes. Under private property, revenues are maximised when marginal revenue equals marginal costs. Marginal revenue (MR) occurs when:

Marginal costs are equal to cost per unit effort c. Equating and re-arranging the equation gives:

where r is the intrinsic growth rate of the rhino population, q is the catchability coefficient, p is the poacher price of rhino horn and k is the carrying capacity of the rhino population.

Open access effort (EOA) is found by equating average revenue to average costs. The equation is:

Using unpublished data on rhinos we are able to provide a preliminary indication of the equilibrium levels of effort.

Under the profit maximisation regime, effort is 679 trips, whereas under open access this is 1358 trips. The 2013 effort was 1004 trips. This suggests that the enforcement of private property rights could have a significant impact on poaching effort, and could even result in the maintenance of rhino populations. Rhino abundance under open access is 54 individuals, which is below the minimum viable population for survival (Traill et al., Citation2010). Under private property rights, rhino abundance increases to 58% of the 2013 rhino population, which is a decrease but nonetheless at a sustainable level.

4.2 Poachers

Building on the analysis in the previous section, it is possible to assess the effects of varying the cost price ratio on rhino abundance at equilibrium. Open access equilibrium populations are at:

Under maximum economic yield they are at:

Therefore, using optimisation it is possible to calculate what the cost price ratio under open access would need to be to equate to the profit-maximising solution. This is estimated to be 0.583, in other words that costs need to be at least 58% of prices for the profit maximising solution to be achieved. Although current estimates of cost price ratios for poachers are anecdotal, indications from the literature suggest that this could be much lower. Data from Milner-Gulland (Citation1999) show that the cost price ratio for poachers could be closer to 0.02, implying that large changes in poacher costs and prices would be needed to achieve the same thing as could be achieved through the enforcement of property rights regimes.

4.3 Consumers

Policies aimed at consumers are less easy to evaluate. For example, there is a growing body of literature which argues that the trade in endangered species is characterised by an Anthropogenic Allee Effect (e.g. Hall et al., Citation2008). This implies that the demand curve is positive at least for certain price ranges. Under such circumstances, demand reduction strategies could actually increase yields (). Furthermore, low international transport costs could actually require massive reductions in yields to offset poaching, as observed with the ivory trade (‘t Sas-Rolfes et al., Citation2014). Furthermore, rhino horn is used for a range of different uses in Asian markets, such as traditional Chinese medicine as a status symbol, and as a food supplement (Milliken & Shaw, Citation2012). These different uses contribute different psychological benefits to consumers that are difficult to disentangle. Therefore, it is important to ascertain the true nature of the demand for rhino horn before such policies can be evaluated.

4.4 Intermediaries

The supply chain for rhino horn is characterised by a complex network of poachers, exporters, wholesalers and retailers. Poachers and exporters are in the country, while wholesalers and retailers are abroad, although this is a simplistic representation because there are a number of additional intermediaries involved, such as couriers, buyers and sellers (Milliken & Shaw, Citation2012). Although Vietnam is the primary recipient of South African rhino horns, trade links include OR Tambo airport (Johannesburg), Maputo International airport and the port of Beira (Mozambique), as well as destinations such as Bangkok (Thailand), Laos, Hong Kong and China (Milliken & Shaw, Citation2012).

The data suggest that the bulk of the earnings from rhino horns accrued to the retailers during the 1990s, but, more recently, the earnings of poachers, exporters and particularly wholesalers have increased dramatically (). Given these high prices, and a preliminary indication that the costs associated with transportation of goods are low (see previous section) and probably declining as better networks are established, we can hesitatingly conclude that price and cost modification strategies are less effective now than they were in the 1990s. However, given the complexities of these intermediary networks, further research in this area is required.

Table 2. Price of rhino horn for different suppliers.

5. Discussion and conclusions

This study has highlighted a number of policy categories: market (ex-situ) interventions, and in-situ interventions and policy mitigation measures. A summary of the evaluation outcomes is presented in (final column). The market interventions, we found, are at this stage untested and the outcomes uncertain, hence introducing a significant degree of risk, and therefore require extreme caution before implementing.

Hunter behaviour modification (an in-situ intervention) may be suitable for legal hunting and on private land. However, the vast number of rhinos killed are killed illegally and on state land. Therefore, behaviour modification may be less relevant in the context of the rhino horn trade.

Protected area management policies (an in-situ intervention) seem to hold most promise at present in the absence of better knowledge of market dynamics. One policy is already being implemented, namely poacher tracking and apprehension. Our evaluation of policies indicates that a second protected area management strategy, namely the establishment of private property rights, seems very promising and should actively be pursued.

Recent studies have indicated that while African protected areas have generally been successful in maintaining habitats, they have been less successful in mitigating the effect of human-induced declines in large mammal populations (Craigie et al., Citation2010; Geldman et al., Citation2013; Lindsey et al., Citation2014). The improvement of protected areas networks, for example through the enforcement of private property rights, is crucial to ensure the sustainability of species populations. Spatial management of wildlife has in some instances been advocated (McCullough, Citation1996). One way of achieving this is through the development of wildlife sanctuaries that act as breeding ‘sources’ for the re-establishment of wildlife populations (Arcese & Sinclair, Citation1997; Hansen & DeFries, Citation2007), and animals are translocated to less productive areas or to areas where hunting is allowed (so-called ‘sinks’). However, this policy is highly dependent on wildlife managers being able to prevent poaching in ‘source’ areas (Bennett & Robinson, Citation2000), especially given the higher densities of rhinos in those areas. A second issue is persuading hunters to by-pass more convenient hunting areas and travel further afield to hunt in ‘sink’ areas (Wilkie & Carpenter, Citation1999).

The development of wildlife sanctuaries appears to have had at least some beneficial effect on rhino conservation (Kagande & Musarurwa, Citation2014). It is important to emphasise, however, the need to reduce the impact of policies on communities dependent on poaching for income. We propose, for example, game reserve co-management or at least involvement by communities in decision-making processes, as well as the promotion of alternative livelihood activities such as livestock farming, game farming or other economic activities.

Additional information

Funding

The authors gratefully acknowledge funding from the National Research Foundation as well as funding from Economic Research Southern Africa.

References

  • And Beyond, 2014. Sabi sand game reserve. http://www.Andbeyond.com/South-Africa/Places-To-Go/Sabi-Sand-Game-Reserve.htm Accessed 2 July 2014.
  • Arcese, P & Sinclair, ARE, 1997. The role of protected areas as ecological baselines. The Journal of Wildlife Management 61, 587–602. doi: 10.2307/3802167
  • Bennett, EL & Robinson, JG, 2000. Hunting for sustainability: The start of a synthesis. In Robinson, JG & Bennett, EL (Eds.), Hunting for sustainability in tropical forests. Columbia University Press, New York, 499–519.
  • Biggs, D, Courchamp, F, Martin, R & Possingham, HP, 2012. Legal trade of Africa’s rhino horns. Science 339, 1038–1039. doi: 10.1126/science.1229998
  • Bulte, EH & Damania, R, 2005. An economic assessment of wildlife farming and conservation. Conservation Biology 19(4), 1222–1233. doi: 10.1111/j.1523-1739.2005.003413.x
  • Clark, CW, 1990. Mathematical bioeconomics: The optimal management of renewable resources. John Wiley & Sons, New York.
  • Collins, A, Fraser, G & Snowball, J, 2013. Rhino poaching: Supply and demand uncertain. Science 340, 1167. doi: 10.1126/science.340.6137.1167-a
  • CITES (Convention on International Trade in Endangered Species), 2013. Species Trade and Conservation: Rhinoceroses. Sixteenth Meeting of the Conference of the Parties, Bangkok (Thailand), 3–14 March 2013. Cop16 Doc. 54.2 (Rev. 1).
  • Craigie, ID, Baillie, JEM, Balmford, A, Carbone, C, Collen, B, Green, RE & Hutton, JM, 2010. Large mammal population declines in Africa’s protected areas. Biological Conservation 143, 2221–2228. doi: 10.1016/j.biocon.2010.06.007
  • Crookes, DJ, 2016. Trading on extinction: an open access deterrence model for the South African abalone fishery. South African Journal of Science 112(3/4), 105–113.
  • Crookes, DJ & Blignaut, JN, 2015. Debunking the myth that a legal trade will solve the rhino horn crisis: A system dynamics model for market demand. Journal for Nature Conservation 28, 11–18.
  • Crookes, DJ & Milner-Gulland, EJ, 2006. Wildlife and economic policies affecting the bushmeat trade: A framework for analysis. South African Journal of Wildlife Research 36(2), 159–165.
  • DEA (Department of Environmental Affairs), 2015. Rhino poaching statistics. Department of Environmental Affairs, Pretoria.
  • Di Minin, E, Laitila, J., Montesino-Pouzols, F, Leader-Williams, N, Slotow, R, Goodman PS, Conway AJ & Moilanen A, 2015. Identification of policies for a sustainable legal trade in Rhinoceros Horn based on population projection and socioeconomic models. Conservation Biology 29 (2), 545–555.
  • Edwards, VM, & Steins, NA, 1999. Special issue introduction: The importance of context in common pool resource research. Journal of Environmental Policy & Planning 1(3), 195–204. doi: 10.1080/714038535
  • Emslie, RH & Knight, MH, 2014. Update on African Rhino status and trends: From IUCN SSC African Rhino specialist group (AFRSG). Report to Cites Standing Committee 65th Meeting, 1–6.
  • Eustace, M, 2012. Rhino poaching: What is the solution? Business Day Live, 8 August.
  • Eustace, M, 2014. Smart trade in Rhino Horn is only solution to poaching. Business Day Live, 21 July.
  • Feeny, D, Berkes, F, McCay, BJ & Acheson, JM, 1990. The tragedy of the commons: Twenty-two years later. Human Ecology 18(1), 1–19. doi: 10.1007/BF00889070
  • Ferreira, SM, Botha, JM & Emmett, M, 2012. Anthropogenic influences on conservation values of white rhinoceros. PLoS One 7(9), e45989. doi: 10.1371/journal.pone.0045989
  • Ferreira, SM & Okita-Ouma, B, 2012. A proposed framework for short-, medium- and long-term responses by range states to curb poaching for African rhino horns. Pachyderm 51, 52–59.
  • Ferreira, SM, Pfab, M & Knight, MH, 2014. Management strategies to curb rhino poaching: Alternative options using a cost–benefit approach. South African Journal of Science 110(5/6), 1–8. doi: 10.1590/sajs.2014/20120055
  • Geldmann, J, Barnes, M, Coad, L, Craigie, ID, Hockings, M & Burgess, ND, 2013. Effectiveness of terrestrial protected areas in reducing habitat loss and population declines. Biological Conservation 161, 230–238. doi: 10.1016/j.biocon.2013.02.018
  • Gordon, HS, 1954. The economic theory of a common-property resource: The fishery. Journal of Political Economy 62, 124–142. doi: 10.1086/257497
  • Hall, RJ, Milner-Gulland, EJ & Chourchamp, F, 2008. Endangering the endangered: The effects of perceived rarity on species exploitation. Conservation Letters 1, 75–81. doi: 10.1111/j.1755-263X.2008.00013.x
  • Hansen, AJ & DeFries, R, 2007. Ecological mechanisms linking protected areas to surrounding lands. Ecological Applications, 17(4), 974–988. doi: 10.1890/05-1098
  • Hardin, G, 1968. The tragedy of the commons, Science 162, 11243–1248.
  • Hardin, G, 1998. Essays on science and SOCIETY: Extensions of ‘The tragedy of the commons’. Science 280(5364), 682–683. doi: 10.1126/science.280.5364.682
  • Kagande, SM & Musarurwa, LK, 2014. Conserving the African Rhinoceros. Biodiversity and Conservation 23(2), 497–502. doi: 10.1007/s10531-013-0613-2
  • Kalron, N, 2013. Neo-conservation, African Security Review 22, 160–166. doi: 10.1080/10246029.2013.823795
  • Lindsey, P, Nyirenda, V, Barnes, J, Becker, MS, McRobb, R, Tambling, C, Taylor, A, Watson, F & t’Sas-Rolfes, M, 2014. Underperformance of African protected area networks and the case for new conservation models: Insights from Zambia. PLoS One 9, e94109. doi: 10.1371/journal.pone.0094109
  • Litchfield, CA, 2013. Rhino poaching: Apply conservation psychology. Science 340, 1168. doi: 10.1126/science.340.6137.1168-a
  • McCullough, D, 1996. Spatially structured populations and harvest theory, The Journal of Wildlife Management 60, 1–9. doi: 10.2307/3802033
  • McHenry, TJP, 1993. Policy and legal tools for the management of wildlife resources. Unasylva 44(3), 46–50.
  • Messer, KD, 2010. Protecting endangered species: When are shoot-on-sight policies the only viable option to stop poaching? Ecological Economics 69, 2334–2340. doi: 10.1016/j.ecolecon.2010.06.017
  • Milliken, T & Shaw, J, 2012. The South Africa–Vietnam Rhino Horn trade nexus: A deadly combination of institutional lapses, corrupt wildlife industry professionals and Asian crime syndicates. Traffic, Johannesburg.
  • Milner-Gulland, EJ, 1999. How many to dehorn? A model for decision-MAKING by Rhino managers. Animal Conservation 2, 137–147. doi: 10.1111/j.1469-1795.1999.tb00059.x
  • Milner-Gulland, EJ & Leader-Williams, N, 1992. Illegal exploitation of wildlife. In: Swanson T, Barbier EB (Eds.), Economics for the wilds. Earthscan, London, 195–213.
  • Ostrom, E, Burger, J, Field, CB, Norgaard, RB & Policansky, D, 1999. Revisiting the commons: Local lessons, global challenges. Science 284, 278–82. doi: 10.1126/science.284.5412.278
  • Schaefer, MB, 1957. Some considerations of population dynamics and economics in relation to the management of the commercial marine fisheries. Journal of the Fisheries Research Board of Canada 14, 669–681. doi: 10.1139/f57-025
  • Stay in Africa, 2014. Sabi Sands Game Reserve. http://www.stayinafrica.com/ Accessed 3 July 2014.
  • Traill, LW, Brook, BW, Frankham, RR & Bradshaw, CJA, 2010. Pragmatic population viability targets in a rapidly changing world. Biological Conservation 143, 28–34. doi: 10.1016/j.biocon.2009.09.001
  • ‘t sas-Rolfes, M, 2012. The rhino poaching crisis: A market analysis. http://Savetherhinotrust.Org.
  • ‘t sas-Rolfes, M, Moyle, B & Stiles, D, 2014. The complex policy issue of elephant ivory stockpile management. Pachyderm 55, 62–77.
  • UNEP ( United Nations Environment Programme), 2014. Emerging technologies: Smarter ways to fight wildlife crime. Global Environment Alert Service Bulletin, June 2014. United Nations Environment Programme. http://www.unep.org/geas/ Accessed 16 July 2014.
  • Vecchiato, P, 2013. Government may auction stockpile of rhino horn. Business Day Live, 03 July.
  • Wilkie, D & Carpenter, J, 1999. Bushmeat hunting in the congo basin: An assessment of impacts and options for mitigation. Biodiversity and Conservation 8, 927–955. doi: 10.1023/A:1008877309871
  • Zunckel, K, 2014. Southern African development community transfrontier conservation guidelines: The establishment and development of TFCA initiatives between SADC Member States. Zunckel Ecological and Environmental Services, Hilton.

Reprints and Corporate Permissions

Please note: Selecting permissions does not provide access to the full text of the article, please see our help page How do I view content?

To request a reprint or corporate permissions for this article, please click on the relevant link below:

Academic Permissions

Please note: Selecting permissions does not provide access to the full text of the article, please see our help page How do I view content?

Obtain permissions instantly via Rightslink by clicking on the button below:

If you are unable to obtain permissions via Rightslink, please complete and submit this Permissions form. For more information, please visit our Permissions help page.