518
Views
5
CrossRef citations to date
0
Altmetric
Original Articles

What Would Korea-US Free Trade Agreement Bring?

&
Pages 161-182 | Received 28 Aug 2011, Accepted 25 Jan 2013, Published online: 28 May 2013
 

ABSTRACT

This paper uses a computable model of trade to forecast the effects of the US–Korea free trade agreement on the manufacturing sector. The model uses the Eaton–Kortum methodology to explain intra-industry trade instead of the usual Armington assumption. It is parameterized using 2005 data for 15 industries and 53 countries. The results show that implementing KORUS would increase the US manufacturing exports to Korea by 56.9% and Korean manufacturing exports to the US by 18.9%. It would also increase manufacturing employment by 26,500 jobs in Korea and 34,200 jobs in the US. In addition, KORUS would lead to significant changes in the patterns of trade and production. The US and Korea would increase their specialization in the industries where they have strong technological comparative advantages. Finally, KORUS would increase welfare in both countries, but only modestly: by 0.27% in Korea and 0.013% in the US.

JEL CLASSIFICATIONS:

Notes

1Data are from the World Bank's WDI database and the US CIA's The World Factbook.

2Of course, this similarity is aided by the fact that these studies used very similar models. For example, five of the studies used the GTAP model.

3See for example Leamer Citation(1984). Most of this literature focuses on factor endowment differences as the determinants of specialization, whereas this paper focuses on the differences of technology.

4The main reason why the Armington-based models significantly underpredicted the effects of NAFTA is that the Armington elasticities they employed (between 2 and 3) were too small. See Ruhl Citation(2008) for an analysis of this issue.

5The assumption of tradability of the non-manufacturing output means that the wages wn in each country are given by the productivity in non-manufacturing and the (numeraire) price of the non-manufacturing good deflated by the price of the bundle of intermediates used in producing this good.

6Kortum Citation(1997) and Eaton and Kortum Citation(1999) provide microfoundations for this approach. Parameter Tij governs the mean of the distribution, while parameter θ, which is common to all countries and industries, governs the variance. The support of the Fréchet distribution is (0, ∞).

7To receive $1 of product in country n requires sending dnij≥1 dollars of product from country i. By definition, domestic transport costs are set to one: dnnj≡ 1. Trade barriers result in dnij>1. Note that trade costs are not restricted to be symmetric (dnij can be different from dinj). Waugh Citation(2007) studies the effects of the asymmetry of trade costs.

8It follows from . The last equality follows from a known statistical result (see Eaton & Kortum, Citation2002).

9Note that parameter T is not the same as total factor productivity (TFP). T is an exogenous parameter of the Fréchet distribution. TFP, on the other hand, is endogenous and represents the average productivity of the firms actually operating in an industry.

10This is true because conditional on the fact that country i actually supplies a particular good, the distribution of the price of this good is the same regardless of the source i.

11This system of equations is easily solved using numerical methods in Matlab.

12A similar procedure is followed by Levchenko and Zhang Citation(2011).

13They also obtain a second estimate of 3.6, but 8.28 is their preferred estimate since θ=3.6 results in unreasonably high trade costs.

14In the data, in addition to intermediate and final goods, there are also investment goods. Since there is no investment in the model, investment goods are treated as intermediate goods.

15Anderson and van Wincoop Citation(2004) roughly estimate the average international trade cost between rich OECD countries to be around 1.7 (excluding local distribution margins, see Anderson & van Wincoop, Citation2004, pp. 692–693). This is lower than the (non-weighted) average trade cost of 2.84 estimated in this paper. However, our dataset includes many less-developed countries that have much higher trade costs than the rich OECD countries. If these countries are excluded from the dataset, the average trade cost for the remaining rich OECD countries is 1.76, which is much closer to the number reported in Anderson and van Wincoop Citation(2004).

16Remember that these international trade cost are measured relative to domestic trade costs, which have also been changing over the decades. Rising trade cost for US imports in this case means that it is rising relative to the US domestic trade costs.

17This is consistent with previous studies (listed in the Introduction) that forecast the effects of NAFTA.

18These numbers are greater than what has been generally predicted by the previous studies. This is consistent with the comment made in the Introduction about the current Armington-based models.

Reprints and Corporate Permissions

Please note: Selecting permissions does not provide access to the full text of the article, please see our help page How do I view content?

To request a reprint or corporate permissions for this article, please click on the relevant link below:

Academic Permissions

Please note: Selecting permissions does not provide access to the full text of the article, please see our help page How do I view content?

Obtain permissions instantly via Rightslink by clicking on the button below:

If you are unable to obtain permissions via Rightslink, please complete and submit this Permissions form. For more information, please visit our Permissions help page.