117
Views
0
CrossRef citations to date
0
Altmetric
Original Articles

DEFENSE SECTOR, ARMAMENTS–LABOR RATIO AND NATIONAL SECURITY

Pages 59-71 | Published online: 25 Jan 2007
 

Abstract

This paper analyzes a national defense economy in which the army reduces the risk of attack and damage. The results show that it is important how countries or people feel about damage to military personnel, citizens and wealth from attack. The feeling determines the optimal levels of arms procurement and army personnel. It also affects international trade. It is found that labor (armaments) input into the military sector is not always decreased following an increase of wage (armaments price). The model suggests that conscription affects army expenditure and international trade.

Notes

1A small country model is often used in international trade theory since it is very convenient model to analyze many problems. In this model, the prices of tradable goods are constant.

2It is assumed that capital is not used in the sector. It is said that the share of the procurement and personnel expenditure in the defense sector is very large (Sandler and Hartley, Citation1995).

3Taking it into consideration is easy. However, basically the results are not changed. Realistically, after the Cold War, the arms trade has become more commercial (Brzoska, Citation2004).

4Some developing countries use second‐hand tanks, which were made long ago in the Soviet Union. In this case, the tanks have small M. On the other hand, newly‐made and expensive tanks have large M. In this connection, it is said the unit price of procurement is increased (Kirkpatrick, Citation1995).

5We can define welfare by using an expected utility function with risk aversion. For example, it is represented as: (1 − P)U(D 1 +p 2 D 2) − PU(D 1 + p 2 D 2A*V). For simplicity, I do not treat the expected utility function. A kind of risk‐neutral is used in this paper since I want to focus on the attitude to the victims.

6 W MM = ∂(∂W/∂M)/∂M = ∂(∂E/∂M)/∂M = − [2β r3pM PF M + V(P″(F M)2 + PF MM)] A*

7 W LL = ∂(∂W/∂L A)/∂L A = E LL − [2V LA PF L + V(∂PF L/∂L A)]A* = − [2(βρ 1−αρ2)PF L + V(P″(F L)2 + PF LL)]A*

8Where Wij = ∂(∂W/∂i)/∂ j (i, j =M, L A, W ), W LM = −A*[PF M(β ρ 1−αρ2)+V M PF L +V(∂(PF L)/∂M)], W ML = −A* [PF L β ρ4pM + PF M V LA + V((PF M)/∂L A)]

9Although wage is an endogenous variable and it is determined by two prices of traded goods, we assume that there is a technological progress that only raises wage under constant prices.

10 V W = β ρ1 L A + α ρ2(L 1 + L 2) + β ρ3 M PM + αρ4(K 1 + K 2)pK > 0

11Detail is omitted for simplicity.

12See footnote 2.

Additional information

Notes on contributors

Kazunori Tanigaki

The author would like to thank Keith Hartley for comments and suggestions which improve the paper. I am grateful to Masayuki Hayashibara and Masayuki Okawa for suggestions.

Reprints and Corporate Permissions

Please note: Selecting permissions does not provide access to the full text of the article, please see our help page How do I view content?

To request a reprint or corporate permissions for this article, please click on the relevant link below:

Academic Permissions

Please note: Selecting permissions does not provide access to the full text of the article, please see our help page How do I view content?

Obtain permissions instantly via Rightslink by clicking on the button below:

If you are unable to obtain permissions via Rightslink, please complete and submit this Permissions form. For more information, please visit our Permissions help page.