Publication Cover
The European Legacy
Toward New Paradigms
Volume 22, 2017 - Issue 4
1,979
Views
0
CrossRef citations to date
0
Altmetric
Articles

From Old Practices to New Governance Models: Contractual Schemes in Africa’s Political DevelopmentFootnote

Abstract

Drawing on various historical documents, the article uses process tracing methods and analytic narratives to establish a relationship between historical contractual practices and state formation in nineteenth-century East Africa. I trace the process through which local political leaders historically sought to secure monopolistic deals over trade with foreign entrepreneurs through incomplete contracts for tangible economic goods (arms and slave trades, manufactured goods) and intangible political goods or services (security, knowledge, independence). By showcasing agents’ bargaining strategies in contractual agreements, the article sheds light on notions of sovereignty and independence articulated through public contracting in Africa’s political development. Historical understandings of notions of independence and sovereignty by procurement practitioners in East Africa provide seeds for thought in controversial debates about government outsourcing today. Is outsourced sovereignty always threatening? Can we outsource sovereignty and remain independent? These are perhaps the most important conceptual queries that make East Africa’s historical contractual experience pertinent today as new public-private partnerships for development, including government outsourcing, increasingly call for the use of private means to solve public problems in the developing countries.

The Ethiopian emperors who contributed to the establishment of the bureaucratic empire were all well aware of the critical need to expand their reservoir of flexible resources in order to increase their autonomy and to strengthen their authority in relation to other groups in society. Flexible resources were simply diplomatic, manpower, monetary, and secularly based institutional resources that could be exclusively manipulated by an emperor.

—Edmond Keller, Revolutionary Ethiopia: From Empire to People’s Republic

Economic life in colonial Africa was stereotypically divided into three spheres. At the top were Western firms, modern, efficient, Weberian, highly capitalized and organized on the joint-stock principle. In the middle were the ‘Asiatic’ intermediaries, often compared to Jews. Their funds came from ‘usury’, and their modest property was attributed to close knit community bonds, based on family, religion, caste and similar ‘pre-modern’ social structures. At the bottom of the social heap were ‘natives’, ignorant, simple-minded, living for the moment, and incapable of rational economic behavior.

—William Gervase Clarence-Smith, “Indian and Arab Entrepreneurs in Eastern Africa, 1800–1914”

Introduction

Conventional wisdom with regard to the political and economic development of Africa gives weight to the colonial origin of the modern state and institutions. However, from the seventeenth century until World War I, African leaders entered into economic and political agreements with foreign firms, early transnational corporations, and signed procurement contracts for the delivery of various goods and services. These contracts present the theorist with an interesting challenge: where (if anywhere) do we place procurement practices in the history of state formation in Africa? It is my contention that these contracts suggest at least two things. Firstly, bargains and deals have always characterized Afro-European-Asian encounters. Secondly, by entering into contractual agreements of various kinds with their European-Asian counterparts, African leaders made it difficult to interpret subsequent changes in global trade and processes of state formation from the vantage point of imperialism and/or colonial interests only.

Drawing on various historical documents,Footnote1 I use process tracing methods and analytic narratives to establish a relationship between historical contractual practices and state formation in nineteenth-century East Africa. I trace the process through which local political leaders historically sought to secure monopolistic deals over trade with foreign entrepreneurs through incomplete contracts for tangible economic goods (arms and slave trades, manufactured goods) and intangible political goods or services (security, knowledge, independence). By showcasing agents’ bargaining strategies in contractual agreements, the article sheds light on notions of sovereignty and independence articulated through public contracting in Africa’s political development.

The historical understanding of notions of independence and sovereignty by procurement practitioners in East Africa provides seeds for thought in controversial debates about government outsourcing today. Is outsourced sovereignty always threatening?Footnote2 Can we outsource sovereignty and remain independent? These are perhaps the most important conceptual queries that make East Africa’s historical contractual experience pertinent today as new public-private partnerships for development, including government outsourcing, increasingly call for the use of private means to solve public problems in the developing countries.Footnote3 Questions of sovereignty and independence within contractual schemes remain poorly researched in the non-Western world.Footnote4 Yet scholarship has uncovered the many ways in which public contracting historically transformed state power in the West.Footnote5 The article addresses this omission in African studies by shifting the focus from a commodity-oriented approach to a transactional analysis of the transformation of political power and institutions through historical procurement practices. The article, however, does so by retrieving the agency of African leaders as strategic agents in historical contractual schemes shaping the formation of a modern state on the continent.

The work presents important empirical findings that challenge the exclusive economic-focus of current procurement models as ahistorical and suggests new directions for future research. Here I argue that intangibles such as independence have historically been the return to polities contracting out services and goods from private suppliers. Political intangibles are indeed the unseen wealth of the political economy of government procurement.Footnote6 If procurement has been one of the ways in which African polities invented independence, the data leave theorists with the task of reimagining the concept of the state, democracy, and sovereignty, especially today as the core functions of government, such as monopoly over the use of violence,Footnote7 are being contracted out to private suppliers. Indeed, we live in an age where public procurement, or the process through which government acquires from private suppliers the goods and services it needs to accomplish its public mission, is transforming state-citizens relations. Nevertheless, those who worry about the future of democracy given the outsourcing of many public functions to private contractors treat the idea of independence as deriving from other sources than the historical contractual practices of nations and states. Thus, by focusing on the interpretation of the idea of independence on the East African Coast, and by showing how procurement enhanced rather than diminished such a concept, Africa’s historical data provide a critique of existing notions of the state based on ahistorical and abstract ideas from Hobbes and consorts. To the extent that historical evidence may help reframe the debate over the means and ends of development today, it is suggested that models of public-private partnerships that do not fundamentally secure the independence of the state in the long run may serve other purposes than development in Africa.

Before I proceed with the analysis, a cautionary note is in order. The region of East Africa under consideration here could roughly be said to cover the territories ranging from modern Sudan to Mozambique. It is useful to remember that specific cases to be discussed in detail should not be read as a history of the modern East African states as defined by the territorial boundaries in existence today. Instead, keeping in mind shifting territorial boundaries since the nineteenth century, cases under consideration are coded as “configurations” of strategic challenges at historical junctures: the strategic choice between means of independence and ways of (de)constructing sovereignty. To the extent that I abstract from territorial national history, I do so with the sole purpose of identifying dominant strategic factors and themes such as political independence and sovereignty that shaped competition for the procurement of tangible and intangible goods and services. In this endeavor focus remains on the decisional process, the choice of trade and political partners, and the strategies of acquisition of goods and services through contracting given the asymmetric distribution of power between rival groups.

To better capture economic and political dynamics in East Africa and the ways in which contracting tangible and intangible goods transformed political and economic power, I have divided the Coast into two sub-regions: the upper-northern region with Ethiopia (also known as Abyssinia in the premodern era) as the most influential power, and the southern coast with Zanzibar as the leading political and economic broker. The names Abyssinia and Ethiopia are used interchangeably in the historical documents scrutinized in this analysis. However, because data analyzed here mostly reflect transactions that took place in the early nineteenth century and beyond, I use the name Ethiopia throughout my analysis. Thus data summarily capture the contractual transactions under emperor Tewodoros II (1855–68) as well as during the reign of the briefly self-proclaimed Emperor Tekle Giyorgis II (1868–72) on the death of Tewodros, Yohannes IV (1872–89), and Menelik II (1889–1913). I first present the general strategic context in each sub-region, which is then followed by the analysis of disaggregated data to compare the contractual contexts, patterns, and strategic constraints of specific agents.

The Upper Region

In the nineteenth century, the Abyssinian Empire (which roughly encompassed what is present-day Ethiopia) appeared as the most internationally connected political entity in the northeastern region. Ethiopia’s contractual practices rivaled those of old European kingdoms, for they were not just written in a local language (Amharic and Ge’ez), but also bore a particular aesthetic intended to showcase political power at its highest level of sophistication. Signatures, customized ornamental seals, the use of witnesses, a sophisticated diplomatic language, and a variety of styles leave no doubt in the reader’s mind about the standing of Ethiopia as a great power among the greatest in this period.Footnote8 Ethiopia stood as the oldest known place in Africa to foreigners; its ancient Christianity amidst pagans and later Muslim neighbors was a highly symbolic currency that incentivized the Christian kingdoms of Europe and Asia to seek its friendship for commerce and military reasons.

Ethiopia’s contractual activities mostly took a bilateral form (Table ) with Italy, Great Britain, France, and the United States (Table ) from roughly 1840 to 1914 (Figure ). In the context of a long standing history of official negotiations with Europe, Ethiopia’s history of public procurement of tangible and intangible goods and services shows that private (commercial and religious) entrepreneurs played a central role as brokers of trade contracts and land concessions.

Table 1a. Bilateral and multilateral contractual patterns of Ethiopia (1840–1914). Rows are levels of engagement of ET (Ethiopia); Columns are levels of CP (contractual patterns [0] bilateral, [1] multilateral).

Table 1b. Contingency Table: Ethiopia’s foreign partners. The main contracting parties were Italy, Great Britain, France, and the United States; Belgium, Austria-Hungary, and Germany were minor trade partners (1840–1914).

Figure 1. Contracting activities of Ethiopia by year (1840–1914). Y= number of contractual agreements; X=Year.

Figure 1. Contracting activities of Ethiopia by year (1840–1914). Y= number of contractual agreements; X=Year.

Figure 2. Zanzibar’s Contractual Activities by Year (1859–1911). Y=number of contractual agreements; X=Year.

Figure 2. Zanzibar’s Contractual Activities by Year (1859–1911). Y=number of contractual agreements; X=Year.

The Data reveal three peak years in economic and political diplomacy: First, 1876 after the British punitive expeditions of 1868 when Ethiopia was under Emperor Theodore II. Second, 1889, the period marking the Mahdist invasion of Ethiopia (1887–89), the battle of Adwa (1896) where the Ethiopians inflicted a monumental defeat on Italian troops, and the signing of the treaty of Addis Ababa securing Ethiopian independence under emperors Yohannes IV and Menelik II. Third and last was 1908, the year of the agreement defining the frontier between Ethiopia and the Italian colony, Eritrea, under emperor Menelik II. The correlation between a high volume of contracting activities and Ethiopia’s most important historical crises suggests that the procurement of goods and services from suppliers took place in a politically stressful environment. Strategy and decisional processes in this context were not necessarily designed to foster economic self-sufficiency, but to preserve political independence, a prerequisite to creating a lasting union as the country became more centralized. For the enemies of a united Ethiopia were not just foreign, they were domestic also.

Before its consolidation in the mid-nineteenth century, independent princes ruled Ethiopia (~late 1700s to 1855). The country was united and centralized as a state under Emperor Tewodros around 1855. The consolidation of monarchical power was constantly contested by internal rebellion and external aggressions mainly from Egypt. At times Christianity helped promote peace; at other times, it worked against it. Thus the project of national unity, the centralization of power, and the ambition to be taken seriously on the world stage made international cooperation and domestic coordination paramount to Ethiopia’s survival. Starting in 1840, the data capture the decisional motivation, the change in political values, and paradoxes of contractual choice in the context of state building when regional princes still had tremendous discretionary power over foreign exchanges.

Whereas we are used to understanding historical contractual practices in Africa as mere replicas of economic practices originating in Western Europe, the case of Ethiopia challenges such overbearing unidirectional assumptions. A close reading of the language and substantive content of contract documents reveals a highly skilled people that used what could be called reverse auctioning as a strategy for the procurement of the goods and services they needed in the process of state-building. To see Ethiopia’s contractual history as a configuration of auction-like strategies has implications for theory building. An auction is a process through which the procurement of goods and services is open up for bids and items are sold to the highest bidder. In contrast, a reverse auction is a process through which goods and services are purchased rather than sold to the auctioneer thus reversing the role of buyer and seller. It is typically assumed that price decreases in reverse auctioning through competition between the sellers. While reverse auctioning is applied today in government procurements, the strategy worked for Ethiopia well before theoretical articulations. Ethiopia successfully combined auction and reverse auction by buying legitimacy in the global market of reputation at a cheap price and by selling to the highest bidder domestic trade privileges. It was through the manipulation of the buyer and seller positions in the process of empire building that Ethiopia maintained its independence despite foreign encroachment in the late nineteenth century. Hence Ethiopia did not just contract out goods and services: princes and emperors changed nineteenth-century agency, discourse and direction over public contracting.

Ethiopia and France

The Ethiopian case is useful in investigating the ways in which contracting historically transformed political power and institutions and the clash that ensued between collective monopolistic forces and individual aspirations. This struggle for decentralization and centralization is seen in the contractual activities and framing of transactions during the era of princes (1769–1855) “when the regional rulers held the real power in the country and the King of Kings in Gondar became but a puppet in the hands of his regents.”Footnote9 Ethiopia used Christianity to finesse its reputation among the Christian kingdoms of Europe, especially with France. On September 12, 1840, a contract between “Sovereign Mahmud Hasan and Badri, judge and religious head, and Edmond Combes charged by the French government, Frederic Broquant, Legion of Honor,” for the sale of the island of Kordumyat, situated in modern day Eritrea, was signed. In ceding to France a piece of land, the Ethiopian sovereign and judge made it clear that they were acting out of their “own free will.” Three years later, a treaty of friendship was concluded between “Sahle Sillase, king of Shewa & the Great Louis Philippe, king of France” for the peace of Jerusalem, promising more preferential concessions. The Ethiopian kings in this case were regional princes.Footnote10

On June 15, 1876, “Menelik II, by the Grace of God king of Shewa,” granted a coal mine concession to Pierre Arnoux representing the French-Ethiopian society.Footnote11 If the first contract took place between a regional prince and a French representative in a politically fragmented Ethiopia, this one occurred at a time when state centralization was in full swing. Thus, even as political rule changed hands in Ethiopia, the tendency to give perks to public and private French citizens remained part of a strategy of self-aggrandizement that paid off. Wielding natural resources concessions with cultural heritage, international reputation was cheaply bought through contracting and lobbying.

By this document we authorize Mr. Pierre Arnoux to cede in our name, without payment and with full ownership, to the French-Ethiopian society to be established in France, the coal mine which is found near Chenno... besides the mine, also the territory necessary for the accommodation of the workers and the exploitation of the coal mine. The company undertakes to construct at its expense a road as far as the river Awash for the transportation of its coal.Footnote12

This was a coal mine and land grant to a company that was going to be incorporated in France. Edmond Keller notes that although Ethiopia historically had different types of land tenure, “the emperor’s fictional control over all land [was] an extremely valued [instrument] of political patronage” that safeguarded his own absolutist position. Footnote13 It is not clear whether King Menelik had stock in the French-Ethiopia Society, but the only immediate economic benefit was a “road” to be constructed in Ethiopia. Otherwise, the French-Ethiopia Society was a powerful lobbying strategy that consolidated Ethiopia’s standing as a great power among the greatest at this time. Through concessions and grants, Menelik appeared to be the buyer of international reputation.

The following year, on June 16, 1876, Arnoux was given a political mandate as envoyé extraordinaire to friendly powers in Europe.Footnote14 If the free concession of a coal mine and land did not make sense in the beginning, it becomes clear why Menelik made the move. He wanted a non-state private ally and employed Arnoux with the hope of building a diplomatic front for the defense of Abyssinian interests. As Menelik’s extraordinary envoy, Arnoux was granted the power to defend and protect the territorial integrity and independence of Abyssinia, sign a treaty with Egypt guaranteed by European powers, establish diplomatic and friendly relations with the Christian nations of Europe, raise questions about Egyptian aggression, and explain the official position of Abyssinia to the European powers.

This strategy evidences the interdependence of trade and politics. More interestingly, it must be noted that the bundling of trade and politics was an African diplomatic initiative. From an Africanist perspective, Menelik could be seen as a visionary theorist and statesman who stretched the concept of freedom and independence. It might come as a surprise that it was Menelik, not Yohannes IV, the great unifier of Ethiopia, who made the best use of private contractors. Yohannes mainly relied on direct and “patient diplomacy” to reach out to the great powers.Footnote15 His administration produced a significant amount of correspondence between Yohannes IV and France, Great Britain, Russia, and Egypt. The letters show that Yohannes clearly wanted to be perceived as equal to other great leaders of powerful nations and this might explain his reliance on formal and direct diplomacy rather than on private brokers.Footnote16 The state of unrest and external aggressions might have made foreign private contractors suspicious to Yohannes IV. In contrast, private contractors helped Menelik undercut the power of Yohannes IV and thus to secure his rise to power.

Following the appointment of Arnoux as Abyssinia’s Ambassador to various governments in Europe, he was sent off with the power of attorney

to sell on the best possible terms the merchandise which [Abyssinia] entrusted to him as samples… to the French government… to conclude political and commercial treaties between France and Ethiopia; to found a large Franco-Ethiopian companyto assist in the development of industry and commerce in Ethiopia… to make purchases on the behalf of the Ethiopian government of arms, ammunitions, various tools, various merchandise, everything according to what has been agreed before his departure, and in accordance with the instructions handed over.Footnote17

A note from Sven Rubenson, the editor of this historical contract, reads as follows: “that this document was initiated and drafted by Arnoux is quite obvious. Whether they were fully understood or even known to Minelik [sic] and his advisers remains an open question.”Footnote18 For my analysis, it suffices that authenticity not be questioned. Rubenson, however, raises an important question related to the choice of angles of analysis of the decisional processes in contractual relations. It might be tempting to view the initial concession as “land grab,” to denounce the appointment of a Frenchman as foreign diplomat as “colonial usurpation” only. I can see the appeal of the argument that economic transactions that are not homegrown could be harmful to domestic interests. But such paternalist analytic attitudes are costly because they infantilize non-Western agency by disqualifying its tenets. Omniscience is neither a measure of sound public policy nor evidence of the absence of strategic thinking. Indeed, accompanying the devolution of power resulting from the decision to hire a private foreign contractor was a carefully designed strategy that sought to consolidate Ethiopia’s reputation internationally and to affirm a unitary rule domestically.

An account of the evolution of the relationship between France and Abyssinia, Arnoux and Menelik, shows that contracting out served both the foreign and domestic interests of Ethiopia. Indeed in long-term relational contracts convention is not all that matters. In many cases, competition in long-term relational contracts remains within reach of the expectant and is rarely limited by the transaction cost of the exchanges. The reverse auction-like strategy of Ethiopia becomes clearer as one distinguishes and juxtaposes concessions made to Arnoux as payment for his services, and privileges given to him as a diplomatic means to attract either more foreign investment to Ethiopia, or win foreign military cooperation against the territory’s enemies.Footnote19

Ethiopia and Italy

Unlike France, Ethiopia’s relations with Italy were hostile. As previously mentioned, the second and third peak in the data occurred when Ethiopia was under external aggression with the Mahdists and Italy leading the charge. Before the outbreak of the battle of Adwa (1896), however, peaceful commercial deals consolidated Italo-Ethiopian relations. On November 15, 1869, a contract for sale of a territory was signed between the two brothers Hasan bin Ahmad and Ibrahim bin Ahmad and Guiseppe Sapeto, an Italian Catholic missionary. The two brothers sold the land for 6,000 thalers. Giuseppe handed over 250 thalers to the sellers with the understanding that the remaining 5,750 should be paid within one hundred days from the sale date.Footnote20 A note from Rubenson reads as follows:

A note follows the signatures: “The rights deriving from this convention were transferred by the Rubattino society [company] to the Royal Government by the convention of 10 May 1882.” All attempts to locate the original or archival copy have failed. The private purchase of a piece of land by the former Catholic missionary Giuseppe (see ACTA I, no. 30) with no mention of the Rubattino Company, for which he was acting, much less the Italian government, nevertheless became the foundation of the first Italian claims to the colony of Eritrea.Footnote21

Thus, whereas Christianity helped further the interests of Ethiopia through contracting with France, it became the bearer of bad news with Italy, another Catholic country. The difference in outcome, however, was attributable less to differences in the nature of Christianity than to the transient nature of private ownership and the changing nature of political power in Italy at this period. What started as a private sale to one missionary entrepreneur later gave ownership rights to a company and imperial claims to Italy through vertical integration of assets. On December 30, 1879, a land sale contract was signed between Burhan Dini, Sultan of Rahita and Ribattino & Co.Footnote22 With this concession, one traces the evolution of trade deals between Rubattino & Co. and the political leaders of Abyssinia. The land ceded had been leased for the past ten years to Mr. Guiseppe Sapeto. Now the Sultan was selling the land for 2,000 rupees for definitive acquisition. In addition to ownership, the Sultan gave rights to the company to “raise the Italian flag there.” This was the first time that the “flag” became explicitly part of trade deals in Rubenson’s collection of treaties and contracts.

Procurement deals are never entirely commercial or political; they are both. Of the many causes of the first war between Ethiopia and Italy (1896) nothing illuminates the past as clearly as the trade contract of 1879 with its patriotic zeal coded as flag privileges. The years that followed the 1879 contract involved land disputes, which preceded the battle of Adwa in 1896.Footnote23 Ethiopia experienced major setbacks not primarily because of the military superiority of Italy, but because of internal weaknesses due to the unfinished business of state centralization. Menelik, then a vassal prince from the South, first allied himself with Italy for the procurement of weapons against Yohannes, the central authority (1883–87).Footnote24 In 1889, the limits of the Sultanate of Oppiah included in another treaty were contested. New boundaries were drawn in May 1889.Footnote25 Unlike its trade contracts with France, Ethiopia seemed to have lost its ability to define independence and sovereignty on its own terms with Italy. The ceding of part of its territory in 1889 was thus a loss of independence giving currency to foreign ideas depicting national freedom as emanating from Italian “protection” only. A concession of Eritrea was given to Italy in the same year, but the terms of this contract, later known as the Treaty of Wuchale, were later contested by both parties and eventually led to war.Footnote26 As Menelik consolidated his power, he later defeated the Italian army in 1896 in the epic Battle of Adwa and secured the territorial integrity of Ethiopia without reclaiming Eritrea.

From the perspective of strategic posturing, the Battle of Adwa was also a policy success for Ethiopia, showing the effective use of foreign non-state actors as military advisers domestically and extraordinary envoys internationally. Menelik II developed a strategic friendship with Russia through Nicolai Leontyev and the St. Petersburg Geographical Society for military support without raising the suspicion of Britain. The House of Commons sitting on February 28, 1895, worried about the Russian mission to Abyssinia and Her Majesty was reassured that the expedition was “not official but sent by the St. Petersburg Geographical Society for scientific purposes… and… very possibly… charged with some religious mission from the Russian Ecclesiastical authorities.”Footnote27 Thus under the cover of scientific missions, humanitarian (Russian Red CrossFootnote28) and Orthodox Christian expeditions, Ethiopia once again recruited foreign agents as partners in the art of war making and intelligence gathering to secure a victory at Adwa.Footnote29 Nicolai Leontyev later became Count Abai and the governor general of one of the provinces of Ethiopia. Accompanying Russia’s first official diplomatic mission to emperor Menelik II in 1897 was Armatov, Colonel of the General Staff, and Arnoldi, a Lieutenant of the Izmailovskiy Guard Regiment, both of whom were “on business from the War Ministry.”Footnote30 By outsourcing the diplomatic functions of empire to foreign consultants, “Menelik strengthened his defensive capability by purchasing modern arms and military equipment.”Footnote31 Thus the procurement of tangible (arms deals) and intangible (lobby, reputation) goods from foreign private suppliers sustained the Ethiopian empire at different stages of its consolidation.

What is remarkable is that public procurement historically transformed the strategic ways and means through which Ethiopia invented and consolidated its independence and sovereignty. Ethiopia sold and bought goods and services, but also actively participated in the transformation of the meaning and value attributed to historical public-private partnerships. The gain to Ethiopia, in this sense, was not material only, but also symbolic, political and epistemological. The asymmetric power context in which Ethiopia evolved was not entirely defined by exogenous attempts to colonize its territory. Power discrepancies were a result of domestic structures highlighting the struggle between centripetal and centrifugal forces at work in the process of a regional empire building. Additionally, public procurement restated the power of individuals within society and especially within the military.

The organization of the military hierarchy was divided along four categories: the regular regimen of troops mainly protecting the emperor, the private regular troops under individual leaders, the auxiliary and territorial troops supplied by landowners in times of war, and the irregular troops comprised of any inhabitant who decided to join combat.Footnote32 Although central authority remained with the emperor, mobilization for war required both general (public) and private troops. The supply of private troops served other purposes than military hierarchical decorum: it was a tactical necessity because a rare commodity. Private troops were a tactical bargain of individual military leaders who recruited and paid them, and “the number of troops of individual leaders [was] not determined by law for each separately, but rather depend[ed] on the wealth, the popularity of the leader, and the size of the region that provide[d] the means for maintaining the troops.”Footnote33 In contrast, the recruitment of the irregular corps was voluntary at the onset of a war. Hence, for individual leaders, war contracting presented them with the opportunity to enhance the military performance of their units and to compete for the favors of the emperor. Individual firms, lone Catholic entrepreneurs as well as regional princes such as Menelik prior to assuming the throne of the King of Kings, became power brokers by manipulating contractual opportunities to their advantage.

The Southern Region

Two important events brought profound change in the southern region in the nineteenth century: first the creation of the Sultanate at Zanzibar, and second the abolition of the Indian Ocean slave trade. Early contacts between Europeans and the southern East African Coast date back to the Middle Ages with Vasco da Gama’s voyages around the Cape of Good Hope. Constant wars between the Portuguese and Muslims in North Africa also led the Knights Templars to this region in search of Christian converts and potential allies against the Arabs. The Portuguese search for potential partners from the East Coast put the Africans in a strategic position that shaped trade and politics for many centuries. There is a vast literature on the strategic encounters of Europeans and Arabs in East Africa. However, in keeping with the goal of this article, I am interested in understanding how contracts became key instruments of trade and politics from an Africanist perspective.

Because of the eclectic cultural nature of this African region, when I use the term “African” it is meant to include political groupings in the hinterland (mostly blacks) and Arab settlers (mostly along the coast). Thus the term “African” denotes a people belonging to the coast (Swahili) and to the interior. The European is treated as the sole foreigner,Footnote34 given the fact that Islam already made inroads into this region well before the arrival of Portuguese missionaries.Footnote35

Although Islam had unified a number of ethnic groups under its umbrella in the northern part of the southern coast, tensions and rivalries remained between local politically autonomous communities, and between the North and the South coast. These internal conflicts took a different turn with the arrival of the Portuguese, whom the Africans sometimes used to settle their own disputes. The North-South divide became more accentuated as the competitive pendulum kept swinging between agents that did not hesitate to use their self-interested rationale or religiously sanctioned tactics to gain advantage over rivals. For the purpose of this study, I confine myself to internal and external factors that shaped contractual agreements. Religion is mentioned only in relation to its underlying political and economic roles in constructing or deconstructing strategic alliances between agents. Here I retain two important factors that contributed to making bargaining in East Africa unequal yet strategic, namely, the nature of overland (hinterland-coast) political economy and climate fluctuation. How agents evaluated the benefit and cost of a cooperative approach to overland and seaborne opportunities for trade diversification against those of unilateral trade monopolies is what the study of their contractual decisions seeks to reveal.

History has it that when Vasco da Gama reached the East Coast of Africa, he received “a friendly reception at Malindi [because] the ruler of that place was usually at war with his more powerful neighbor at Mombasa and accordingly welcomed the Portuguese as a possible ally.”Footnote36 Through their strategic partner, the King of Malindi, the Portuguese later obtained a lease of the island of Mombasa—which the African ruler had previously captured—and turned it into a center for proselytization.Footnote37 Mombasa therefore passed into the hands of the Portuguese and became their administrative capital.

The coast-hinterland relations were a determining factor in designing the strategic context for the procurement of goods and services. The autonomy of towns in East Africa was particularly revealing about their strategic vulnerability. As Nicholls notes, “coastal settlements had no territorial backing... since all places offered the same commodities for sale, each would compete with its neighbors in trying to entice interior peoples and maritime traders to its own markets.”Footnote38 Thus the hinterland and its people became strategic players with potential symbolic and economic power especially with the entry of the Portuguese into the race for trade monopoly.

On the one hand, the Portuguese were in search of Prester John, a mythical Christian King of Abyssinia (Ethiopia), with whom they hoped to defeat the Arabs in Africa. Thus the search for an overland route to Ethiopia became a spiritual and national obsession for the Portuguese, which required the collaboration of political groups in the hinterland. Yet beyond the realm of the spiritual imaginary, the hinterland had significant economic power as a supplier of raw materials such as gold, ivory, and slaves. It is therefore not surprising that when Vasco da Gama learned that “gold mines existed in the interior, he also discovered that the trade in gold was more or less a monopoly of the inhabitants of Kilwa.”Footnote39 The discovery of a gold monopoly in the interior prompted Portugal to change its initial strategy of peaceful contacts into a forceful capture of the southern gold producing town of Sofala (located in modern Zimbabwe), which led to the construction of a fort to assert monopoly over trade and the control of economic transactions with the independent Queen of Zanzibar. As will be shown later, although Portuguese activities were short-lived, their contractual gains were mainly concentrated in the South Africa-Mozambique-Zanzibar-Madagascar belt.

In response to this attempt to capture and replace an indigenous natural monopoly with a foreign “managed” control of the gold trade, Africans allied themselves with pirates in North Africa to thwart Portuguese plans on the East Coast. Thus the vertical (North-South) configuration of the strategic context revealed a struggle between competing monopolistic claims: a struggle between the Cross and the Crescent. The initial gains secured by early Portuguese traders and missionaries were subsequently challenged as many towns rebelled against the foreign monopoly over trade. The Swahili sometimes invoked “Jihad” against infidels and eventually turned to Oman for support. In 1698 Mombasa fell to the Omanis who later established an independent Sultanate at Zanzibar in 1729 (adding to the list of groups coded Africans in this study).Footnote40

With the entry of the Omanis into the picture, the politics and economics of contracting became an interplay between three types of agents separated by land and by sea, yet needing the produce from both sources: the landlocked, the coastal, and the Indian Ocean merchants. The Omani Sultanate at Zanzibar retained control over maritime commerce and secured the cooperation of the Sultans of the mainland by contracting out trade revenues. In the fragmented South at Kilwa, the Omanis “had made an agreement with the Sultan that he should retain his title and one-fifth of the customs dues.”Footnote41 In the North, they asserted monopoly over trade from and to Mombasa, but they did so without disturbing commercial relations with the hinterland and without alienating the middlemen upon whom transactions with the coastal towns depended. Hence the Sultanate at Zanzibar successfully established a network of exchanges with the mainland (North and South) and the hinterland that added to the advantage of its strategic location as the guardian of maritime trade. Subsequent arrivals and departures of different European powers restructured the balance of power between the hinterland, the coastal towns, and Zanzibar but did not totally control the dynamic of change. Thus the contractual activities in this region were of two types: (a) the contracts of Zanzibar in the process of establishing itself as a major power broker in the southern region; and (b) the contracts concluded between Africans and other regional agents in their attempts to unseat Zanzibar’s authority. Peripheral but equally important were the contractual transactions of Madagascar and Mauritius as rivals and partners with Zanzibar in the slave trade and plantation economy.

One unifying factor besides the actual goods and services justifying iterated bargaining in the region was the climate cycle of the monsoon winds. One could imagine the monsoon winds as the regulators of overall trade, constraining choice and the durability of choice, in this context.Footnote42 The wind that may have carried out trade rivals from April to August from the East African Coast to the Persian Gulf and to Asia was the same airstream that brought back new competitors from November to March. To illustrate:

Mombasa’s defensive position was strengthened by the difficulties of mounting a blockage. Blockade tactics, assisted, it is true, by the narrowness of the harbor’s entrance, were greatly hindered by the monsoon winds. Vessels could only maintain a blockade for the duration of one monsoon or forfeit their freedom to return to their home port.Footnote43

Because the monsoon determined trade cycles, climate had a strategic implication. That is, unilateral solutions and one-way exit or entry strategies were not as useful as some parties might have wished, because the monsoon winds simultaneously empowered and disempowered different trading agents with its cycles. The only exception to the whims of the wind was Zanzibar because the monsoon did not affect its trade with the mainland, a strategic advantage that facilitated the transformation of the island into an export-import monopolistic port.

I now turn to the analysis of the contractual patterns of specific political agents over time. Again, modern names used here are approximations of historical places where the events under study took place.

Based upon the volume of contracts and the durability of contracting activities, Zanzibar appears as a major power in trade relations. Zanzibar’s contractual activities peaked around the years 1884 and 1885, followed by a steady decline only after 1895. This pattern suggests: (a) the influential role of the Indian Ocean slave trade in the making of Zanzibar’s economy; and (b) the position of the island as a full-fledged negotiator that the colonial powers had to grapple with during the territorial scramble for Africa in the late nineteenth century.

Intangibles: The Rise of Anti-Slavery Discourse and Policy

The data collected show Zanzibar’s contractual transactions starting in the mid-nineteenth century when the abolitionist discourse and policy were in full swing. Before the emergence of the abolitionist discourse and policy, the most strategic concerns of different Arab families in East Africa were the consolidation and preservation of their independence from Oman. The politics before the early nineteenth century were therefore dominated by internal feuds between the houses of Mazrui, the pro-independence faction, and the Busaidi, who were in favor of continuing their allegiance to Oman. After establishing themselves at Zanzibar in the late eighteenth century, the authority of the Mazrui continued to be challenged from Oman and from the mainland. The loss of Pemba, Zanzibar’s main food supply, led to a search for strategic alliances to prevent the island from falling back under the authority of Oman. With the demise of the Portuguese in the region, a strategy was devised to contract out independence to the British stationed at Bombay in India. A letter by Abdulla bin Ahmed sent to Bombay explained that “he was the ruler of an independent state which Said bin Sultan of Oman wished to annex,”Footnote44 and declared that he would rather give the said independent state to England. This request was rejected given the close ties that bound Britain and Oman. Notwithstanding this complication, the Mazrui amended their offer by giving “half of [their] revenues” to Britain in exchange for an officer stationed on the coast.Footnote45 The British never formally accepted the offer, but the changes in the discourse over trade practice and policy made their presence in the region necessary. Instead of working with the Mazrui stationed at Mombasa, Bombay chose to cooperate with Sultan Seyyid Said in Oman who regained control of the East African Coast in the early nineteenth century after turning local protests against the Mazrui family to his advantage.

In 1807 the British adopted the Slave Trade Act which outlawed slave trade in all territories and dominions. Previous attempts to curb the slave trade yielded imperfect results in East Africa, the reason being that the Sultan of Oman derived substantial revenues from taxes levied on slave ships from Zanzibar. The French merchants at Mauritius and the Bourbon islands had independently secured slave trade concessions with Zanzibar and Kilwa in 1776, 1785, and 1819, and competed with Portuguese and Spanish merchants.Footnote46 To win the collaboration of Oman, the British strategically likened the slave trade to piracy, which they had previously fought against alongside Seyyid. The reinvention of an anti-piracy discourse in the form of a fight against slavery offered the discursive incentive to the Sultan of Oman to agree to a treaty with Moresby in 1822. Given the economic returns of the slave trade from Zanzibar to the Omani treasury, this political discourse proved strategically significant because the treaty took effect in Zanzibar where the Omani had previously migrated. Thus,

1840s is climacteric in the history of the East African coastline, since it saw the setting up in Zanzibar of a court whose ruler had foreign diplomatic connections—the first in tropical Africa—with France, with Britain, and with the United States. From the United States, he accepted a consul in Zanzibar in 1836, and from Britain a consul, Atkins Hamerton, in 1840. This, so far as the British were concerned, was mainly to confirm and support the Moresby Treaty of 1822, by which Said had agreed to make illegal throughout his dominions the sale of slaves to the subjects of Christian powers, and to confirm trading conditions already existing. For the Americans it was a similar confirmation. These changes brought Europe and the United States into permanent formal contact with Zanzibar.Footnote47

The Omani edict of 1850, when the contractual history of Zanzibar starts in my sample, forbade slave trading to Indian merchants on the East African Coast leading to, on the one hand, the consolidation of Zanzibar authority in the sub-region, and on the other hand, to an increase in slave capture for the local plantation industry.Footnote48 But Sultan Seyyid Said’s double-dealings with the slave trade and pirates quickly led some colonial administrators to reconsider the offer from the Mazrui family as well as new partnerships with other groups in the hinterland.

Beside Britain and France, Germany played a key role in expanding the contractual affairs of the East Coast. The date of the first contract recorded in my sample is 1859, the year of the treaty on Trade, Friendship and Navigation between the Hanseatic League and Zanzibar. In it, “the Hanseatic cities [Hamburg, Bremen, and Lübeck] of Germany asked the Sultan to provide a legal framework for the ever increasing trade. ... Modeled after the respective treaties which Zanzibar had concluded with the United States, England and France. … In 1860 Johann Witt, representative of the firm William O’Swald, was nominated the first German Consul in Zanzibar.”Footnote49 Henrich Ruete, a German merchant, even won the heart of Sayyida Salme, the Sultan’s sister, and gave Germany a prominent role on the East African Coast.Footnote50

Like their predecessors, the German merchants traded with the island of Zanzibar and bought territorial concessions from disgruntled vassals from the mainland. By 1885, a mixture of trade contracts, gunboat diplomacy, and strategic alliances with Britain put Zanzibar under the control of Germany. The ascendancy of German firms, however, cannot be dissociated from the economic gains and territorial footholds they received from dissatisfied Sultans in the mainland. Similarly, on the British side, the proclamation of a Protectorate over Mombasa, Malindi, and Pangani (1824–26) is a tale of Captain Owen’s attempt to suppress the slave trade as well as a result of scuffles with local chiefs bidding for power against the house of Mazrui that in turn was betting against Oman.

While one notes that the contractual language and subsequent interpretations of the historical documents often focused on the citizenship of the agents, it is important to remember that prior to 1885, private European companies and other non-state actors on the continent were also engaged in political diplomacy. Thus the language of “treaties” is somewhat misleading because it seems to overemphasize the role of the “public agent,” or the state, while simultaneously ignoring the “private” dimensions of early trade deals in Africa. Nevertheless, the distinction and intertwining of public/private forces is important to note especially when analyzing the decisional motivations of African agents in this context. Here, strategy and choice may appear to be confounded, but they remain distinct. The Africans’ bargaining opportunities and choice of contracting partners became more restricted in the late nineteenth century, thanks to the outright scramble of the continent. Nevertheless, the use of contracts as instruments of cooperation and non-cooperation points to something else in East Africa: a progressive attempt to harness the winds of discontent. To use fashion imagery, the external-internal agential aspect of Africa’s contractual history allows one to identify the local threads of objection, rebellion, anger, and dissatisfaction in the quilt of colonial possessions; a search for new modes of freedom, and a fight against monopolistic forces in societies. These are the politically significant intangibles worth noticing as they narrow the interval between the colonial history and contemporary challenges to public procurement practices and reform in Africa today.

This is illustrated by the political contracts between coastal dwellers and the hinterland with Britain and Germany which simultaneously pulled in and pushed power away from Zanzibar. In the year leading to the conference of Berlin in 1885, British negotiators secured treaties with chiefs Chagga and Taveta in the presence of Sir J. W. Matthews, in which they recognized their loyalty to the Sultan of Zanzibar. Conversely, German treaties signed with many chiefs from the mainland and hinterland tended to disavow Zanzibar’s supremacy:

On November 26 1884, a declaration and agreement was signed at Msevero by the “Governor,” Salim bin Hamed, and Dr. Peters. The agreement stated that the Governor, who for four years had been First Plenipotentiary of the Sultan of Zanzibar in Nguru, had declared that the Sultan did not possess suzerainty or protectorate on the mainland East Africa, and specifically not in Nguru or Usagara. … On 2 December 1884, the Sultan Mbumi, Lady of the Province of Mukondokwa (or Mkondogwa) in Usagara, who declared that she was not and never had been dependent in any way on the Sultan of Zanzibar, signed a treaty with Dr. Peters, in which she declared that she, with the consent of the people, made over to him as the representative of the Society for German Colonization, her whole territory, with all civil and public rights, for all time and without any condition.Footnote51

Analyzed from the perspective of European possessions, these historical dealings have mainly been seen as colonial. The nineteenth-century swapping of trade and political status between public and private agents ended with the consolidation of a colonial regime. Nevertheless, when one examines the motivational processes and tactical choices from an Africanist perspective, it becomes probable that the theory, not the action of the parties, might be at fault here. Scholars have not seen the pedagogical, value-laden relevance of the seemingly subpar African choice in colonial encounters because rational choice assumptions confound strategy with choice and sovereignty with independence.

Reflection

It made sense to Africans to bargain over sovereignty because independence seemed to matter more to them. Looking back, these controversial historical choices force one to query the meaning of independence without sovereignty and vice versa. Looking forward, and given the contingencies of the modern state and governments, one might ask, what kind of independence becomes toxic and what kind is worth keeping when governments contract out goods and/or services to mostly private/foreign firms today? If one thinks the choices of Africans were “irrational,” existing concerns about government outsourcing suggest the contrary.Footnote52 While some caution against the rise of a new corporate imperialism,Footnote53 others see opportunities for new forms of partnership between central governments, local governments, and the private sector (profit and non-profit) for the provision of public goods,Footnote54 and none is satisfied with either purely public or private law regulatory mechanisms,Footnote55 or with an exclusive economic approach to reform.Footnote56 Thus, revisiting the past from an Africanist perspective is humbling in the sense that it reveals how contemporary governance problems remain unanswered questions of the past. More importantly, the theoretical overture here suggests that inquiry into global governance should not be bound to a particular, that is, Western epistemological, genealogy.

So, where does all of this lead us? Hopefully, to rethinking the function that intangibles occupy in matters of contractual relationships for economic development and security. Intangibles matter in contractual relationships because they create equilibrating dynamics that are imperfectly captured in rational strategic choice models. Economics or law alone do not explain why political entities contract out services; nor can rational choice make sense of the historical contracting dynamics in East Africa. As demonstrated, climate conditioned the trade environment as a repeated game of interactions, thereby restricting simple and unilateral moves. Although predictable, the repeated cycles of the monsoon winds made strategy unstable. That is, strategic behavior was a combination of agents’ ability to spot particular favorable trade/political configurations, not a unique optimal solution.

Intangibles matter because they increase the scope of what matters. Put differently, they are the things bargained for as well as the prerequisites for bargaining. Intangibles in this sense might explain historically why given political discontent and fragmentation, some societies do not collapse. Hence sovereignty and independence appear at times as a choice and at other times as a strategy with delayed choice. We are accustomed to thinking of sovereignty as a choice, thanks to Hobbes and consorts. The data, however, suggest another possibility: sovereignty as a strategy.

My findings about the use of concepts and practices of sovereignty in the northern part of East Africa could be interpreted as countering and critiquing emerging visions of an international order organized around the notion of sovereignty “as an outcome of ongoing interactions between states” only.Footnote57 When non-Western people bargained with Western non-state actors prior to 1885 in Africa, they incorporated and transformed angles and possibilities for critical engagements with the emerging state-centered monopoly over political coercion in the provision of public goods. As Thomson argues, the transition from a heterogeneous management of violence to state monopolization of (domestic and extraterritorial) order did not displace old strategic bargaining practices. Confronted with social resistance of powerful groups against the monopolization of political and coercive power, rulers often “struck bargains with various societal groups. …These bargains constitute[d] subplots in the central drama in which the state achieved ultimate authority, especially on the use of coercion, within its territory.”Footnote58 Charles Tilly’s empirical study of the evolution of European states equally shows that “everywhere… the nation’s creation of military might involved its agents in bargaining with power holders and with groups of ordinary people.”Footnote59 To the extent that Ethiopia’s strategic procurement and political discourse differtiated independence from sovereignty, its case departs from the widely spread amalgamations persistent in international relations theory today.Footnote60 Furthermore, by combining formal diplomacy and bargaining with private contractors, East Africa’s strategic procurements could be seen as stretching the territorial dimensions and political location of subplots against the international normative sovereign order of the time.

Notes on contributor

S. N. Nyeck is a visiting senior research fellow at the Intersectional Center for Social Justice and Inclusion (INCISE), Canterbury Christ Church University, UK, and a research fellow with the Amsterdam Institute for Social Science Research (AISSR), University of Amsterdam. She writes about government outsourcing, sexuality and politics in Africa. She is the editor of Public Procurement Reform and Governance in Africa (Palgrave-Macmillan, 2016).

Notes

An earlier version of this article was presented in the workshop “Fading Europe? Confronting Limitations/Envisioning Alternatives,” ISSEI’s 15th International Conference, the University of Lodz, Poland, 11–15 July 2016.

1. Millette, Treaties in Force; Seaton and Maliti, Tanzania Treaty Practice; Rubenson, ed., Internal Rivalries; and Rubenson, ed., Correspondence and Treaties.

2. Verkuil, Outsourcing Sovereignty. The author suggests outsourcing always threatens democracy because there is a fundamental link between sovereignty and democracy.

3. See for example the United Nations’ Millennium Development Goals and the Post-2015 Development Agenda calling for more partnership between the public and private sector for a sustainable development (https://goo.gl/VP4xD0) September 2014.

4. Carland, The Colonial Office and Nigeria; and Sunderland, Managing the British Empire.

5. Baker, Government and Contractors; Cooley and Spruyt, Contracting States; and Spruyt, The Sovereign State.

6. The idea of intangibles as “unseen wealth” is borrowed from Blair and Wallman, Unseen Wealth. My concern, however, is not about the management, measurement, and reporting of intangibles. I understand the intellectual, political, and social premise of intangibles in the procurement process as inseparable from the economic and profit motives of agents. Political independence is one of such motives.

7. The concerns about outsourcing state violence to private contractors in a context of peace and war in the twentieth century revolved around prison management. On these concerns, see Tabarrok, ed., Changing the Guard; Blakely, America’s Prisons; and Selman and Leighton, Punishment for Sale. On the use of torture and indiscriminate killings in the war on terror, see Singer, Corporate Warriors; Avant, The Market for Force; Pelton, Licensed to Kill; Scahill, Blackwater; Rasor and Bauman, Betraying our Troops; Uesseler, Servants of War; and Hartung, Prophets of War.

8. Rubenson, ed., Internal Rivalries and Foreign Threats; and Rubenson, ed., Correspondence and Treaties.

9. Abir, Ethiopia: The Era of the Princes, xxiii.

10. Rubenson, ed., Correspondence and Treaties, vol. 1, 46, 36, 66.

11. Rubenson, ed., Internal Rivalries and Foreign Threats, vol. 3, 241, document 168.

12. Ibid.

13. Keller, Revolutionary Ethiopia, 51.

14. Rubenson, ed., Internal Rivalries, vol. 3, 241, document 169.

15. Keller, Revolutionary Ethiopia, 28.

16. For Yohannes IV’s correspondences with different foreign powers during his reign, see Rubenson, ed., Internal Rivalries and Foreign Threats, vol. 3.

17. Ibid., vol. 3, 242, document 170. My emphasis

18. Ibid.

19. In return for his good services, Menelik granted Pierre Arnoux a piece of land (about 20 x 50 square kilometers). The new contractual elements were the following: the land grant was made according to French Law; Menelik promised to eject the farmers who were settled on the land—nothing is said about relocation or compensation of the farmers; Arnoux was entitled to cede or give away the land as well as the stream on the condition that it will all be “utilized for cultivation, irrigation, or establishment of factories.” Arnoux is referred to as “the French merchant.” Given at Liche on June 10, 1876. Rubenson, ed., Internal Rivalries. vol. 3, 243, document 171.

20. The Maria Theresa thalers were minted throughout the Austrian Empire in limited numbers and circulated in different parts of Africa during the scramble period (1880–1900). Great Britain and Italy later manipulated the currency and acquired a monopolistic edge on trade and politics on the East African Coast. For details, see Gervais, “Pre-colonial Currencies,” 147–52.

21. Rubenson, ed., Internal Rivalries, vol. 3, 27, document 22.

22. Ibid., 339, document 235.

23. Millette, ed., Treaties in Force, documents 1 and 3.

24. Keller, Revolutionary Ethiopia, 31; and Bulatovich, Ethiopia through Russian Eyes, 98.

25. Rubenson, ed., Internal Rivalries, vol. 3, 339, documents 235 and 161.

26. Misunderstandings such as the one that arose from the interpretation of the Treaty of Wuchale were quite rare and point to the overbearing impact of aggression and war on traditional diplomacy. Nevertheless, what is important from my perspective is to note that the contestation ex-post of the intent of the treaty was never presented as an outright denial of its existence. A deeper understanding of the context and agents involved in the signing of the treaty helps clarify the origin of the misunderstanding. See Caulk, “Between the Jaws of Hyenas”; and Erlich, Ethiopia and Eritrea. For a critical analysis of Menelik II’s relations with Italy as well as how the financial demise of the army of occupation complicated the mobilization of white battalions and native troops on the ground, see Berkeley, Campaign of Adowa, chap. 7.

27. Hansard, February 28, 1895, vol. 31 c31, “Mission to Russia” <https://goo.gl/VfHjxE>.

28. Bulatovich, Ethiopia through Russian Eyes, bk. 2, 173.

29. Although this article is not concerned with the procurement practices of European powers in Africa per se, it might be useful to highlight the fact that the defeat of Italy could be attributable to dysfunctional war procurement systems and parliamentarian bickering over budget. See Berkeley, Campaign of Adowa, chap. 7.

30. Bulatovich, Ethiopia through Russian Eyes, bk. 2, 173–74.

31. Keller, Revolutionary Ethiopia, 33.

32. Bulatovich, Ethiopia through Russian Eyes, 101–2.

33. Ibid., 102.

34. China’s sea power reached the East African Coast in the fifteenth century before the arrival of the Europeans. Historians have traced early gifts from the king of Mombasa (modern Kenya) to the Chinese emperor at this time, but contacts with China were bound to be superseded by East African trade with the Europeans because of China’s isolationist policies that followed after initial contacts. See Lodewijk Duyvendak, China’s Discovery of Africa; and Levathes, When China Rules the Seas.

35. Coptic Christianity in Ethiopia has a longer history in this region. In fact, according to Gray in Early Portuguese Missionaries, some of the early missionaries were interested in the East Coast in part because they were looking for Prester John, a legendary “Christian King of Ethiopia, of whom the peoples of Europe had heard so much, and from whom they expected so much aid in their struggle against the Moors” (2). Nevertheless, when I refer to Christianity, I am mainly referring to the religion the Europeans brought to the Coast.

36. Gray, Early Portuguese Missionaries, 3.

37. Ibid., chap. 4.

38. Nicholls, The Swahili Coast, 23.

39. Gray, Early Portuguese Missionaries, 5.

40. Middleton, African Merchants, 35–36. The date varies in different sources. The Sultanate, however, became consolidated only after the defeat of the Portuguese in Mombasa in 1832. The actual transfer of the independent Omani Sultanate from Muscat to Zanzibar took place around 1861. See Seaton and Maliti. Tanzania Treaty Practice, 5.

41. Nicholls, The Swahili Coast, 33.

42. See a very interesting analysis of the effects of the monsoon on the economies and local strategies of the Gulf of Persia port cities in Floor, The Persian Gulf.

43. Nicholls, The Swahili Coast, 46.

44. Gray, Early Portuguese Missionaries, 21.

45. Ibid., 21.

46. Nicholls, The Swahili Coast, 198, 131–36.

47. Her Majesty’s Stationary Office, Zanzibar: Exchange of letters between His Highness the Sultan of Zanzibar and the British Resident terminating the 1890 Agreement as respects the Dominions of the Sultan not Comprised in in the Kenya Protectorate. Presented to Parliament by the Secretary of State for the Colonies by Command of Her Majesty, December 1963. Although a minor player with Zanzibar, Italy added his name to the cohort of consular representation in 1885, secured a concession contract of the Benadir Ports on August 12, 1892, the duration of which was set to three years after additional negotiations in 1893. See Herslet, Map of Africa, vol. 2, documents 201, 203, and 204.

48. Nicholls, The Swahili Coast, 211–15.

49. Schneppen, Zanzibar and the Germans, Occasional Paper, no. 10, 1.

50. For a brief history of Germany, Islam, and Christianity in Zanzibar, see Schneppen, Sayyida Salme/Emilie Ruete, Occasional Paper, no. 12.

51. Seaton and Maliti, Tanzania Treaty Practice, 7–8. The authors provide a thorough list of treaties on page 9.

52. Government contracts make scholars and policymakers worry about the future of foreign policy, democracy, civil liberties, domestic security and public spending, international peace and cooperation. See Stanger, One Nation under Contract; Freeman and Minow, eds., Government by Contract; Blakely, America’s Prisons; and Cedilot and Noel, Mafia Inc.

53. Scheidernman, Constitutionalizing Economic Globalization; and Gourevitch and Shinn, Political Power & Corporate Control.

54. Minow, Partners, Not Rivals; and Mary-Scott, Collaboration Nation..

55. Goldstein, et al., eds., Legalization and World Politics.

56. McCrudden, Buying Social Justice.

57. Thomson, Mercenaries, Pirates, and Sovereigns, 5.

58. Ibid., 4. My emphasis.

59. Tilly, Coercion, Capital, 100.

60. A number of scholars have raised concerns about the fitness of international relations theory and social science models in the developing world. See Newman, ed., International Relations and the Third World; Connell, Southern Theory; Comaroff and Comaroff, Theory from the South; Cornelissen, Cheru, and Shaw, eds., African and International Relations; and Dunn and Shaw, eds., Africa’s Challenge to International Relations.

References

  • Abir, Mordechai. Ethiopia: The Era of the Princes. Washington: Praeger, 1970.
  • Avant, Deborah. The Market for Force: The Consequence of Privatizing Security. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 2005.
  • Baker, Norman. Government and Contractors: The British Treasury and War Supplies 1775–1783. London: The Althone Press, 1971.
  • Berkeley, George Fitz-Hardinge. The Campaign of Adowa and the Rise of Menelik. Westminster: Archibald Constable, 1902.
  • Blair, Margaret, and Steven M. H. Wallman. Unseen Wealth: Report of the Brookings Task Force on Intangibles. Washington, DC: The Brookings Institution Press, 2001.
  • Blakely, Curtis R. America’s Prisons: The Movement Toward Profit and Privatization. Florida: Brown Walker Press, 2005.
  • Bulatovich, Aleksandr Ksaver’evich. Ethiopia through Russian Eyes: Country in Transition 1896–1898. Translated by Richard Seltzer. New Jersey: Red Sea Press, 2000.
  • Carland, John M. The Colonial Office and Nigeria, 1898–1914. Stanford, CA: Hoover Institution Press, 1985.
  • Caulk, Richard Alan. “Between the Jaws of Hyenas”: A Diplomatic History of Ethiopia (1876–1896). Edited by Bahru Zewde. Wiesbaden: Harrassowitz Verlag, 2002.
  • Cedilot, André, and André Noel. Mafia Inc. Grandeur et Misère du Clan Sicilien au Québec. Québec: Les Editions de L’Homme, 2010.
  • Clarence-Smith, William. “Indian and Arab Entrepreneurs in Eastern Africa, 1800–1914.” In Négoce Blanc en Afrique Noire: L’Evolution du Commerce à Longue Distance en Afrique Noire du 18ème au 20ème Siècle, edited by Hubert Bonin, 335–49. Paris: Société Française d’Histoire d’Outre-Mer, 2001.
  • Comaroff, Jean, and John Comaroff. Theory from the South: Or How Euro-America is Evolving Toward Africa. Boulder, CO: Paradigm Publishers, 2011.
  • Connell, Raewyn. Southern Theory: Social Science and the Global Dynamics of Knowledge. London: Polity, 2007.
  • Cooley, Alexander, and Hendrik Spruyt. Contracting States: Sovereign Transfers in International Relations. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press, 2009.
  • Cornelissen, Scarlett, Fantu Cheru, and Timothy M. Shaw, eds. African and International Relations in the 21st Century. New York: Palgrave-Macmillan, 2011.
  • Dunn, Kevin C., and Timothy M. Shaw, eds. Africa’s Challenge to International Relations Theory. New York: Palgrave-Macmillan, 2001.
  • Erlich, Haggai. Ethiopia and Eritrea during the Scramble for Africa: A Political Biography of Rās Alulā, 1875–1897. East Lansing: Michigan State University African Center, 1982.
  • Floor, Willem. The Persian Gulf: A Political and Economic History of Five Port Cities 1500–1730. Washington, DC: Mage, 2006.
  • Freeman, Jody, and Martha Minow, eds. Government by Contract: Outsourcing and American Democracy. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press, 2009.
  • Gervais, Raymond. “Pre-colonial Currencies: A Note on the Maria Theresa Thaler.” African Economic History (1982): 147–152.
  • Goldstein, Judith L., Miles Kahler, Robert O. Keohane, and Anne-Marie Slaughter, eds. Legalization and World Politics. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press, 2001.
  • Gourevitch, Peter, and James Shinn. Political Power and Corporate Control: The New Global Politic of Corporate Governance. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press, 2005.
  • Gray, Sir John. The British in Mombasa 1824–1826: Being the History of Captain Owen’s Protectorate. London: Macmillan, 1957.
  • Hartung, William D. Prophets of War: Lockheed Martin and the Making of the Military-Industrial Complex. New York: Nation Books, 2011.
  • Herslet, Edward. Map of Africa by Treaty, Vol. 2. Charleston, SC: Bibliobazaar, 1894. Documents 201, 203, and 204.
  • Keller, Edmond. Revolutionary Ethiopia: From Empire to People’s Republic. Bloomington: Indiana University Press, 1988.
  • Levathes, Louise. When China Rules the Seas: The Treasure Fleet of the Dragon Throne, 1404–1433. Oxford: Oxford University Press, 1997.
  • Lodewijk Duyvendak, Jan Julius. China’s Discovery of Africa: Lectures Given at the University of London on January 22 and 23 1947. A. Probsthain’s Oriental Series, 1949.
  • McCrudden, Christopher. Buying Social Justice: Equality, Government Procurement and Legal Change. Oxford: Oxford University Press, 2007.
  • Middleton, John. African Merchants of the Indian Ocean: Swahili of the East African Coast. Long Grove, IL: Waveland, 2004.
  • Millette, Anne Marie Jacomy, ed. Treaties in Force 1889–1971: Draft List of Treaties and Other International Agreements of Ethiopia. Addis Ababa: Addis Ababa University Press, 1973.
  • Minow, Martha. Partners, Not Rivals: Privatization and the Public Good. Boston, MA: Beacon Press, 2002.
  • “Mission to Russia.” Hansard, February 28, 1895, Vol. 31 c31. https://goo.gl/VfHjxE.
  • Nabers, Mary Scott. Collaboration Nation: How Public-Private Ventures are Revolutionizing the Business of Government. Doylestown, PA: Platform Press, 2012.
  • Neuman, Stephanie G., ed. International Relations and the Third World. New York: St. Martin’s Press, 1998.
  • Nicholls, Christine Stephanie. The Swahili Coast: Politics, Diplomacy and Trade on the East African Littoral, 1798–1856. New York: Africana Publishing Corporation, 1971.
  • Pelton, Robert Young, ed. Licensed to Kill: Hired Guns in the War on Terror. New York: Three Rivers Press, 2006.
  • Rasor, Dina, and Robert Bauman. Betraying our Troops: The Destructive Results of Privatizing War. New York: Palgrave-Macmillan, 2008.
  • Rubenson, Sven, ed. Correspondence and Treaties 1800–1854, Acta Aethiopica. Vol. 1. Addis Abeba: Addis Abeba University Press, 1987.
  • Rubenson, Sven, ed. Internal Rivalries and Foreign Threats 1869–1879 Acta Aethiopica. vol. 3. Addis Abeba: Addis Abeba University Press, 2000.
  • Scahill, Jeremy. Blackwater: The Rise of the World’s Most Powerful Mercenary Army. New York: Nation Books, 2007.
  • Scheidernman, David. Constitutionalizing Economic Globalization: Investment Rules and Democracy’s Premise. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 2008.
  • Schneppen, Heinz. Sayyida Salme/Emilie Ruete: Between Zanzibar and Germany, Between Islam and Christianity. Tanzania: National Museums of Tanzania, 1999.
  • Schneppen, Heinz. Zanzibar and the Germans: A Special Relationshi 1844–1966. Tanzania: National Museums of Tanzania, 1998.
  • Seaton, Earle E., and Sosthenes T. Maliti. Tanzania Treaty Practice. Dar Es Salaam: Oxford University Press, 1973.
  • Selman, Donna, and Paul Leighton. Punishment for Sale: Private Prisons, Big Business, and the Incarceration Binge. New York: Rowman & Littlefield, 2010.
  • Singer, Peter Warren. Corporate Warriors: The Rise of the Privatized Military Industry. Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press, 2003.
  • Spruyt, Hendrik. The Sovereign State and its Competitors. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press, 1994.
  • Stanger, Allison. One Nation under Contract: The Outsourcing of American Power and the Future of Foreign Policy. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press, 2009.
  • Sunderland, David. Managing the British Empire: The Crown Agent, 1883–1914. Suffolk: The Royal Historical Society, 2004.
  • Tabarrok, Alexander, and Charles H. Logan, eds. Changing the Guard: Private Prisons and the Control of Crime. Oakland, CA: The Independent Institute, 2003.
  • Thomson, Janice E.. Mercenaries, Pirates, and Sovereigns. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press, 1994.
  • Tilly, Charles. Coercion, Capital, and European States AD 990–1992. Cambridge: Blackwell, 1992.
  • Uesseler, Rolf. Servants of War: Private Military Corporations and the Profit Conflict. Translated by Jefferson Chase. New York: Soft Skull Press, 2008.
  • Verkuil, Paul R. Outsourcing Sovereignty: Why Privatization of Government Functions Threatens Democracy and What We Can Do About It. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 2007.