2,852
Views
2
CrossRef citations to date
0
Altmetric
Original Articles

Testing the validity of Gibrat’s law in the context of profitability performance

&
Pages 2850-2863 | Received 28 Mar 2018, Accepted 03 Jun 2019, Published online: 29 Aug 2019

Abstract

The purpose of the article is to investigate whether the profitability of firms affects the validity of Gibrat’s law. We begin with the thesis that small firms have less access to outside financial sources (especially bank loans) than large companies, so the role of profit in generating growth varies depending on firm size and is probably more important for smaller companies. We divided a large sample of companies (about 30,000 firms) into three profitability groups (lower 25%, middle 50%, and upper 25% of firms) to examine whether the size-growth relationship is influenced by profitability. Gibrat’s law was verified both at the aggregate level and at the industry level (using one-digit NACE classification). The results show that the validity of Gibrat’s law is not significantly influenced by the amount of firm profit at the aggregate level or at the industry level. In most sectors and profitability groups, smaller firms grow faster than their larger counterparts do.

JEL classification:

1. Introduction

Robert Gibrat (Citation1931) investigated French manufacturing firms and concluded that firm growth is a random effect, independent of firm size. This idea is known as Gibrat’s law or the law of proportionate effect. Many studies have followed from Gibrat’s work and are devoted to empirically testing the validity of Gibrat’s law. A review of these studies and a summary of their conclusions can be found, for instance, in Santarelli, Klomp, and Thurik (Citation2006); another review of more recent studies was presented in Nassar, Almsafir, and Al-Mahrouq (Citation2014).

The results of studies testing the validity of Gibrat’s law vary significantly. Some studies reject Gibrat’s law; others confirm it or present mixed results. This raises the question: Why are the findings of empirical studies so different? Some of the factors that can affect the validity of Gibrat’s law have been very well investigated. These include the minimum efficient scale (MES) of production (e.g. Daunfeldt & Elert, Citation2013; Teruel-Carrizosa, Citation2010), type of ownership (e.g. Djankov & Murrell, Citation2002; Estrin, Hanousek, Kočenda, & Svejnar, Citation2009; Ivandić, Citation2015), industry uncertainty (Daunfeldt & Elert, Citation2013; Lensink, van Steen, & Sterken, Citation2005), and ownership structure (e.g., Bottazzi & Secchi, Citation2006; Fagiolo & Luzzi, Citation2006; Variyam & Kraybill, Citation1992). Very little attention has been paid to profitability as a factor that could affect the size-growth relationship. To fill this gap in the literature, this study investigates the influence of the ‘profitability’ factor.

The aim of this article is to examine if the profitability of companies affects the validity of Gibrat’s law.

Like Mukhopadhyay and AmirKhalkhali (Citation2010), we begin with the thesis that large firms can obtain outside funding (especially bank loans) or new registered capital more easily than their smaller counterparts. Thus, the facilitating role of profit in generating growth differs depending on the size of a company, and it is probably more important for the smaller companies than for the larger ones. Hence, the validity of Gibrat’s law may vary depending on profit. As small firms have less access to external sources of financing, there could be a tendency for low-profitability large companies to grow faster (due to better access to bank loans) than low profitability small ones. Gibrat’s law should be valid for highly profitable firms where the need for external financing is lower.

In contrast to most previous studies, we: (1) test the validity of Gibrat’s law in the context of profitability as we mentioned above, only one previous study deals with this issue; (2) use a large sample of about 30,000 firms; (3) prove the relationship on an industry level; and (4) present the first findings about the size-growth relationship in the context of profitability for the Czech Republic.

This article is organised as follows: Section 2 focuses on a literature review; Section 3 describes the data used and methodology applied; Section 4 shows the empirical results, discusses the achieved results, and compares them with the findings of previous studies; and the last section, titled Conclusion, deals with a concise recapitulation of the main findings.

2. Literature review

Many researchers have focused on the relationship between firm growth rate and firm size. Some studies accepted the validity of Gibrat’s law and concluded that firm growth was independent of firm size. These studies were focused mostly on large and mature companies, including Buckley, Dunning, and Pearce (Citation1984), Hart and Prais (Citation1956), and Simon and Bonini (Citation1958). Hart and Prais (Citation1956) examined quoted companies in Great Britain for selected years during 1885–1950. Simon and Bonini (Citation1958) chose the 500 largest U.S. industrial firms from 1954 to 1956. Buckley et al. (Citation1984) investigated the validity of Gibrat’s law using data from the world’s largest companies. Gibrat’s law was also confirmed on a sample of high-tech Norwegian firms (Klette & Griliches, Citation2000), Austrian manufacturing companies (Pfaffermayr & Bellak, Citation2000), Italian manufacturing firms (Del Monte & Papagni, Citation2003), and Portuguese firms (Leitão, Serrasqueiro, & Nunes, Citation2010). Fujiwara, Guilmi, Aoyama, Gallegati, and Souma (Citation2004), who examined firms from 45 European countries, also validated Gibrat’s law.

Many other studies found that smaller firms grew faster than their larger counterparts, so Gibrat’s law was rejected in these papers. A large part of these studies focused on the manufacturing industry in the U.S. (Evans, Citation1987a, Citation1987b), Germany (Almus & Nerlinger, Citation2000), Portugal (Oliveira & Fortunato, Citation2006a), Spain (Calvo, Citation2006), France (Levratto, Tessier, & Zouikri, Citation2010), and Iran (Feizpour, Mahmoudi, & Soltani, Citation2010).

Some researchers, including Dunne and Hughes (Citation1994), Falk (Citation2008), Bentzen, Madsen, and Smith (Citation2012), and Fiala and Hedija (Citation2015), chose to analyse more industries. Dunne and Hughes (Citation1994) verified the link between firm growth rate and firm size in 19 industries. Falk (Citation2008) investigated the manufacturing industry, business services industry, and the mining and energy industry. Fiala and Hedija (Citation2015) tested the size-growth relationship for all industries of the Czech private sector. Bentzen et al. (Citation2012) focused on seven industries: primary industries, manufacturing, construction, wholesale and retail sales and hotels, transport services, financial services, and the publicly regulated sector and social services. In contrast to previous studies, they surprisingly concluded that big firms grew faster than smaller companies in most examined industries.

Some studies produced mixed results. Gibrat’s law was confirmed only for some part of the sample in these studies. Mansfield (Citation1962) analysed three sectors of the manufacturing industry in the U.S., with each sector divided into more periods. Gibrat’s law was rejected in more than half of the cases. Hall (Citation1987), Chen and Lu (Citation2003), Aslan (Citation2008), and Hedija (2016) found similar mixed results. The last of these studies examined the size-growth relationship for 14 sectors (NACE A-N) using a sample of more than 36,000 Czech firms. The validity of Gibrat’s law was confirmed only in two of the fourteen examined sectors. Small firms grew faster than their larger counterparts in the great majority of the Czech private sector.

It is clear that the results of studies testing the validity of Gibrat’s law differ. For this reason, some authors have investigated selected determinants that could influence the validity. Daunfeldt and Elert (Citation2013) used a large sample of Swedish firms and showed that the validity of Gibrat’s law was industry specific. The aim of their study was to identify factors explaining the differences in the validity of Gibrat’s law. They proved the importance of industry size, MES of production, industry age, R&D expenditure, liquidity, ownership, uncertainty, market concentration, and location in explaining the size-growth relationship. They showed that the likelihood that Gibrat’s law would be confirmed was greater in mature industries with high market concentration and a large share of group ownership.

Other factors affecting the validity of Gibrat’s law could be profitability performance and financial constraints. Empirical studies show that access to outside sources of financing varies depending on firm size; small- and medium-sized enterprises (SMEs) have less access to these funds (Donati, Citation2016). The reduced access of SMEs to outside sources (especially to bank loans) in comparison with large firms has also been confirmed in the Czech Republic by empirical studies (Belás, Macháček, Bartoš, Hlawiczka, & Hudáková, Citation2014; Lízal & Svejnar, Citation2002). Empirical findings support the role of profit and financial constraints in firm growth (e.g. Becchetti & Trovato, Citation2002; Colley & Quadrini, Citation2001; Donati, Citation2016; Oliveira & Fortunato, Citation2006b). Using data from Italian firms, Becchetti and Trovato (Citation2002) found that the availability of external financing (subsidy, leverage and financial constraints) significantly affected firm growth. Donati (Citation2016) showed that liquidity constraints hindered the growth of small Italian firms in manufacturing. Oliveira and Fortunato (Citation2006b) used cash flow as a proxy for financial constraints and revealed a higher sensitivity of cash flow on growth for small and younger firms, and that financial constraints hence have a higher impact on the growth of small and young firms. Colley and Quadrini (Citation2001) supported this conclusion, confirming that the investment of small firms was more sensitive to cash flow.

Mukhopadhyay and AmirKhalkhali (Citation2010) tested the size-growth relationship in the context of financial constraints and profitability performance of firms using a sample of 191 large U.S. firms. Return on equity (ROE) was used to measure profitability in this study. They concluded that large firms tended to grow faster than smaller ones regardless of the profitability of companies. We followed this study to re-examine its results using a very large sample of Czech firms and to estimate the validity separately for individual sectors using alternative measures of profitability.

3. Data and methodology

The analysis is based on panel data from the Albertina CZ Gold Edition database for the period from 2007 to 2012. The Albertina database contains information about all companies in the Czech Republic that have an organisation identification number. Because of the specific characteristics of the public sector, we test the validity of Gibrat’s law only for private sector firms, with the private sector defined as industries A-N according to the Statistical Classification of Economic Activities in the European Community (NACE).

We narrowed the sample and used only the data of such companies that had already been in the industry for five years before 2007, survived throughout the study period, and did not change their primary economic activity (using one-digit NACE). We used a balanced panel of firms; the final sample covers the data of 29,437 Czech firms.

Removing the start-up firms and firms that left the market enables us to monitor the development of mature companies in the industry. The development of start-up and ending companies is specific, since start-up companies tend to be smaller, and their initial growth is very dynamic. In contrast, firms in liquidation mostly report a decline or minimum activity regardless of size. Empirical studies show that the Gibrat’s law is more likely to be valid in mature industries (Daunfeldt & Elert, Citation2013; Lotti, Santarelli, & Vivarelli, Citation2009).

We used sales as the indicator of firm size. Sales, total assets, and number of employees are among the most frequently used measurements of firm size in empirical studies (Nassar et al., Citation2014). We chose ‘sales’ because it is the most flexible indicator of the three. The ‘sales’ indicator includes real annual revenues from sales of products, goods, and services. We used the year 2005 as the base period. Real sales were calculated using the consumer price index published by the Czech Statistical Office.1

To assess the validity of Gibrat’s law in the context of firm profitability, we used two profitability ratios as indicators of profitability: return on assets (ROA) and ROE. ROA is defined as earnings before interest and taxes divided by total assets. ROA is a very frequently used measurement for profitability in empirical studies (for an overview, see Hult et al. Citation2008, including studies by Czech researchers, e.g., Šiška, Citation2009). ROE is defined as earnings after taxes (net profit) divided by equity. We also employed this indicator since the ROE includes the leverage, which is an important factor to consider when a bank provides a loan to a firm. In comparison to ROA, ROE encounters problems when both earnings and equity are negative. Firms in this situation seem to be falsely positive ROE (Trimbath, Citation2006). To minimise this problem, we used the absolute value of equity to compute the value of ROE. The descriptive statistics are shown in .

Table 1. Summary statistics by sector (average for the period 2007–2012).

To verify the validity of Gibrat’s law, we applied the approach of Daunfeldt and Elert (Citation2013). They estimate the validity of Gibrat’s law using this model: (1) lnSjti=αj0+αj1.lnSj(t1)i+θjt.Tt+ujt.(1) where Sjti is the size of i-th firm of j-th industry in time t, θjt.Tt  is a vector of time-specific fixed effects. The values of parameter αj1 indicate whether Gibrat’s law is valid. Gibrat’s law holds if αj1 ̂ equal to one. A value smaller than one implies that small firms grow faster than large ones; a value higher than one implies that large firms grow faster than small firms do.

The advantages of this model are its simplicity and relatively low data input requirements. It also includes time-specific fixed effects. Hardwick and Adams (Citation2002) showed that business cycles could play a role and this model makes it possible to consider this. A disadvantage is that it does not address the potential non-linearity of the relationship (for example, see Park & Jang, Citation2010). However, this model is frequently used in empirical studies and it allows comparability of results (e.g., Daunfeldt & Elert, Citation2013; Peric & Vitezic, Citation2016; Tang, Citation2015).

To estimate the validity of Gibrat’s law, we modify the original model (Equationequation 1) to filter out the industry-specific fixed effects. We use this form: (2) lnSjti=αj0+αj1.lnSjt1i+αj2.Tt+αj3.NACEji+αj4k.Tt.NACEji+ujt.(2) where Sjti is the size of i-th firm of j-th industry by one-digit NACE in time t, NACEji is the dummy variable for industry using five-digit NACE classification of i-th firm, αj2.Tt is the vector of time-specific fixed effects, αj3.NACEji is the vector of industry-specific fixed effects, αj4k.Tt.NACEji is a vector of time and industry-specific fixed effects. The values of parameter αj1 indicate whether Gibrat’s law is valid. Gibrat’s law holds if αj1 is equal to one. A value less than one implies that small firms grow faster than large ones; a value higher than one implies that large firms grow faster than small ones.

To consider the validity of Gibrat’s law in the context of the industry and profitability of the firm we divided the firms from every sector (one-digit NACE) into three groups according to profitability: lower 25%, middle 50%, and upper 25% of firms (as in Mukhopadhyay & AmirKhalkhali, Citation2010). We used the mean of ROA/ROE for the examined period as the indicator for the inclusion of a company in the profit group. We then tested the validity of Gibrat’s law using EquationEquation (2). We estimated the model for the whole private sector and then separately for each industry on the level of one-digit NACE and every profitability group.

To allow for heteroskedasticity and serial correlation problem, we used the OLS estimator with cluster-robust standard errors. To confirm or reject Gibrat’s law, we tested the null hypothesis H0:α1̂=1  versus H1:α1̂1  using F-test.

4. Results and discussion

We investigated the validity of Gibrat’s law on the whole sample of private sector companies (NACE A-N) using EquationEquation (2), including industry-specific fixed effects and time-specific fixed effects and their combination, capturing industry and time variant heterogeneity in growth rates. Companies were divided into three profitability groups on the basis of their profitability performance. We used two profitability ratios as the measurement of profitability for more robust results: ROA and ROE Results are shown in . Coefficient α1 is the key indicator for rejection or confirmation of the validity of Gibrat’s law. The validity of Gibrat’s law could be confirmed if α1̂ = 1. F-test was used to test this hypothesis.

Table 2. Testing Gibrat’s law validity – by profit groups.

If profit is an important factor determining the validity of Gibrat’s law, the size-growth relationship should differ across individual profit groups. Considering the difficulties for small firms in accessing external sources of financing, low-profit larger firms (from the lower 25%) could tend to grow faster. Using the sample of more profitable firms (in the middle 50% and upper 25%) with less need for outside funds, the industry should tend validate Gibrat’s law. As shows, Gibrat’s law is rejected both for the whole sample and for all three profitability groups. The findings are similar for both indicators of profitability (ROA and ROE). The results indicate that smaller enterprises grow faster than their larger counterparts in all profitability groups of companies (α1̂ < 1).

These results suggest that profit is not an important determinant of size-growth relationship at the aggregate level. This finding is in harmony with the study by Mukhopadhyay and AmirKhalkhali (Citation2010), who investigated large U.S. industrial firms and concluded that the profitability performance did not influence the size-growth relationship. They also concluded that in many cases large firms tended to grow faster than their smaller counterparts. Their findings contradict the vast majority of previous studies confirming the higher growth dynamic of smaller firms. This result could be explained by their chosen sample of companies. Unlike our study and the majority of studies testing the validity of Gibrat’s law, Mukhopadhyay and AmirKhalkhali (Citation2010) used a sample of the 191 largest U.S. industrial companies. Here, economies of scale could play an important role in supporting the higher growth of large firms.

According to data from the Czech Ministry of Industry and Trade (Citation2013), the importance of profit and other sources of funding differs across industries (see ). Hence, the impact of profit on the validity of Gibrat’s law could vary in individual sectors. Profit and funding both represent important sources of finance in most industries and approximately 30% of total liabilities on average. Significant differences are also found in the use of bank loans and financial accommodations.

Table 3. The share of individual funding sources on total liabilities by sector in 2012 (in %).

The importance of profit in funding is relatively low in sector I, where it amounts to 0% and in sector L, where it represents 14% of total liabilities. Other sources, especially bank loans and financial accommodations, predominated in these sectors. If we assume that small firms were more constrained in obtaining outside funds, the validity of Gibrat’s law could differ for both low and high-profit firms in these sectors and these differences could be significant. In contrast to the sectors in which other sources (especially bank loans and financial accommodations) are not such important funding sources, differences in the validity of Gibrat’s law according to profit groups cannot be expected. In this case, restricted access to outside funds for smaller firms could not be an important factor affecting the size-growth relationship.

We next verify the validity of Gibrat’s law separately for individual sectors (A–N) using one-digit NACE and model (2). The results are presented in .

Table 4. Testing Gibrat’s Law validity by sectors.

Using the sample of all firms and sector levels, the validity of Gibrat’s law is rejected for most sectors of the economy. Using a 5% level of significance, Gibrat’s law is valid only in sectors B, D, and E; we can reject its validity for the rest of the sectors. These results are very similar to those presented by Hedija (Citation2016), who examined the validity of Gibrat’s law in individual sectors of the Czech economy and rejected the validity of Gibrat’s law in the vast majority of industries. The differences in the validity of Gibrat’s law among individual industries are explained by differences in concentration rate, the size of the industry, and the MES of production.

Using the profit groups, the validity of Gibrat’s law is rejected in the majority of cases. The validity of Gibrat’s law was confirmed only in one third of the cases in the examined groups, and it was not proved that companies with higher profits (from the middle 50% and upper 25%) tended to validate Gibrat’s law. The results were very similar for both applied indicators of profitability.

We then focused on sectors in which bank loans and financial accommodations are important sources of funding (sectors I and L). We presume that the validity of Gibrat’s law could vary across individual profit groups in these sectors. As the results show, using the sample of all firms, the validity of Gibrat’s law is rejected for both sectors. Moreover, the size-growth relationship does not differ across individual profit groups in sectors I and L. Small companies tend to grow faster than larger ones here, independent of profit group.

Hence, these results do not prove that profitability is a significant factor affecting the relationship between firm growth and firm size. They show that the size-growth relationship does not vary systematically depending on the amount of firm profit.

Other factors that may affect the growth performance of companies in individual profit groups could play an important role as well. Empirical studies show that in addition to access to financing, foreign ownership, family control, networks, and contacts also influence firm growth (Bellak, Citation2004; Hamelin, Citation2013; Leitner, Citation2016). Other possible explanations could include financial and non-financial support for SMEs from European Union funds and special national funds and institutions (for example, the Czech-Moravian Guarantee and Development Bank) that can make up for missing funds (e. g. bank loans) from commercial banks to minimise the impact of financial constraints (see Ministry of Industry & Trade, 2012).

5. Conclusion

SMEs are considered to be important pillars of the economy. However, they could experience some disadvantages that large companies do not (for example, see Havierniková, Citation2016; Šúbertová & Meszárošová, Citation2015). According to our hypothesis, one disadvantage for SMEs is that they cannot obtain external financial resources as easily as large companies. This could affect the growth rate of small firms. In industries with low profitability, large firms can grow faster than the smaller ones.

This study examined the validity of Gibrat’s law in the context of the profitability performance of firms. We used a large sample of firms, divided into three profitability groups (lower 25%, middle 50%, and upper 25% of firms) to examine whether profit affects significantly the size-growth relationship. We tested the validity of Gibrat’s law at the aggregate level and then at the industry level (using one-digit NACE classification) using the linear auto-regression model. The results show that the size-growth relationship does not vary systematically depending on the amount of firm profit at the aggregate level or at the industry level. We identified the tendency of small firms to grow faster than their larger counterparts regardless of profit group in most sectors.

We can conclude that our results do not prove that profitability is a significant factor affecting the relationship between firm growth and firm size. The rate of profit and the differing access to outside funds do not seem to be factors that negatively affect SMEs in their growth in the Czech Republic. This is a very important finding for the policies supporting SMEs Fiala (Citation2017) confirmed the convergence toward Gibrat-like behaviour over time for sample of SMEs. The article by Fiala (Citation2017) and the findings of this study indicate that SMEs should be supported in the initial period when they have not exceeded the MES of production.

Although our research provides new findings, it is not without limitations. Factors other than profitability and financial constraints could influence the firm-growth relationship, including foreign ownership, family control, and SME support. We have not considered these factors in our analysis, but their influence may prevail.

Due to our relatively surprising results, the possible effect of country-specific factors, and the lack of studies on this topic, further research should focus on testing the influence of profitability on firm-size growth relationships in other countries as well as on capturing the influence of other factors on the validity of Gibrat’s law, especially financial and non-financial support for SMEs.

Disclosure statement

No potential conflict of interest was reported by the authors.

Additional information

Funding

This work was supported by the College of Polytechnics Jihlava, under Grant no. 1170/4/186.

Notes

1 Sales = (revenue from sales of products, goods, and services/C.P.I.).100

References

  • Almus, M., & Nerlinger, E. A. (2000). Testing “Gibrat’s Law” for Young Firms – Empirical Results for West Germany. Small Business Economics, 15(1), 1–12.
  • Aslan, A. (2008). Testing Gibrat’s Law: Empirical evidence from panel unit root tests of Turkish firms. MPRA: Munich Personal RePEc Archive. http://mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/10594/1/mpra_paper_10594.pdf.
  • Becchetti, L., & Trovato, G. (2002). The determinants of growth for small and medium sized firms. The role of the availability of external finance. Small Business Economics, 19(4), 291–306.
  • Belás, J., Macháček, J., Bartoš, P., Hlawiczka, R., & Hudáková, M. (2014). Business risks and the level of entrepreneurial optimism among SME in the Czech and Slovak Republic. Journal of Competitiveness, 6(2), 30–41. doi:10.7441/joc.2014.02.03
  • Bellak, C. (2004). How domestic and foreign firms differ and why does it Matter? Journal of Economic Surveys, 18(4), 483–432. doi:10.1111/j.0950-0804.2004.00228.x
  • Bentzen, J., Madsen, E. S., & Smith, V. (2012). Do firms’ growth rates depend on firm size? Small Business Economics, 39(4), 937–947. doi:10.1007/s11187-011-9341-8
  • Bottazzi, G., & Secchi, A. (2006). Gibrat’s law and diversification. Industrial and Corporate Change, 15(5), 847–875. doi:10.1093/icc/dtl019
  • Buckley, P. J., Dunning, J. H., & Pearce, R. D. (1984). An analysis of the growth and profitability of the world’s largest firms 1972 to 1977. Kyklos, 37(1), 3–26. doi:10.1111/j.1467-6435.1984.tb00738.x
  • Calvo, J. L. (2006). Testing Gibrat’s law for small, young and innovating firms. Small Business Economics, 26(2), 117–123. doi:10.1007/s11187-004-2135-5 doi:10.1007/s11187-004-2135-5
  • Chen, J. R., & Lu, W. C. (2003). Panel unit root tests of firm size and its growth. Applied Economics Letters, 10(6), 343–345. doi:10.1080/1350485022000044075
  • Colley, T. F., & Quadrini, V. (2001). Financial markets and firm dynamics. American Economic Review, 91(5), 1286–1310. doi:10.1257/aer.91.5.1286 doi:10.1257/aer.91.5.1286
  • Czech Statistical Office. (2016). Indexy spotřebitelských cen - inflace - časové řady. Retrieved from http://www.czso.cz/csu/redakce.nsf/i/isc_cr.
  • Daunfeldt, S. O., & Elert, N. (2013). When is Gibrat’s law a law? Small Business Economics, 41(1), 133–147. doi:10.1007/s11187-011-9404-x doi:10.1007/s11187-011-9404-x
  • Del Monte, A., & Papagni, E. (2003). R&D and the growth of firms: Empirical analysis of a panel of Italian firms. Research Policy, 32(6), 1003–1014. doi:10.1016/S0048-7333(02)00107-5
  • Djankov, S., & Murrell, P. (2002). Enterprise restructuring in transition: A quantitative survey. Journal of Economic Literature, 40(3), 739–792. doi:10.1257/jel.40.3.739
  • Donati, C. (2016). Firm growth and liquidity constraints: Evidence from the manufacturing and service sectors in Italy. Applied Economics, 48(20), 1881–1892. doi:10.1080/00036846.2015.1109044
  • Dunne, P., & Hughes, A. (1994). Age, size, growth and survival: UK companies in the 1980s. The Journal of Industrial Economics, 42(2), 115–140. doi:10.2307/2950485
  • Estrin, S., Hanousek, J., Kočenda, E., & Svejnar, J. (2009). The effects of privatization and ownership in transition economies. Journal of Economic Literature, 47(3), 699–728. doi:10.1257/jel.47.3.699
  • Evans, D. S. (1987a). Tests of alternative theories of firm growth. Journal of Political Economy, 95(4), 657–674. doi:10.1086/261480
  • Evans, D. S. (1987b). The relationship between firm growth, size and age: Estimates for 100 manufacturing industries. The Journal of Industrial Economics, 35(4), 567–581. doi:10.2307/2098588
  • Fagiolo, G., & Luzzi, A. (2006). Do liquidity constraints matter in explaining firm size and growth? Some evidence from the Italian manufacturing industry. Industrial and Corporate Change, 15(1), 1–39. doi:10.1093/icc/dtj001
  • Falk, M. (2008). Testing Gibrat’s law for European multinational enterprises. FIW Re-search Report. http://www.fiw.ac.at/fileadmin/Documents/Publikationen/fiwstudie14.pdf.
  • Feizpour, M. A., Mahmoudi, V., & Soltani, E. (2010). The validity of Gibrat’s Law: Evidence from manufacturing industry in Iran: 1995–1998. The International Business & Economics Research Journal, 9(2), 33–36. doi:10.19030/iber.v9i2.519
  • Fiala, R. (2017). Testing convergence toward Gibrat’s law for Czech manufacturing firms. Ekonomický Časopis, 65(8), 737–750.
  • Fiala, R., & Hedija, V. (2015). The relationship between firm size and firm growth: The case of the Czech Republic. Acta Universitatis Agriculturae et Silviculturae Mendelianae Brunensis, 63(5), 1639–1644. doi:10.11118/actaun201563051639
  • Fujiwara, Y., Guilmi, C. D., Aoyama, H., Gallegati, M., & Souma, W. (2004). Do Pareto-Zipf and Gibrat laws hold true? An analysis with European Firms. Physica A: Statistical Mechanics and Its Applications, 335(1–2), 197–216. doi:10.1016/j.physa.2003.12.015
  • Gibrat, R. (1931). Les inégalités économiques. Librairie du Receuil Sirey, Paris.
  • Hall, B. H. (1987). The relationship between firm size and firm growth in the US manufacturing sector. The Journal of Industrial Economics, 35(4), 583–606. doi:10.2307/2098589
  • Hamelin, A. (2013). Influence of family ownership on small business growth. Evidence from French SMEs. Small Business Economics, 41(3), 563–579. doi:10.1007/s11187-012-9452-x
  • Hardwick, P., & Adams, M. (2002). Firm size and growth in the United Kingdom life insurance industry. Journal of Risk & Insurance, 69(4), 577–593. doi:10.1111/1539-6975.00038
  • Hart, P. E., & Prais, S. E. (1956). The analysis of business concentration: A statistical approach. Journal of the Royal Statistical Society, 119(2), 150–191. doi:10.2307/2342882
  • Havierniková, K. (2016). The identification and classification of risks in terms of cluster cooperation. In M. Okręglicka (Ed.), Proceedings of the 1st international conference contemporary issues in theory and practice of management (pp. 130–136). Czestochowa: Czestochowa University of Technology.
  • Hedija. (2016). The validity of Gibrat’s law in individual sectors of Czech economy. In D. Foris (Ed.), 3rd international multidisciplinary scientific conference on social sciences & art SGEM (pp. 897–904). Sofia: STEF92 Technology Ltd.
  • Hult, G. T. M., Ketchen, D. J., Griffith, D. A., Chabowski, B. R., Hamman, M. K., Dykes, B. J., … Cavusgil, S. T. (2008). An assessment of the measurement of performance in international business research. Journal of International Business Studies, 39(6), 1064–1080. doi:10.1057/palgrave.jibs.8400398
  • Ivandić, N. (2015). Gibrat’s law and the impact of ownership: A case study of Croatia’s hotel industry. Tourism Economics, 21(1), 105–120. doi:10.5367/te.2014.0439
  • Klette, J., & Griliches, Z. (2000). Empirical patterns of firm growth and R&D investment: A quality ladder model interpretation. The Economic Journal, 110(463), 363–387. doi:10.1111/1468-0297.00529
  • Leitão, J., Serrasqueiro, Z., & Nunes, P. M. (2010). Testing Gibrat’s law for listed Portuguese companies: A quantile approach. International Research Journal of Finance and Economics, 37, 147–158.
  • Leitner, S. M. (2016). Financing constraints and firm growth in Emerging Europe. South East European Journal of Economics and Business, 11(1), 18–40. doi:10.1515/jeb-2016-0002 doi:10.1515/jeb-2016-0002
  • Lensink, L., van Steen, P., & Sterken, E. (2005). Uncertainty and growth of the firm. Small Business Economics, 24(4), 381–391. doi:10.1007/s11187-005-7121-z
  • Levratto, N., Tessier, L., & Zouikri, M. (2010). The determinants of growth for SMEs. A longitudinal study of French manufacturing firms. Document de Travail Working Paper. Retrieved from http://economix.fr/pdf/dt/2010/WP_EcoX_2010-28.pdf
  • Lízal, L., & Svejnar, J. (2002). Investment, credit rationing, and the soft budget constraint: Evidence from Czech panel data. Review of Economics and Statistics, 84(2), 353–370. doi:10.1162/003465302317411596
  • Lotti, F., Santarelli, E., & Vivarelli, M. (2009). Defending Gibrat’s law as a long-run regularity. Small Business Economics, 32(1), 31–44. doi:10.1007/s11187-007-9071-0
  • Mansfield, E. (1962). Entry, Gibrat’s law, innovation, and the growth of firms. The American Economic Review, 59(5), 1023–1051.
  • Ministry of Industry and Trade. (2012). Small and medium enterprises support strategy 2014–2020. Retrieved from https://www.mpo.cz/assets/dokumenty/47605/54370/599917/priloha001.pdf
  • Ministry of Industry and Trade. (2013). Finanční analýza podnikové sféry se zaměřením na konkurenceschopnost sledovaných odvětví za rok 2012. Retrieved from http://www.mpo.cz/dokument141226.html
  • Mukhopadhyay, A. K., & AmirKhalkhali, S. (2010). Profitability performance and firm size-growth relationship. Journal of Business & Economics Research, 8(9), 121–126. doi:10.19030/jber.v8i9.764
  • Nassar, I. A., Almsafir, M. K., & Al-Mahrouq, M. H. (2014). The validity of Gibrat’s law in developed and developing countries (2008-2013): Comparison based assessment. Procedia - Social and Behavioral Sciences, 129, 266–273. doi:10.1016/j.sbspro.2014.03.676 doi:10.1016/j.sbspro.2014.03.676
  • Oliveira, B., & Fortunato, A. (2006a). Testing Gibrat´s law: Empirical evidence from a panel of Portuguese manufacturing firms. International Journal of the Economics of Business, 13(1), 65–81. doi:10.1080/13571510500519996
  • Oliveira, B., & Fortunato, A. (2006b). Firm growth and liquidity constraints: A dynamic analysis. Small Business Economics, 27(2–3), 139–156. doi:10.1007/s11187-006-0006-y
  • Park, K., & Jang, S. (2010). Firm growth patterns: Examining the associations with firm size and internationalization. International Journal of Hospitality Management, 29(3), 368–377. doi:10.1016/j.ijhm.2009.10.026
  • Peric, M., & Vitezic, V. (2016). Impact of global economic crisis on firm growth. Small Business Economics, 46(1), 1–12. doi:10.1007/s11187-015-9671-z
  • Pfaffermayr, M., & Bellak, C. (2000). Why foreign-owned firms are different: A conceptual framework and empirical evidence for Austria. In E. Jungnickel (Ed.), Foreign-owned firms: Are they different? (pp. 13–57). New York, NY: Palgrave Macmillan.
  • Santarelli, E., Klomp, L., & Thurik, A. R. (2006). Gibrat’s Law: An overview of the empirical literature. In E. Santarelli, (Ed.), Entrepreneurship, growth, and innovation: The dynamics of firms and industries (pp. 41–73). New York: Springer.
  • Simon, H. A., & Bonini, C. P. (1958). The size distribution of business firms. American Economic Review, 48(4), 607–617.
  • Šiška, L. (2009). How to evaluate economic successfulness of an enterprise. In P. Jedlička (Ed.), Hradecke ekonomicke dny 2009 (pp. 306–312). Hradec Králové: Gaudeamus.
  • Šúbertová, E., & Meszárošová, Z. (2015). Comparison of perception of external influences on family businesses in the Slovak Republic and in selected European country. In E. Pastuszková, et al. (Eds.), Proceedings of the 7th international scientific conference finance and performance of firms in science, education and practice (pp. 1511–1523). Zlín: Tomas Bata University.
  • Tang, A. (2015). Does Gibrat’s law hold for Swedish energy firms? Empirical Economics, 49(2), 659–674. doi:10.1007/s00181-014-0883-x
  • Teruel-Carrizosa, M. (2010). Gibrat’s law and the learning process. Small Business Economics, 34(4), 355–373. doi:10.1007/s11187-008-9127-9
  • Trimbath, S. (2006). Financial ratios in quantitative data analysis: A practical guide. In Z. Hoque (Ed.), Methodological issues in accounting research: Theories, methods and issues (pp. 411–425). London: Spiramus Press.
  • Variyam, J. N., & Kraybill, D. S. (1992). Empirical evidence on determinants of firm growth. Economics Letters, 38(1), 31–36. doi:10.1016/0165-1765(92)90157-T