751
Views
0
CrossRef citations to date
0
Altmetric
Introduction

Introduction to symposium

&
Pages 177-178 | Received 15 May 2019, Accepted 20 May 2019, Published online: 25 Jun 2019

This symposium on behavioural economics features some of the papers that were presented during the workshop Economics and/or Psychology? Interdisciplinary Perspectives on Behavioural Economics, which we organised at the University of Helsinki in May 2017. The frame and focus of the workshop were developed in 2015 and 2016 in a reading group on behavioural economics at TINT – Centre for Philosophy of Social Science. The workshop attracted not only speakers from all over the world, but also many people who flew to Helsinki just to listen to the presentations and discuss the past, present, and future of behavioural economics. Readers can find more information about the event in a detailed report written by our colleague Chiara Lisciandra (Citation2017).

The workshop was an attempt to stimulate reflection on the current state of the art in behavioural economics from the perspectives of history and philosophy of science, economic methodology, history of economic thought, science and technology studies, sociology of science, and science policy, as well as from the point of view of self-identified behavioural economists. In the call for papers we asked: Is it possible to define behavioural economics by a set of theoretical or methodological commitments? Is behavioural economics a truly interdisciplinary endeavour, or rather just a minor modification of the so-called neoclassical economics? What is the interplay between the epistemic and the institutional dimensions in the development of interdisciplinary exchanges between economics and other disciplines? We were also interested in investigating factors that contributed to the academic and policy success of behavioural economics; in particular why has the so-called ‘new’ behavioural economics become the mainstream, whereas alternative approaches to integrating psychological insights with economics have not? After two days of our collective effort to address these questions, it became clear that what we call the received view on behavioural economics needs revisions in several ways.

What does the received view consist of? In a nutshell, it states that behavioural economics is a research programme that is (i) alternative to neoclassical economics, that develops (ii) more psychologically realistic models of economic decision-making (iii) based on evidence, mostly coming from the laboratory experiments. It is also widely believed that these features allow behavioural economists to design better, more evidence-based, policies. In what follows, we summarise how the papers presented in this symposium issue complicate the received view or cast doubts on its plausibility.

First of all, Vladimir and Avtonomov’s analysis situates the alleged alternative nature of behavioural economics in an historical context, arguing that the debates around behavioural economics closely follow the established pattern of Methodenstreits in the history of economics. In this sense, behavioural economics is one of a number of ‘behavioural shifts’ that keep redefining dominant modes of analysis in economics. Erik Angner, however, insists that some practitioners mischaracterise this as an assimilation of behavioural economics into neoclassical models. The nature of the synthesis, Angner argues, was the opposite, making everyone behavioural economists now.

Second, the claim that behavioural economics is a more realistic approach to the study of economic behaviour is challenged from a range of perspectives. James Grayot and Michael Joffe argue that it is not clear in which sense behavioural economics is based on psychological findings. Sabine Frerichs argues that the way in which most behavioural economists attempt to integrate ‘the social’ into their models is in fact very limited and reductive in failing to acknowledge the social contingency of behaviour. More generally, behavioural economists’ view of agency – humans as opposed to econs – is criticised as too simplistic to capture its internal and social complexity, such as multiple agents (James Grayot) and gender roles (Giandomenica Becchio).

Finally, concerning the view that behavioural economics is empirical and evidence-based, Joffe suggests a viable alternative to the way mainstream behavioural economists model causal mechanisms based on available empirical findings. O. Çağlar Dede looks at policies inspired by the rise of behavioural economics and shows that the ‘behavioural insights’ are not enough to propose and evaluate evidence-based policy: we need a plurality of scientific findings.

We hope that this symposium will contribute to the enrichment of the received view, by encouraging researchers, including both analysts and practitioners of behavioural economics, to envision and implement different ways of developing this intriguing field.

Correction Statement

This article has been republished with minor changes. These changes do not impact the academic content of the article.

Additional information

Funding

Magdalena Małecka’s work on this project was supported by the Academy of Finland [under grant no. 308682] and by Marie Skłodowska-Curie Fellowship EPISTEMEBEHAVIOUR. Michiru Nagatsu’s work was supported by the Academy of Finland [under grant no. 294545].

Reference

Reprints and Corporate Permissions

Please note: Selecting permissions does not provide access to the full text of the article, please see our help page How do I view content?

To request a reprint or corporate permissions for this article, please click on the relevant link below:

Academic Permissions

Please note: Selecting permissions does not provide access to the full text of the article, please see our help page How do I view content?

Obtain permissions instantly via Rightslink by clicking on the button below:

If you are unable to obtain permissions via Rightslink, please complete and submit this Permissions form. For more information, please visit our Permissions help page.