10,450
Views
15
CrossRef citations to date
0
Altmetric
Original Articles

The Lerner index and revenue maximization

&

ABSTRACT

Based on profit-maximizing behaviour, the usual interpretation of the Lerner index is that a zero value reflects competitive behaviour, while a positive value is associated with market power. We investigate to what extent the usual interpretation of the Lerner index remains valid in a setting where firms do not pursue profit maximization, but instead maximize revenues subject to a minimum-profit constraint. We show that a positive Lerner index still indicates market power, but that the magnitude of a positive Lerner index can no longer be used to determine how much market power there is. Furthermore, extra information would be required to draw conclusions about the presence or absence of market power when the Lerner index is zero or negative. We discuss the empirical implications of our results.

JEL CLASSIFICATION:

I. Introduction

Because the degree of competition among the firms in a sector or industry has important welfare implications for both consumers and firms (e.g. Bikker Citation2004), the assessment of firms’ market power is the topic of many theoretical and empirical studies in the economic literature.

Measures of market power often rely on the assumption of profit-maximizing behaviour (e.g. Hay and Liu Citation1997; Shaffer Citation2004; Boone Citation2008; Bikker, Shaffer, and Spierdijk Citation2012). However, Baumol (Citation1958) already argued that firms in oligopolistic markets are more likely to maximize revenues subject to a minimum-profit constraint rather than to pursue profit maximization; a theory for which the early literature found some empirical evidence (e.g. Amihud and Kamin Citation1979; Winn and Shoenhair Citation1988). More recently, Segerson and Squires (Citation1995) argued that the appropriate short-run behavioural assumption for a multi-product firm is revenue maximization. Other alternative pricing strategies that have been considered in the literature are limit pricing (Milgrom and Roberts Citation1982) and constant mark-up pricing (Rosse and Panzar Citation1977).

A widely used measure of market power is the Lerner index, whose theoretical and historical foundation has been extensively discussed in the literature (e.g. Landes and Posner Citation1981; Elzinga and Mills Citation2011; Giocoli Citation2012). The Lerner index compares a firm’s output price with its associated marginal costs, where marginal cost pricing is referred to as the ‘social optimum that is reached in perfect competition’ (Lerner Citation1934, 168). The standard interpretation of the Lerner index is that a zero value reflects competitive behaviour, while a positive value is associated with market power. However, this interpretation is directly derived from profit-maximizing behaviour, as we will see later.

This leads to the fundamental question to what extent the usual interpretation of the Lerner index remains valid in a setting where firms do not pursue profit maximization. As argued by Cairns (1995), a measure of market power ‘[…] should be able to provide a meaningful summary measure of monopoly power in any situation, not just that in which the firm is maximizing profits somehow defined.’ If the common interpretation is no longer valid in the absence of profit-maximizing behaviour, this will have stark implications for empirical studies using the Lerner index. Such studies do not test whether firms actually pursue profit maximization, but rely on the standard interpretation of the Lerner index anyhow (e.g. Ferna´Ndez De Guevara and Maudos Citation2004; Koetter, Kolari, and Spierdijk Citation2012).

The goal of this study is to investigate whether the interpretation of the Lerner index as a measure of market power is robust to deviations from the profit-maximization paradigm. We focus on revenue maximization as alternative pricing strategy because of two reasons. First, its empirical relevance has already been pointed out by, e.g., Segerson and Squires (Citation1995). Second, revenue maximization subject to a minimum-profit constraint encompasses several limiting cases, including sales maximization subject to a break-even constraint, and even profit maximization. This makes it a convenient and fairly general framework to analyse.

Our main results are as follows. When firms maximize revenues subject to a minimum-profit constraint, we can safely conclude that they possess market power when the Lerner index is significantly positive. However, we can no longer use the magnitude of the Lerner index to determine how much market power they have. Furthermore, additional information would be required to draw conclusions about the presence or absence of market power when the Lerner index is zero or negative. In particular, without such information, we can no longer conclude that a zero Lerner index implies the absence of market power. We show that statistical tests for profit maximization (Varian Citation1984; Love and Shumway Citation1994) can contribute to a correct interpretation of the Lerner index.

II. The Lerner index under profit maximization

We consider a profit-maximizing firm with a single-output production technology. Let denote the inverse demand function satisfying for . Furthermore, let denote total production costs as a function of output, with corresponding marginal cost function for . The Lerner index is defined as a firm’s relative mark-up of the output price over marginal cost, given the firm’s output level :

(1)

Under profit maximization, . Here is the profit-maximizing output quantity and the firm’s inverse price elasticity of demand evaluated in (Lerner Citation1934, 169). We have , while for any . Under profit maximization we can thus distinguish competitive () from uncompetitive () behaviour on the basis of the sign of the Lerner index. Furthermore, the value of the Lerner index is monotonically associated to market power.

Lerner (Citation1934, 170) suggested that the relative difference between the observed price and marginal cost can always be used to assess a firm’s market power, even in the absence of profit maximization. This suggestion has been adopted by the empirical literature in many fields of study, where the Lerner index is widely viewed as a standard tool to assess a firm’s market power regardless of the firm’s objective function.

However, the equality in does no longer hold in the absence of profit maximization. Consequently, in such a scenario, the Lerner index may become zero or even negative in the presence of market power. We will investigate the implications for the interpretation of the Lerner index in the next section.

III. The Lerner index under revenue maximization

We assume that a firm maximizes revenues subject to a minimum-profit constraint (Baumol Citation1958; Kafoglis and Bushnell Citation1970). This section characterizes the optimal output of a revenue maximizing firm and considers the measurement of market power by means of the Lerner index.

Characterization of optimal output

We assume that the following conditions hold, for :

Assumption 1

(i) .

(ii) for .

(iii) for .

(iv) The profit function is concave with the unique profit-maximizing output level and maximum profit level .

For a given minimum-profit level , the firm’s optimization problems equals

(2)
(3)

We notice that corresponds to revenue maximization subject to a break-even constraint and to profit maximization.

The necessary conditions for an optimal solution are summarized below, which is an extension of Kafoglis and Bushnell (Citation1970) because it includes the cases that and .

Result 1 Under Assumptions 1 (i) – (v), if there is a solution to the firm’s optimization problem, it must satisfy and the following first-order condition:

(4)

for the Kuhn–Tucker multiplier .

Proof: The Kuhn–Tucker conditions for the firm’s optimal output are

(5)
(6)
(7)
(8)
(9)

Because , we must have . We can rewrite Condition (5) as

(10)

Case 1: If , Equation (10) implies that . To show that is possible, assume that and . To prove that is a solution such that , we have to verify feasibility and optimality. Evidently, . Furthermore, Equation (10) is satisfied for and because under profit maximization. It is straightforward to verify that also competitive behaviour (, ) yields a solution with . Case 2: If , then we must have because of Equation (10) and . With , Condition (7) implies that the minimum-profit constraint is not binding. Because and , this case thus excludes profit maximization and competitive behaviour for which . □

An implication of Result 1 is that and for .

The Lerner index and market power

Given the optimal output level under revenue-maximizing behaviour subject to a minimum-profit level, we can rewrite the associated Lerner index on the basis of Equation (10) as

(11)

It is readily seen that , with strict inequality for . We thus observe that under competitive conditions (). More specifically, we find for and , while for and . Both and can arise under uncompetitive conditions. Using a similar continuity argument as Bikker, Shaffer, and Spierdijk (Citation2012), it follows that is also possible under uncompetitive conditions. The online appendix with supplementary material provides specific examples to illustrate that , and are indeed possible under uncompetitive conditions, and that under competitive conditions.

Empirical implications

The main implication of our results is that, under revenue maximization subject to a minimum-profit constraint, we can only use the Lerner index as a one-sided test for market power in the following sense. Given an empirical estimate of L (denoted ), we distinguish two cases. If statistical tests show that is significantly positive, we conclude that there is market power. However, we can no longer use the magnitude of a positive Lerner index to determine how much market power there is. This happens because the Lerner index’ competitive benchmark value is no longer 0 (instead, non-positive values may arise in competitive cases). If is not significantly different from 0 or significantly negative, we can draw no conclusions about the degree of market power since can occur under both competitive and uncompetitive conditions. Additional information would be required in this case. In both cases, statistical tests for profit maximization (Varian Citation1984; Love and Shumway Citation1994) can contribute to a correct interpretation of the Lerner index; see .

Table 1. Conclusions on the basis of L and the outcome of a profit maximization test.

Supplemental material

Supplementay_file_for_1254333.pdf

Download PDF (32.9 KB)

Acknowledgment

Laura Spierdijk gratefully acknowledges financial support by a Vidi grant (452.11.007) in the Vernieuwingsimpuls-program of the Netherlands Organization for Scientific Research.

Disclosure statement

No potential conflict of interest was reported by the authors.

Supplemental material

The supplemental data for this article can be accessed here.

Additional information

Funding

Laura Spierdijk gratefully acknowledges financial support by the Vidi grant [452.11.007] in the Vernieuwingsimpuls-program of the Netherlands Organization for Scientific Research.

References

  • Amihud, Y., and J. Kamin. 1979. “Revenue Vs. Profit Maximization: Differences in Behavior by the Type of Control and by Market Power.” Southern Economic Journal 45: 838–846. doi:10.2307/1057481.
  • Baumol, W. 1958. “On the Theory of Oligopoly.” Economica 25: 187–198. doi:10.2307/2550723.
  • Bikker, J. 2004. Competition and Efficiency in a Unified European Banking Market. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar Publishing.
  • Bikker, J., S. Shaffer, and L. Spierdijk. 2012. “Assessing Competition with the Panzar-Rosse Model: The Role of Scale, Costs, and Equilibrium. Review of Economics and Statistics 94: 1025–1044.
  • Boone, J. 2008. “A New Way to Measure Competition.” Economic Journal 118: 1245–1261.
  • Cairns, R. 1995. “Reflections on Lerner’s Index of Monopoly Power.” Review of Industrial Orga- Nization 10: 83–96. doi:10.1007/BF01024261.
  • Elzinga, K., and D. Mills. 2011. “The Lerner Index of Monopoly Power: Origins and Uses.” American Economic Review 101: 558–564. doi:10.1257/aer.101.3.558.
  • Ferna´Ndez de Guevara, J., and J. Maudos. 2004. “Measuring Welfare Loss of Market Power: An Ap- Plication to European Banks.” Applied Economics Letters 11: 833–836. doi:10.1080/1350485042000263908.
  • Giocoli, N. 2012. “Who Invented the Lerner Index? Luigi Amoroso, the Dominant Firm Model, and the Measurement of Market Power.” Review of Industrial Organization 41: 181–191. doi:10.1007/s11151-012-9355-7.
  • Hay, D., and G. Liu. 1997. “The Efficiency of Firms: What Difference Does Competition Make?” Eco- Nomic Journal 107: 597–617.
  • Kafoglis, M., and R. Bushnell. 1970. “The Revenue Maximization Oligopoly Model: Comment.” Amer- Ican Economic Review 60: 427–428.
  • Koetter, M., J. Kolari, and L. Spierdijk. 2012. “Enjoying the Quiet Life under Deregulation? Evidence from Adjusted Lerner Indices for US Banks.” Review of Economics and Statistics 94: 462–480. doi:10.1162/REST_a_00155.
  • Landes, W., and R. Posner. 1981. “Market Power in Antitrust Cases.” Harvard Law Review 94: 937–996. doi:10.2307/1340687.
  • Lerner, A. 1934. “The Concept of Monopoly and the Measurement of Monopoly Power.” The Review of Economic Studies 1: 157–175. doi:10.2307/2967480.
  • Love, H., and C. Shumway. 1994. “Nonparametric Tests for Monopsonistic Market Power Exertion.” American Journal of Agricultural Economics 76: 1156–1162. doi:10.2307/1243409.
  • Milgrom, P., and J. Roberts. 1982. “Limit Pricing and Entry under Incomplete Information: An Equi- Librium Analysis.” Econometrica 50: 443–459. doi:10.2307/1912637.
  • Rosse, J., and J. Panzar. 1977. Chamberlin Vs. Robinson: An Empirical Test for Monopoly Rents. Stanford, CA: Stanford University Studies in Industry Economics 77.
  • Segerson, K., and D. Squires. 1995. “Measurement of Capacity Utilization for Revenue-Maximizing Firms.” Bulletin of Economic Research 47: 77–84. doi:10.1111/boer.1995.47.issue-1.
  • Shaffer, S. 2004. “Patterns of Competition in Banking.” Journal of Economics and Business 56: 287–313. doi:10.1016/j.jeconbus.2003.10.003.
  • Varian, H. 1984. “The Nonparametric Approach to Production Analysis.” Econometrica 52: 579–597. doi:10.2307/1913466.
  • Winn, D., and J. Shoenhair. 1988. “Compensation-Based (Dis)Incentives for Revenue-Maximizing Behavior: A Test of the “Revised” Baumol Hypothesis.” The Review of Economics and Statistics 70: 154–158. doi:10.2307/1928164.