182
Views
1
CrossRef citations to date
0
Altmetric
Symposium: Sustainable Development and Financial Markets

Farmers’ Social Networks and the Fluctuation in Their Participation in Crop Insurance: The Perspective of Information Diffusion

, , &
 

ABSTRACT

By investigating the diffusion of information among social networks, and by presenting an analysis of apple growers in terms of the mechanism that underlies insurance decision-making, this paper first examined the relationship between information diffusion in social networks and the volatility that is observed in the crop insurance purchasing rate in China. In accordance with the mean-field theory of social networks, a mathematical model of infectious disease dynamics was employed to construct an insurance purchasing model, and the convergence value of the crop insurance purchasing rate was derived. Second, this paper analyzed research data related to apple insurance, and verified some of the properties related to purchasing rate fluctuations. The results show that the purchasing rate of crop insurance has a unique convergence point. The greater the average degree among the social network, the quicker the crop insurance purchasing rate reached the convergence point, and the lower its volatility.

Acknowledgments

We thank International Science Editing (www.internationalscienceediting.com) for editing this manuscript. The authors accept all errors.

A-1: Proof of Theorem 1

Because σ1, hence 11σ0 and i(t)(11σ)0. Since δ>0,i(t)>0, we obtain di(t)dt0, the application ratio is a decreasing function, until i()=0

A-2: Proof of Theorem 2

Consider the following differential function assuming the initial condition, we assume δ,μ is constant for convenient.

di(t)dt=δi(t)[i(t)(11σ)],i(t0)=i0

Since 0<δ<1,0<i(t)<1, we obtain:

A{\hbox{-}1 δi(t)[i(t)(11σ)],i(t)>(11σ)δi(t)[i(t)(11σ)],i(t)<(11σ)A{\hbox{-}1

So, when the initial value i(t)>(11σ),i(t) is continuous and decreasing; whereas when i(t)<(11σ),i(t) is continuous and increasing. Hence, whatever the value of i0, the unique asymptotical convergence i exists, and i=11σ.

A-3: Proof of Corollary 1

Consider a scenario where time is discrete. The equation then changes as follows:

(A{\hbox{-}2) N[i(t+1)i(t)]=δNs(t)i(t)μNi(t)s(t)+i(t)=1i(0)=i0>0(A{\hbox{-}2)

We then obtain i(t+1)=i(t)δi(t)[i(t)(11σ)] .

Let i0(0,1],Δt>0, set ix=i(xΔt),

Note

ρ(ix,iy)=ixiy=i0δi0xΔti011σ i0δi0yΔti011σ=(xy)δi0Δti011σ

Since 0<δi0<1,0<Δt<1, when σ>1,0<i0(11σ)<1, so 0<δi0Δti011σ<1.

Let α=δi0Δti011σ(0,1). Thus we have ρ(ix,iy)<αρ(x,y) pix,iyαρx,y.

Then ix:RR is contraction map.

For any x0:

ρ(ix0n+p,ix0n)αnρ(ix0p,x0)αn(αn1+αn2++1)ρ(ix0,x0)αn1αρ(ix0,x0)

since 0<α<1,{ixn} is a Cauchy sequence.

And, as R is complete, from the nature of the contraction map, we obtain the unique-fixed point 11σ.

A-4: Proof of Corollary 3

Consider the scenario of equilibrium ik(t): under the extreme value, we have dik(t)dt=δk(t)ik(t)(1ik(t))μik(t)=0

δk(t)=υ+ik(t)1ik(t)θecηtq

We obtain the following:

[υ+ik(t)1ik(t)θecηtq]ik(t)(1ik(t))μik(t)=0

After rearranging, we obtain the following:

(A{\hbox{-}3) ik(t)=υμυθecηtq=υμυθecηt1kkkp(k)ik(t)(A{\hbox{-}3)

since q=1kkkp(k)ik(t).

Completing the square of both sides of the above equation, and by calculating the sum of all of k, we obtain the following:

q=1kkkp(k)ik(t)=1kkkp(k)υμυθecηtq=υμυθecηtq1kkkp(k)

Because 1kkkp(k)=1, we haveq=υμυθecηtq.

After rearranging, we obtain the following equation:

F(t,q)=(q)2θecηt+(1q)υμ=0, and θ,c,η,υ,μ are all constant.

From the function, we can obtain the following:

  • (i) F(t,q) is continuous to t andqin the domain of definition;

  • (ii) When q=1,t0=clnμθη and F(t,q)=0;

  • (iii) F(t,q)=(q)2θηecηt, the partial derivative of F(t,q), to tin the domain of definition; and

  • (iv) Ft(t0,q0)=F1,clnμθη=θηecηclnμθη=ημ0.

From the theorem of implicit function, the unique implicit function t=f(q) exists, and we have the following:

f(q)=Fq(t0,q0)Ft(t0,q0)

And because

A{\hbox{-}5 Ft(t,q)=(q)2θηecηtFq(t,q)=2qθηecηtυA{\hbox{-}5

hence .

f(q)=Fq(t0,q0)Ft(t0,q0)=2qθηecηtυ(q)2θηecηt

From f(q)=0, we can obtain the following:

2qθηecηtυ=0

We can input this into the following:

q=1kkkp(k)ik(t)

We can obtain the following:

(A{\hbox{-}6) t=clnυ2qθη=clnkυ2θkkp(k)ik(t)η(A{\hbox{-}6)

Hence, when k>k, we have t<t.

Notes

1. The elaboration likelihood model was proposed by psychologists Richard E. Petty and John T. Cacioppo. It is the most influential theoretical model about consumer information-processing behavior. Consumers can take the information provided by advertisements seriously when forming their attitude toward advertising brands. They will search, analyze, and use the information related to advertised products carefully, which ultimately leads to the formation or transformation of their attitudes.

Additional information

Funding

This work was supported by the National Natural Science Foundation of China [71403215, 71503203, 71603190, 71673206, 71873103]; The Fundamental Research Funds for the Central Universities [No. 2015RWYB07].

Reprints and Corporate Permissions

Please note: Selecting permissions does not provide access to the full text of the article, please see our help page How do I view content?

To request a reprint or corporate permissions for this article, please click on the relevant link below:

Academic Permissions

Please note: Selecting permissions does not provide access to the full text of the article, please see our help page How do I view content?

Obtain permissions instantly via Rightslink by clicking on the button below:

If you are unable to obtain permissions via Rightslink, please complete and submit this Permissions form. For more information, please visit our Permissions help page.