3,381
Views
2
CrossRef citations to date
0
Altmetric
Articles

What motives shape the initial accounting for goodwill under IFRS 3 in a setting dominated by controlling owners?

ORCID Icon &

Abstract

We investigate how different motives shape the initial accounting for goodwill in a setting dominated by controlling owners, using data from 1112 acquisition analyses reported by Swedish listed acquiring firms. In contrast to prior studies, we find no evidence that earnings-based compensation affects the proportion of the purchased price accounted for as goodwill. Instead, we find that when a family-owned firm is the acquirer, a larger proportion of the purchase price is accounted for as goodwill than as specific assets and liabilities. These two findings indicate that controlling owners may curb managerial motives, while controlling family owners apply the discretion of IFRS 3 according to their motives. We also find in this setting that acquisition-related motives have a significant impact on the proportion of the purchased price accounted for as goodwill. Overall, our analyses indicate that the motives shaping goodwill accounting choices depend on the institutional setting.

1. Introduction

The accounting for goodwill has attracted research interest because significant professional judgment is prevalent both at the initial and subsequent stages of determining its value. While there is a vivid ongoing debate about whether the subsequent accounting for goodwill (i.e. annual impairment tests) provides useful information in a European setting (e.g. Schatt et al., Citation2016), there has been much less focus on the initial accounting. Because the subsequent impairment tests can be endogenously determined by the initial accounting (Zhang & Zhang, Citation2017), it is also important to explore whether goodwill is affected by different motives at the time of the acquisition analysis. Previous studies have mainly explored how managerial motives, such as bonus incentives, influence the proportion of the purchase price initially accounted for as goodwill (Detzen & Zülch, Citation2012; Shalev et al., Citation2013). In this study, however, we intend to investigate motives that may shape the initial accounting for goodwill in a setting dominated by controlling owners, where managerial motives are arguably less influential. To do so, we make use of the disclosure requirements of the International Financial Reporting Standard (IFRS) 3 Business Combinations.Footnote1,Footnote2 After screening more than 2000 annual reports, our dataset contains 1112 acquisition analyses reported by 205 unique Swedish publicly listed firms from 2005 to 2013.

According to IFRS 3, goodwill can only arise after the acquirer has recognized the sum of the fair values of assets given, liabilities assumed and any non-controlling interest in the acquiree (IFRS 3.10). The process starts by classifying/designating the identifiable acquired assets and assumed liabilities (IFRS 3.15) to arrive at the fair value of net identifiable assets in the acquiree. The difference between the price paid and the acquirer’s ownership in the fair value of the acquiree’s net identifiable assets is reported as goodwill (IFRS 3.32). Although IFRS 3 provides guidance to the process of identifying and determining the fair value of acquired assets, significant professional judgment is still required. Goodwill and other acquired assets with an indefinite useful life should, according to the International Accounting Standard (IAS) 36, subsequently be tested for impairment, which also demands professional judgment. This has caused some researchers to voice concerns about the usefulness of goodwill, arguing that it may be tempting to make choices at the initial stage that resuts in goodwill balances that exceed the economic value (e.g. Detzen & Zülch, Citation2012; Li & Sloan, Citation2017; Ramanna & Watts, Citation2012). The reason why critics contend that goodwill is likely to exceed its economic value is because this, in combination with required subsequent professional judgments, enables the acquirer to manage future earnings upward (e.g. Detzen & Zülch, Citation2012). It is even suggested that the required professional judgments of the impairment-only approach to goodwill has led to overpayments for acquirees (e.g. Bartov et al., Citation2021).Footnote3

Research on the initial accounting for goodwill has mainly explored how managerial motives shape the outcome of the professional judgments. Shalev et al. (Citation2013) find that a larger proportion of the purchase price is accounted for as goodwill when CEOs of U.S. acquirers obtain considerable earnings-based compensation. Detzen and Zülch (Citation2012) find similar results for a sample of large publicly listed European firms. Thus, they argue that managers use the professional judgment given to them at the acquisition date, by reporting a larger proportion of the purchase price as goodwill, to increase future earnings and bonuses.

In this study, we explore several motives that may affect the proportion of the purchase price that is accounted for as goodwill. In particular, we conjecture that the importance of managerial motives identified in prior research (e.g. Detzen & Zülch, Citation2012; Shalev et al., Citation2013) is contextual and curbed by owners when they have sufficient power to do so. But as predicted by agency theory (e.g. Anderson & Reeb, Citation2003; Shleifer & Vishny, Citation1997), controlling owners may also have their own motives that shape the initial accounting for goodwill. For instance, a family owner with disproportionately low cash flow rights may participate in value-destructive acquisitions for control reasons (Claessens et al., Citation2000; Dyck & Zingales, Citation2004). While family owners may have a dampening effect on managerial actions, they may also be tempted to structure the outcome of the acquisition analysis to produce more opaque accounting and to manage future earnings by reporting goodwill that exceeds its economic value (cf. Bartov et al., Citation2021). Thus, we further the understanding of the initial accounting for goodwill in a setting where different types of owners typically have more power than managers. Family ownership is of particularly interest because it is the most common type worldwide (e.g. Aminadav & Papaioannou, Citation2020).

Our sample of 1112 acquisition analyses is larger than most previous studies of the initial accounting for goodwill, and it includes acquisitions of both public and private acquirees. We believe that our sample better resembles the typical setting in which IFRS 3 is applied as it also includes smaller acquirers and acquirees, which differs from prior research focus of only including large acquisitions. Further, the Swedish setting offers unique opportunities to explore how ownership affects the outcome of an acquisition analysis as the ownership structure varies considerably and is often distinctively different from an Anglo-Saxon setting.Footnote4 The use of control-enhancing mechanisms, such as dual classes of shares, is extensive in Sweden (Faccio & Lang, Citation2002; Institutional Shareholder Services, Citation2007) , which further enhances the influence of controlling owners. Swedish law also forbids dual responsibilities as CEO and chairman of the board (Aktiebolagslagen, Citation2005, p. 551, Ch.8, §49), and the Swedish Corporate Governance Code (SCGC) does not permit that more than one manager sits on the board (SCGC, Citation2016, Ch.4, §3). Thus, the CEOs in publicly listed Swedish firms will have a relatively weaker influence than that of the CEOs in large widely held Anglo-Saxon firms when making acquisitions and accounting for them.

The empirical analysis does not show that the acquirer reports a larger proportion of the purchase price as goodwill when the CEO obtains more earnings-based compensation. This implies that the documented importance of managerial motives is curbed in a setting where owners are in control of important firm decisions. Instead, we find that family-controlled firms report a larger proportion of the purchase price as goodwill. The agency conflict between owner and management is thus curbed, but the agency conflict between controlling and non-controlling owners appears more relevant in the Swedish setting. Regardless of whether this finding is due to a strategy of concealing ill-executed acquisitions by reporting it as goodwill (cf. Bartov et al., Citation2021), or a desire to control acquisition-related expenses for contracting reasons (Ramanna & Watts, Citation2012; Watts, Citation2003), it indicates that motives related to family ownership shape the initial accounting for goodwill. These results remain robust to a number of alternative variable definitions, subsamples and additional controls.

We also find that a number of additional motives shape the initial accounting for goodwill. Specifically, the proportion of the purchase price accounted for as goodwill increases when (i) the acquirer pays more than the industry-average for the book value of the target firm’s pre-acquisition net assets, and (ii) the uncertainty is more pronounced due to foreign acquirees. These findings could potentially be related to the difficulty of fully attributing the payment to specific assets when uncertainty prevails, but it could also be because goodwill is used to conceal overpayments (cf. Bartov et al., Citation2021; de Bodt et al., Citation2018). Moreover, we find that frequent acquirers have a dampening effect on the proportion of the purchase price accounted for as goodwill. This indicates that serial-acquirers may learn how to better attribute the purchase price to specific assets and liabilities, making goodwill potentially more reliable and useful to investors.

The study contributes to the accounting literature by showing that the institutional context is important to understand accounting choices, such as the initial accounting for goodwill. Researchers studying subsequent goodwill accounting decisions, such as impairments, should be aware of the varying motives that shape the initial accounting for goodwill. We also contribute to the literature on agency conflicts. In particular, we show that the discretion of fair-value measurements may not just reflect managers’ personal motives, but also owners' motives. In a broad sense, the case of goodwill accounting shows how fair-value estimates based on unobservable Level 3 inputs are affected by the institutional setting. Our study should be of interest for international standard setters as it provides evidence that family ownership plays a role in the initial accounting for goodwill. It is, therefore, wise for standard setters to improve their understanding of how owners' motives shape goodwill accounting choices given that goodwill is a very large item in many firms’ balance sheets, and because family ownership is large and frequent around the world. It is particularly important for standard setting in Europe because families own or control 70–80% of all European firms (Alderson, Citation2011).

The rest of the paper is organized as follows. We present prior research and our hypotheses in Section 2, describe our setting and empirical models in Section 3, present results and analyses in Section 4, and conclude in Section 5.

2. Literature Review and Hypotheses

2.1. The Accounting for Business Combinations Under IFRS 3

To internationally harmonize – and presumably improve – the accounting, the Financial Accounting Standards Board (FASB) and the International Accounting Standards Board (IASB) initiated a joint project on the accounting for business combinations. At that time, both standard-setting bodies allowed firms to use either the acquisition or the pooling method to account for a business combination. Only the acquisition method permitted goodwill, and goodwill was usually amortized over the asset’s useful life, which at the time was 20 years according to the IASB and 40 years according to the FASB. In their joint project, the IASB and the FASB decided that only the acquisition method should be permitted and that goodwill should only be subject to impairment tests. The FASB’s standards SFAS 141 (Business Combinations) and SFAS 142 (Goodwill and other intangible assets) was enacted in the United States as of 2001. The IASB introduced IFRS 3 in 2004, and as of January 2005, the European Union made it mandatory for all publicly listed firms of its member countries to comply with IFRS as issued by the IASB; and thereby, requiring the application of IFRS 3 for business combinations.

The accounting for business combinations has varied over time and between standard setting bodies (Ding et al., Citation2008). One of the most recently debated matters is whether goodwill is an asset, and what components it should consist of. In this respect, Johnson and Petrone (Citation1998) distinguishes between six possible components of goodwill: (1) the fair-value revaluation of the acquiree’s assets; (2) the fair value of identified assets not recognized by the acquiree prior to the acquisition; (3) the fair value of the ‘going concern element’ that comes from the synergies of combining the acquiree’s assets prior to the acquisition, which could be internally generated or acquired previously by the acquiree; (4) the synergies that come from combining the acquirer’s and the acquiree’s assets and businesses that would not be possible if the firms were stand-alone entities; (5) an overvaluation of the consideration paid, such as the acquirer’s own stock in an all-stock transaction; and (6) an overpayment for the acquiree. In line with Johnson and Petrone (Citation1998), the IASB and the FASB agreed that goodwill meets the definition of an asset as long as acquired assets and liabilities can be correctly identified and valued before recognizing goodwill , meaning that goodwill should mainly consist of Components 3 and 4 in the Johnson and Petrone (Citation1998) framework.

When a business combination is completed, an entity shall account for each business combination by applying the acquisition method (IFRS 3.4), in which the acquirer and acquisition date are determined. The standard mandates the acquirer to recognize the sum of the fair values of assets given, liabilities assumed and any non-controlling interest in the acquiree (IFRS 3.10). The acquirer shall also classify or designate the identifiable acquired assets and assumed liabilities (IFRS 3.15) to arrive at the fair value of net identifiable assets in the acquiree. Goodwill is a residual coming from the difference between the consideration transferred for the acquiree and the acquirer’s interest in the fair value of the net identifiable assets in the acquiree (IFRS 3.32). Because goodwill is a residual, it does not by itself produce a valuation problem, but at the time of the initial recognition, problems arise indirectly from the fair value assessment of specific acquired assets and liabilities (i.e. Components 1 and 2 in the Johnson and Petrone (Citation1998) framework). For the acquirer to determine the fair value of net identifiable assets, it is necessary to employ significant professional judgment in the recognition and measurement process.

In the accounting literature, there is substantial skepticism towards the adoption of the impairment-only approach to goodwill and other assets with an indefinite useful life (e.g. Li & Sloan, Citation2017; Ramanna & Watts, Citation2012; Watts, Citation2003; Zhang & Zhang, Citation2017). The main argument for such skepticism is that managers will let their professional judgments at the acquisition date be affected by personal motives; and as a consequence, they may compromise future economic impairments. Such a behavior would be consistent with including the first two components of the Johnson and Petrone (Citation1998) framework to goodwill. For example, Shalev et al. (Citation2013) argue that managers with earnings-based compensation align their professional judgment with their personal motives to maximize future earnings and bonuses. There are also concerns that the combination of professional judgment in the process of initially determining goodwill and the subsequent impairment-only tests can lead to overpayments for an acquiree. Bartov et al. (Citation2021) find that goodwill under the impairment-only approach likely is used to conceal overpayments. Thus, goodwill may, according to critics, also contain component 6 in the Johnson and Petrone (Citation1998) framework.

Empirical accounting research also suggests that goodwill to a large extent reflect the motives of the acquirer, rather than the underlying economics (e.g. Beatty & Weber, Citation2006; Detzen & Zülch, Citation2012; Hamberg & Beisland, Citation2014; Li & Sloan, Citation2017; Ramanna & Watts, Citation2012; Shalev et al., Citation2013; Yehuda et al., Citation2019). For example, Ramanna and Watts (Citation2012) document that acquirers that capitalize proportionately more goodwill report higher post-acquisition earnings, and that the likelihood of reporting goodwill impairment decreases with accounting discretion. The consequences are inflated goodwill balances, untimely impairments and investors who do not seem to fully anticipate the untimely nature of goodwill impairments (Li & Sloan, Citation2017). While most research has been conducted on SFAS 141 and the U.S. institutional context, there is evidence of substantial problems also with IFRS 3 (Bugeja & Loyeung, Citation2015; Detzen & Zülch, Citation2012; Hamberg & Beisland, Citation2014). In a comparative study of the two settings, André et al. (Citation2016) find that problems are, at least, as severe under IFRS 3 as under SFAS 141.

2.2. Motives Shaping the Initial Accounting for Goodwill

As discussed in the previous section, the accounting for business combinations requires significant professional judgment, which often leads to subjective accounting choices. Research shows that in settings where most acquiring firms are widely held without a controlling owner, managers often report a large proportion of the purchase price as goodwill if they can benefit from it. For example, Shalev et al. (Citation2013) find, using a sample of 320 U.S. acquisitions, that the proportion of the purchase price reported as goodwill increases when managers of acquiring firms receive substantial earnings-based compensation. In a study of 123 large European acquisitions, Detzen and Zülch (Citation2012) find a similar positive relation between earnings-based compensation and the proportion of the purchase price reported as goodwill.

Prior to the impairment-only approach, goodwill was also subject to impairment tests, but only as a complement to annual amortizations. Studies comparing the initial accounting for goodwill in the periods before and after the implementation of the impairment-only approach, find that managerial motives only play a significant role in the latter period. Zhang and Zhang (Citation2017) show that the association between earnings-based compensation and a large proportion of the purchase price accounted for as goodwill is, in the U.S. setting, only prevalent under the impairment-only approach. Similarly, Bugeja and Loyeung (Citation2015) show that the proportion of the purchase price accounted for as goodwill increased when Australian firms transitioned to the impairment-only approach under IFRS 3 and IAS 36.

Most prior studies have been conducted in Anglo-Saxon institutional settings. Thus, we expect that the institutional context may explain the established association between earnings-based compensation and the proportion of the purchase price reported as goodwill. We stress two important differences between the previously studied Anglo-Saxon context and our Swedish context. First, the average firm in the Anglo-Saxon institutional context tends to have a much more dispersed ownership. Aminadav and Papaioannou (Citation2020) document that the largest owner in an average U.S. firm holds 13.0% of the voting rights, and in the UK, it is 17.3%, which can be compared to a world average of 31.5%. In Sweden, the average largest owner possesses 31.9% of the voting rights (Aminadav & Papaioannou, Citation2020). Second, ownership is also considerably more dispersed in large firms, and previous research (Detzen & Zülch, Citation2012; Shalev et al., Citation2013; Zhang & Zhang, Citation2017) has only targeted large acquirers' acquisitions of other large publicly listed firms.

Another reason for expecting that the association between earnings-based compensation and the proportion of the purchase price reported as goodwill is contextual, is the relative power of management. In the U.S., managers often occupy a number of seats on the board of directors. Adams et al. (Citation2010) survey several studies and report that almost half of the board members consist of managers or affiliated directors. In addition, there is often a CEO and chairman duality role in the U.S. For instance, Adams et al. (Citation2010) suggest that 80% of the CEOs also act as the chairman. In a more recent study, Tinaikar (Citation2017) reports that 68% of the CEOs in his sample of large U.S. firms are also the chairman. This puts a CEO in a relatively more powerful position and likely increases the agency conflict between owners and management (Jensen & Meckling, Citation1976). In other settings, managers are less powerful. For instance, Swedish law prohibits the CEO to also be the chairman.

Thus, the documented association between managerial motives and the initial accounting for goodwill could be an effect of studying an institutional setting in which CEOs are relatively more powerful (c.f. Detzen & Zülch, Citation2012; Shalev et al., Citation2013; Zhang & Zhang, Citation2017). Earnings-based compensation is a strong personal motive for a CEO in any institutional setting, but the association between earnings-based compensation and the proportion of the purchase price allocated to goodwill is perhaps not significant in settings where most firms have controlling owners and the CEO cannot be the chairman of the board. While it is an empirical question whether the CEO’s earnings-based compensation will shape the initial accounting for goodwill in such a setting, we conjecture that CEO motives in general are curbed when firms are less widely held and controlling ownership is common. In other words, we expect in contrast to findings from previous research that earnings-based compensation will not have an effect on the initial accounting for goodwill when managers are relatively less powerful. For this reason, we formulate the following first hypothesis:

H1: The proportion of the purchase price accounted for as goodwill is not associated with the CEO’s level of earnings-based compensation in a setting dominated by controlling owners.

As discussed, ownership worldwide is more concentrated than in the typical Anglo-Saxon setting (Aminadav & Papaioannou, Citation2020). But another distinct difference between the Anglo-Saxon setting and other settings is the extent to which publicly listed firms are owned and controlled by a family.1 It is widely known that families constitute the most common owner type among publicly listed firms worldwide (Alderson, Citation2011; Claessens et al., Citation2000; Dyck & Zingales, Citation2004; Faccio & Lang, Citation2002; La Porta et al., Citation1999). However, family ownership of publicly listed firms is less pronounced in the U.S. and the UK relative to Continental Europe (e.g. Alderson, Citation2011; Faccio & Lang, Citation2002). For instance, La Porta et al. (Citation1999) show that only 20% of large U.S. firms were family-controlled, which can be compared to about 45% in the Swedish setting.

It is often claimed that family owners want to not only maximize shareholder value, but also make decisions that maintains family control over the business (e.g. Bertrand & Schoar, Citation2006). There is an ongoing and unresolved debate as to whether family ownership benefits corporate performance. On the one hand, a family owner often knows the organization better and is better able to supervise and motivate employees (Bertrand & Schoar, Citation2006). These advantages also give the family owner outstanding monitoring abilities (Demsetz & Lehn, Citation1985). But on the other hand, the family owner is sub-optimally diversified and desires less firm-specific risk. As a consequence, family firms often reduce its operating risks, avoid destabilizing acquisitions and prefer equity-financing of projects (e.g. Miller et al., Citation2009; Miller & LeBreton-Miller, Citation2005). While some have claimed that controlling family owners destroy shareholder value (Cronqvist & Nilsson, Citation2003; Goa & Kling, Citation2008), most research seems to agree that the benefits of family ownership exceed the drawbacks (e.g. Anderson & Reeb, Citation2003; Barontini & Caprio, Citation2006; Faccio & Lang, Citation2002; Maury, Citation2006; Villalonga & Amit, Citation2006). However, research also shows that that family owners may influence the firm’s acquisition policy in order for them to indirectly diversify their private portfolio (e.g. Miller et al., Citation2010). Moreover, it has been found that family firms may under such conditions destroy value when undertaking acquisitions (Bauguess & Stegemoller, Citation2008).

It is likely that the financial reporting of a family-controlled firm will have several distinct features. Vural (Citation2018) investigates disclosure practices in Swedish firms’ annual reports using a disclosure index. She documents that family firms disclose less information than non-family firms. This finding is , in large, supported by studies from other settings (e.g. Ali et al., Citation2007; Chen et al., Citation2008; Yang, Citation2010). There are two reasons as to why family firms can be expected to disclose less information. First, the family owner has access to other information channels; and given that accounting information is costly, it appears unnecessary to produce more information than the minimum requirements. Second, better disclosure practices will reduce the controlling owner’s information advantage and allow non-controlling owners to better monitor the firm’s practices. When the controlling owner is a family that wants to maintain corporate control, fully transparent disclosures may shed a light on the decisions that the family owner wishes not to reveal. This could, for example, be because the family owner wants to conceal that the firm’s investment policy, through acquisitions, in reality is motivated by a need for diversification in the family's private portfolio, and not optimal investments (c.f. Bauguess & Stegemoller, Citation2008).

When it comes to corporate acquisitions, family-controlled firms are not only likely to make fewer acquisitions, but also to make accounting choices that reveal less detailed acquisition information. A such opaque reporting practice will reduce the probability of being criticized by external stakeholders, including non-controlling owners. Because the controlling family owner perceives no significant information gain from identifying specific assets and liabilities in a detailed acquisition analysis (rather the opposite), the firm is more likely to increase the proportion of the purchase price accounted for as goodwill. By reporting a larger proportion of the purchase price as goodwill, the family owner also obtains better control over future earnings. In sum, goodwill can due to family ownership contain components 1 and 2 as well as 6 in the Johnson and Petrone (Citation1998) framework. For these reasons, we formulate the following second hypothesis:

H2: The proportion of the purchase price accounted for as goodwill increases with family ownership.

While personal and governance motives are likely to be important (Bugeja & Loyeung, Citation2015; Detzen & Zülch, Citation2012; Shalev et al., Citation2013; Zhang & Zhang, Citation2017), other factors may also affect the proportion of the purchase price reported as goodwill. Acquisitions tend to create value for society as they help restructure industries and improve efficiency, but they are value-destroying for the owners if the acquirer overpays (Malmendier & Tate, Citation2008). As argued and shown by Bartov et al. (Citation2021), managers may attempt to conceal overpayments by reporting more goodwill; and consequently, the goodwill balance then consists of component 6 in the Johnson and Petrone (Citation1998) framework. Overpayment is not (necessarily) a conscious act: In the corporate finance literature, hubris is a well-known motivation for corporate acquisitions (Roll, Citation1986), and it suggests that acquirers are overconfident in their ability to create shareholder value from an acquisition. In particular, such overconfidence may arise in firms with outstanding track records (Billett & Qian, Citation2008; Doukas & Petmezas, Citation2007). Along these lines, Bartov et al. (Citation2021) find that overbidding is more prevalent after the adoption of SFAS 142, arguing that the impairment-only approach enables acquirers to conceal any overpayment by reporting it as goodwill. The consequence of an overpayment is that it is difficult to recognize it as a specific asset and the acquirer will, intentionally or unintentionally, report goodwill that does not reflect its underlying economic value. Along these lines, we formulate the following third hypothesis:

H3: The proportion of the purchase price accounted for as goodwill increases with payments that are significantly higher relative to other similar acquisitions.

Some firms grow rapidly through corporate acquisitions and these firms are likely to accumulate valuable experiences on how to successfully make value-creating acquisitions and how to account for acquired resources. We expect acquisition experience – in the form of acquisition frequency – to benefit the professional judgment of the acquirer and to reduce the proportion of the purchase price reported as goodwill. Research suggests that acquisition experience has a positive impact on acquisition performance. For example, experienced acquirers can become better at estimating potential synergies (Haleblian & Finkelstein, Citation1999; McDonald et al., Citation2008). In a similar fashion, accounting skills are likely to develop gradually over time. Any allocation of the purchase price to specific assets comes from an understanding of how to attribute the value of future operations to specific assets of the acquiree. Managers with more acquisition experience may possess better knowledge of how to use their professional judgment to attribute acquired resources to correct assets. Thus, the difference between the purchase price and the fair value net assets will, ceteris paribus, better reflect acquired synergies of components 3 and 4 in the Johnson and Petrone (Citation1998) framework. Based on these two strands of arguments we formulate the following fourth hypothesis:

H4: The proportion of the purchase price accounted for as goodwill decreases with acquirer’s past acquisition experience.

Acquisitions are uncertain as information is asymmetrically distributed between the potential acquirer and the owners of the potential acquiree. The level of uncertainty is affected by many factors, including knowledge of the acquiree’s valuable resources, its markets and its accounting practices. For example, McNichols and Stubben (Citation2015) find that the quality of the acquiree’s accounting information reduces acquisition uncertainty and the risk for the acquirer to overpay. It also seems as if acquirers benefit from reduced information uncertainty by sharing auditors with the acquiree (Cai et al., Citation2016; Dhaliwal et al., Citation2016). These findings suggest that acquisitions with more uncertainty are more likely to be associated with overpayments, making goodwill more likely to stem from both Component 6 as well as Components 1 and 2 in the Johnson and Petrone (Citation1998) framework. Based on these arguments, we formulate the following fifth hypothesis:

H5: The proportion of the purchase price accounted for as goodwill increases with acquisition uncertainty.

3. Research Method

3.1. The Swedish Institutional Setting

Before listed firms in Sweden were mandated to comply with IFRS, the Swedish accounting standard RR 1:00 required them to use the purchase method and a two-component approach with annual amortizations over a maximum period of twenty years; and if necessary, impairments. Most firms were much more conservative and in 2004 the median Swedish listed firm amortized goodwill over a period of seven years (Hamberg et al., Citation2011). The Stockholm Stock Exchange is a well-functioning liquid equity market with a total of 375 listed firms during the studied period of 2005–2013. Swedish publicly listed firms are known, in general, to provide high-quality accounting numbers (e.g. Leuz et al., Citation2003) and informative financial reports (La Porta et al., Citation1999).

The ownership structure among Swedish listed firms is relatively concentrated, and family ownership is common. Aminadav and Papaioannou (Citation2020) suggest that the average largest owner in a Swedish listed firm holds about 31.9% of the voting rights, which is close to the world average of 31.5%. Families control about 45% of the Swedish listed firms, which is higher than the world average of 30% (Barontini & Caprio, Citation2006; La Porta et al., Citation1999; Maury, Citation2006). Sweden also has among the highest ownership concentration and separation of control and cashflow rights in the corporate world (Faccio & Lang, Citation2002; Institutional Shareholder Services, Citation2007). La Porta et al. (Citation1999) report that Swedish firms to have the highest frequencies in terms of dual share classes and pyramid ownership structures.

Swedish law prohibits the CEO from taking on dual responsibilities as the chairman of the board (Aktiebolagslagen, Citation2005, p. 551, Ch.8, §49). It also requires at least three board members (Aktiebolagslagen, Citation2005, p. 551, Ch.8, §46) and because the Swedish Corporate Governance Code (SCGC) recommends no more than one manager on the board (SCGC, Citation2016, Ch.4, §3), managers should typically not be able to dominate the board of directors. However, the SCGC does not block the control of the main owner as it only requires two board members to be independent from controlling owners, regardless of the size of the board (SCGC, Citation2016, Ch.4, §5). Thus, CEOs are, together with other managers, effectively hindered by the combination of the law and the code, as well as large controlling owners, to dominate the board of directors. The composition of the CEOs’ compensation packages in Sweden also stands out compared to Anglo-Saxon settings. Fernandes et al. (Citation2013) study cross-country differences in executive compensation and find that for the average Swedish CEO, equity-based pay and bonuses are less than 20% of the total compensation. This can be compared with American CEOs who earn substantially more and the variable components account for more than 60% of the total compensation (Fernandes et al., Citation2013). In other words, Swedish CEOs are much less powerful compared to U.S. CEOs, and their earnings-based compensation motive to report a larger proportion of the purchase price as goodwill should therefore be dampened.

3.2. Research Model and Empirical Measures

To test the hypotheses, we employ the following pooled OLS regression as Model 1, using acquisition analysis-level data: (1) GOODWILLi=α0+α1BONUSi+α2FAMILYi+α3EXCESS_PRICEi+α4EXPERIENCEi+α5UNCERTAINTYi+α6CFRIGHT+α7DUAL_SHARES+α8OPTIONSi+α9TOTAL_PAYi+α10NONCASHi+α11ACTIVITYi+α12PAST_GWi+α13ROAi+α14DEBTi+α15LIQUIDITYi+α16TRGT_INTANGIBLEi+α17TRGT_DEBTi+α18TRGT_SIZEi+e(1) The dependent variable GOODWILL is defined as the reported goodwill at the acquisition date divided by the total purchase price.Footnote5 Because other acquired intangible assets than goodwill are also only subject to yearly impairment tests, we use the alternative dependent variable INTANGIBLES, which includes reported goodwill and all revaluations of intangible assets, to test the robustness of Model 1.

According to hypothesis H1, we expect the proportion of the purchase price accounted for as goodwill to not be related to the CEO’s earnings-based compensation (BONUS) in a setting dominated by controlling owners. We define BONUS as the ratio of variable to fixed compensation for the CEO as disclosed in the annual report for the end of the acquisition year. In the regression model, we expect α1 not to be statistically significant. To control for inter-firm compensation differences, we include total CEO compensation (TOTAL_PAY). According to hypothesis H2, we expect the proportion of the purchase price accounted for as goodwill to increase with family ownership (FAMILY). We measure FAMILY using a dummy variable that takes the value of 1 when the largest ultimate owner at the time of the acquisition is a family (or individual private person) that controls at least 10% of the voting rights.Footnote6 The family owner can be a Swedish or non-Swedish citizen. In the regression model, we expect α2 to be positive and statistically significant.

According to hypothesis H3, we expect the proportion of the purchase price accounted for as goodwill to increase with the level of excess purchase price (EXCESS_PRICE). We primarily measure EXCESS_PRICE with a dummy taking the value of 1 when the ratio between the purchase price and the acquiree’s book value of equity as a stand-alone entity (before any fair-value reassessment) is higher than the average for the acquirer’s industry at the year of the acquisition. Alternatively, we measure excess price (EXCESS_PRICE_2) simply as the natural logarithm of the difference between the purchase price and the acquiree’s book value of equity as a stand-alone entity, before any fair-value reassessment. We expect α3 to be positive and statistically significant. According to hypothesis H4, we expect the proportion of the purchase price accounted for as goodwill to decrease with acquisition experience (EXPERIENCE). We measure EXPERIENCE with a dummy taking the value of 1 when the acquirer made more acquisitions than the average of its industry peers and year. In the regression model, we expect α4 to be negative and statistically significant.

According to hypothesis H5, we expect the proportion of the purchase price accounted for as goodwill to increase with acquisition uncertainty (UNCERTAINTY). We expect more uncertainty for an acquisition of a foreign firm as cultures, markets and even accounting measures are relatively less known to the acquirer. Thus, UNCERTAINTY is a dummy taking the value of 1 when the acquiree is not domiciled in Sweden. In the regression model, we expect α5 to be positive and statistically significant. All data used to construct the test variables and the dependent variables come from the acquirers’ annual reports.

We use a number of control variables that relate to the acquirer, the acquiree, and the acquisition itself. In terms of the acquirer, we control for its profitability (ROA), its indebtedness (DEBT), its liquidity (LIQUID), its concentration of power (OWNCON) and the existence of dual classes of shares (DUAL_SHARES).Footnote7 We include ROA to control for differences in the acquirer’s capacity to withstand expenses associated with amortizations. We measure ROA as the acquirer’s net profit divided by its average total assets in the year prior to the acquisition. We include DEBT to control for the impact of debt covenants on the initial accounting for goodwill, and measure it as total debt scaled by total assets at the beginning of the acquisition year. We include LIQUID to further control for the acquirer’s capacity to withstand expenses associated with impairments, and measure it as cash and short-term investments scaled with total assets at the beginning of the acquisition year. We measure the firm’s past accounting for goodwill (PAST_GW) as goodwill scaled with total assets, at the beginning of the acquisition year. OWNCON is measured as the largest owner’s percentage of voting rights, at the beginning of the acquisition year. DUAL_SHARES is a dummy variable taking the value of 1 for firms with dual-class shares. Data on acquirer-specific characteristics are obtained from either COMPUSTAT Global or each firm’s annual report, and financial market information is collected from Thomson Reuters Eikon.

We also control for a number of acquiree-specific characteristics: the acquiree’s pre-acquisition intangible assets (TRGT_INTANGIBLE), pre-acquisition debt (TRGT_DEBT), and relative size (TRGT_SIZE). We use TRGT_INTANGIBLE to control for the possibility that a larger proportion of the purchase price is reported as goodwill when the acquiree is intangible-intensive. It is measured as the acquiree’s total intangible assets scaled with total assets at the time of the acquisition. TRGT_DEBT controls for the effect of adding the acquiree’s debt to the acquirer’s balance sheet; measured as the acquiree’s total debt scaled with total assets at the time of the acquisition. TRGT_SIZE controls for the effect that relatively large acquisitions seem to destroy more value for the acquirer’s shareholders (e.g. Grinstein & Hribar, Citation2004; Harford & Li, Citation2007; Loderer & Martin, Citation1990). We measure TRGT_SIZE as the purchase price scaled with the market value of the acquirer at the time of the acquisition. Data on acquiree-specific characteristics are manually collected from the acquisition analyses, as reported in the acquirers’ annual reports.

Finally, we include two acquisition-specific control variables: the level of trading in the acquiring firm (ACTIVITY) and the payment form (NONCASH). ACTIVITY measures the value of the acquiring firm’s traded shares scaled with the average market capitalization during the previous calendar year. The data is obtained from the OMX Nasdaq Stockholm website. NONCASH is the proportion of total purchase price that is not paid in cash. Because both the number of acquisitions and the purchase price paid in acquisitions vary considerably between years and industry, we also include untabulated year and industry dummies in all regression analyses together with robust standard errors clustered at the acquirer firm-level.

3.3. Sample Selection and a Description of the Acquisition Analyses

We start by identifying all potential acquirers listed on the Stockholm Stock Exchange (SSE) in the period 2005–2013. Panel A of shows that there are 2299 available firm-years during the studied period. We exclude firms not reporting in accordance with IFRS (28 firm-years), and firms that are not domiciled in Sweden (118 firm-years). We then exclude the finance industry, including banks, insurance companies, real estate companies, and investment companies (371 firm-years). Only ten firm-year observations are excluded due to lack of data. In sum, we reduce the initial sample of potential acquirers to 1772 firm-year observations.

Table 1. Sample description.

We manually search the annual reports of the 1772 firm-year observations to identify acquisitions leading to a stake in the target firm of 100%. As shown in Panel B of , we identify 1418 acquisition analyses. We remove acquisition analyses when the purchase price is either not specified or reported as zero (in 64 and 9 observations, respectively). We also remove observations where goodwill is not specified or negative (101 and 21 observations, respectively). We exclude another 132 observations with missing information, leading to a final sample of 1112 acquisition analyses. In the final sample, 263 acquisition analyses (23.7%) contain more than one acquiree. In total, 78.4% of all identified acquisition analyses contain sufficient information to be included in our final sample.

Panel A of provides more detailed descriptive statistics on the final sample of the 1112 acquisition analyses from 690 annual reports. In other words, there are disclosures about acquisitions in 38.9% (690/1772) of the firm-year observations. The years with the highest and the lowest number of acquisitions are the year before and after the financial crisis; i.e. 2007 and 2009, respectively.

Table 2. Descriptive statistics for the acquisition analyses – full sample.

For our final sample, more than a third of the listed firms report an acquisition analysis (690 firm-years), and 72.2% of the acquired firms are foreign. Moreover, 76.4% of the acquisition analyses include only one significant acquiree (848 out of 1112 observations). As shown in Panel A, only 24 out of 1112 acquisition analyses include publicly listed acquirees. Untabulated data shows that the purchase price is below USD 1mn in 11.5% of the cases (128 acquisitions).Footnote8,Footnote9 This distinguishes our sample from those in previous studies (Detzen & Zülch, Citation2012; Shalev et al., Citation2013; Zhang & Zhang, Citation2017). Shalev et al. (Citation2013) reports purchase prices almost twenty times larger than the average price in our sample. Panel C provides information about the size of the reported goodwill during the studied period. Most goodwill was acquired in 2007 (both in absolute terms and on average), and the least in 2009.

In we focus on a subsample with 765 observations (i.e. 68.8% of the final sample of the 1112 acquisition analyses) that contains full information on the pre-acquisition values of assets and liabilities and the revaluations.Footnote10 reveals that the average purchase price is SEK 526 mn, with the highest price is paid in 2007 (avg SEK 991 mn), and the lowest in 2010 (avg SEK 144 mn). The average acquiree had a pre-acquisition book value of equity of SEK 132 mn, with the highest in 2007 (SEK 263 mn), and the lowest in 2010 (SEK 39 mn). Thus, acquirees were bought at an average market-to-book ratio of 4.0, and the ratio varied from 2.8 (in 2008) to 10.6 (in 2005). The average purchase price in excess of the acquired book value of equity is SEK 395 mn (varying from SEK 728 mn in 2007 to SEK 181 mn in 2008). On average, 27.1% of the excess purchase price is recognized as specific assets and liabilities. The remaining SEK 287 mn (about 72.8%) is reported as goodwill. It is only in 2006 that less than 50% of the purchase price is reported as goodwill. In 2008, when the market-to-book value is at its lowest, reported goodwill is at its highest (93.4%). An untabulated analysis reveals that in 29.1% of the cases (324 of 1112), the entire excess purchase price is reported as goodwill.Footnote11 In contrast, there is no reported goodwill in 11.7% of the observations (130/1112). It appears as if many acquirers routinely report the entire excess payment as goodwill.

Table 3. Descriptive statistics for the acquisition analyses – subsample.

4. Empirical Analysis

4.1. Descriptive Statistics

presents descriptive statistics for the variables used in the regression analyses of Models 1–5. The dependent variable GOODWILL displays an equal-weighted average value of 59.1%, which is fairly close to the value-weighted average shown in (53.1%). Thus, for the average acquisition analysis, goodwill represents 59.1% of the purchase price. For a few acquisitions, goodwill is larger than the purchase price, with a maximum value of 212.5%. This occurs when the target firm’s book value of equity is negative at the acquisition date. In total, 74.6% of the purchase price is reported as specific and unspecific intangible assets (INTANGIBLES).

Table 4. Descriptive statistics – variables.

Among the test variables, BONUS is on average 33.1% (median: 24.4%), indicating that variable compensation is a relatively small part of the CEO’s total compensation. Fernandes et al. (Citation2013) show that in large Anglo-Saxon firms considerably more than 50% of compensation is variable. The test variable FAMILY captures family ownership and we find that families control more than the majority of the acquirers (74.9%). EXCESS_PRICE_2 has a mean value of 0.748, suggesting that 25.2% of the excess purchase price in a typical acquisition reflects the acquired firm’s pre-acquisition book value of equity. A minimum value of −11.5 and a maximum value of 12.3, as well as a standard deviation of 0.866, indicates that the excess purchase price is often considerably different from the pre-acquisition book value of equity. The variable EXCESS_PRICE shows that 20.4% of the acquisitions are made at a higher than year-industry average. This clearly shows that a few acquisitions are made at very steep prices. EXPERIENCE captures the acquirers involved in above-average number of acquisitions within its industry-year, and we find that only 21.9% of the acquirers are involved in serial-acquisitions over the years. We also find that UNCERTAINTY is high for 62.2% of the takeovers, meaning that more than half of the acquisitions are made outside of Sweden.Footnote12

For the control variables, we note that three variables are connected to ownership. CFRIGHT displays the ultimate owner’s cash flow rights; on average 22.7%. This is considerably lower than the average voting rights (OWNCON) with a mean of 33.4%. Because of multiple classes of shares, the largest owner holds more voting than cash flow rights. In the sample, 58.6% of the observations are firms that employ dual classes of shares (DUAL_SHARES). Furthermore, we observe that stock options (OPTIONS) are fairly uncommon (19.0%), that acquisitions are usually made by profitable firms (ROA) and most acquisitions (90.7%) are paid directly in cash which is consistent with prior studies on family firm’s (e.g. Caprio et al., Citation2011; Martin, Citation1996). As expected from a sample of mainly privately held acquirees, targets are often small (TRGT_SIZE is on average 7.4%).

presents pairwise correlations for the variables used in the regression analyses. In Column 1, the CEO’s variable compensation (BONUS) is negatively correlated with family ownership (FAMILY), non-cash payments (NONCASH) and the size of the acquiree (TRGT_SIZE). BONUS is also positively correlated with excess purchase price (EXCESS_PRICE), the CEO’s total salary (TOTPAY), the profitability of the acquirer (ROA) and the acquiree’s pre-acquisition level of intangibles (TRGT_INTANGIBLE). Overall, these correlations suggest that CEOs with more variable compensation are more prone to include noncash components in the payment.

Table 5. Pairwise correlation matrix.

In Column 2, family firms (FAMILY) are positively correlated with acquisitions of foreign targets (UNCERTAINTY), ownership concentration (OWNCON), differentiated voting rights (DUAL_SHARES), past experience with goodwill (PAST_GW) and indebtedness (DEBT). FAMILY is also negatively correlated with excess purchase price (EXCESS_PRICE), cash flow rights (CFRIGHT), the CEO’s total salary (TOTPAY), the market activity of the acquirer (ACTIVITY), and pre-acquisition liquidity level (LIQUID). Hence, family firms have more concentrated ownership through control enhancing mechanisms, and may therefore have limited incentives to align their strategic decisions with non-controlling owners. Family firms are also more prone to report goodwill, and provide lower levels of CEO compensation. Interestingly, family acquirers are more successful in completing acquisitions of non-Swedish acquirees.

In Column 3, we find that excess purchase price (EXCESS_PRICE) is positively correlated with above average past experience with acquisitions (EXPERIENCE), foreign acquisitions (UNCERTAINTY), options (OPTIONS), the CEO’s total salary (TOTPAY), the market activity of the acquirer (ACTIVITY), the acquirer’s return on assets (ROA), the acquiree’s book value of intangibles (TRGT_INTANGIBLE) and the acquiree’s relative size (TRGT_SIZE). EXCESS_PRICE is also negatively correlated with cash flow rights (CFRIGHT). These correlations indicate that the acquirer pays above the industry average for an acquiree when the acquirer is relatively more experienced than its industry peers, when the acquiree is domiciled outside of Sweden, when its CEO’s total salary is relatively high, when the acquirer is profitable, and when the acquiree prior to acquisition holds more intangible assets on its balance sheet.

Column 4, displays that acquirers with above-average acquisition experience within its industry (EXPERIENCE) are positively correlated with differentiated voting rights (DUAL_SHARES), options (OPTIONS), the CEO’s total salary (TOTPAY), and return on assets (ROA). EXPERIENCE is also negatively correlated foreign targets (UNCERTAINTY), with cash flow rights (CF_RIGHTS), non-cash payment (NONCASH) and the acquirees’ level of book value intangibles (TRGT_INTANGIB). Thus, experienced acquirers seem to be more conservative as they are focusing on acquiring domestic firms using cash payments.

Finally, in Column 5, we find that more uncertain acquisitions (UNCERTAINTY) are positively correlated with (DUAL_SHARES), the CEO’s total salary (TOTPAY), the market activity of the acquirer (ACTIVITY), the acquirer’s past experience with goodwill (PAST_GW), the acquirer’s indebtedness (DEBT) and the acquiree’s book value of intangibles (TRGT_INTANGIB). UNCERTAINTY is also negatively correlated with cash flow rights (CF_RIGHTS), non-cash payments (NONCASH) and the acquirees’ relative size (TRGT_SIZE). Overall, these correlations indicate that firms with a past record of reporting goodwill are also more prone to acquire smaller foreign firms, and the payment is more likely to be non-cash.

4.2. Motives Shaping the Initial Accounting for Goodwill

presents the results from the main analyses of the proportion of the purchase price accounted for as goodwill in a business combination. Specifically, we present results from univariate regressions (see column Univariate in ), and five different multivariate regressions (see Models 1–5 in ). Model 1 is our main model, and Models 2 and 3 come with minor variations in the modeling of ownership characteristics. Model 4 is similar to Model 1 with the exception that we change the measure of the independent variable EXCESS_PRICE to reflect the absolute value of the difference between the purchase price and the acquiree’s book value of equity (i.e. EXCESS_PRICE_2). Finally, Model 5 is similar to Model 1 with the exception that we replace the dependent variable GOODWILL with INTANGIBLES, so that we include the reported goodwill and all adjusted identifiable intangibles (and scale it by the purchase price). All multivariate models are based on robust standard errors, adjusted for year-fixed and industry-fixed effects, and all continuous variables are winsorized at the 1%-level. There seems to be no problems with multicollinearity as all variables have tolerable VIF scores; we find the largest VIF scores for CF_RIGHTS (VIF of 2.66), and OWNCON (VIF of 2.44).Footnote13,Footnote14

Table 6. Determinants of the initial accounting for goodwill.

Starting with the managerial motives and the initial accounting for goodwill, we find BONUS not to be associated with the proportion of the purchase price accounted for as goodwill. This finding is consistent for all our different model specifications, and in stark contrast with the findings of prior studies (e.g. Detzen & Zülch, Citation2012; Shalev et al., Citation2013; Zhang & Zhang, Citation2017); all of which find that management's personal motives have a positive impact on the proportion of the purchase price reported as goodwill. Thus, we find support for the first hypothesis, suggesting that managers’ motives do not impact the proportion of the purchase price reported as goodwill in an institutional setting where controlling ownership is common.

We speculate that the finding is due to several important differences between the Anglo-Saxon and the Swedish institutional settings. First, as previously explained, Swedish law and the SCGC make it impossible for CEOs of Swedish publicly listed firms to take on a leading role on the corporate board where acquisitions are often discussed. Second, the board of directors of Swedish publicly listed firms are dominated by active family owners who potentially discipline CEOs to act in accordance with owner motives rather than their own personal motives. Finally, the CEOs’ incentive to manipulate future earnings is dampened when their compensation is less related to corporate performance (Fernandes et al., Citation2013).

Next, we turn to ownership motives and the initial accounting for goodwill. In support of the second hypothesis, we find that FAMILY is positively related to the proportion of the purchase price reported as goodwill for all five models, suggesting that family-owned acquirers report more goodwill. Overall, the family firm effect is robust to a number of controls for ownership structures (compare Model 1 with Models 2 and 3). Regardless of whether we control for ownership concentration (i.e. OWNCON and CF_RIGHTS) and differentiated voting rights (DUAL_SHARES), family firms report a larger proportion of the purchase price as goodwill.

Taken together, the results of H1 and H2 indicate that controlling owners, such as families, eliminate the managerial motive of aligning unverifiable fair-value measures with optimized compensation. Thus, the standard agency conflict between managers and owners that has been central to the previous research on the initial accounting for goodwill is not present in our setting. This result can be context-driven, but it can also relate to the fact that samples containing many small acquirers and small privately held target firms are under-studied. Given that there is support for the second hypothesis, our data suggest that family firms actively choose to report a larger proportion of the purchase price as goodwill.

In support of the third hypothesis, we find that the coefficient for EXCESS_PRICE is positively associated with the proportion of the purchase price accounted for as goodwill. When the acquiring firm pays a higher than industry-average excess purchase price for the acquiree, it is more likely to report more as goodwill. Although it is possible that an excess purchase price stems from uncapitalizable assets, it is more likely that the proportion of the purchase price accounted for as goodwill increases if synergies lack economic substance (Bartov et al., Citation2021; de Bodt et al., Citation2018). Also, managers that pay excessively for an acquiree but have no personal motives may desire to control future expenses by disguising the overpayment as goodwill (cf. Bartov et al., Citation2021). It is possible that by reporting a larger proportion of the excess purchase price as goodwill, acquirers achieve such objectives and also diminish the likelihood of being questioned by outside stakeholders.

We further find support for the fourth hypothesis. The coefficient for EXPERIENCE is negative and statistically significant in all five models. This suggests that experienced acquirers learn how to attribute the purchase price to specific assets and liabilities. We note that only 21.9% of the acquirers are experienced acquirers. Untabulated tests show no time-trend in the proportion of the purchase price accounted for as goodwill; meaning that there seems to be no overall learning effect as firms in general become more accustomed to IFRS 3. Perhaps using knowledge from experienced third-parties, including auditing firms and investment banks, could dampen the proportion of the purchase price recognized as goodwill. But while it makes sense, such a plausible expectation is not possible to test given currently available data.

Finally, there is some support of the fifth hypothesis, that the uncertainty of making foreign acquisitions (UNCERTAINTY) is positively associated with the proportion of purchase price accounted for as goodwill. This finding suggests that the acquirers counteract the higher level of uncertainty of attributing value to foreign acquisitions by reporting a larger proportion of purchase price as goodwill. The larger proportion of the purchase price accounted for as goodwill may be an option-of-last-resort, but it raises the question of whether acquirers perhaps should improve the due diligence of foreign acquisitions. Similar to the analysis of EXCESS_PRICE above, the results indicate that acquirers choose more discretion, which is desirable if the acquiree’s future performance turns out to be unexpectedly weak. Yet, we do not find any significant results related to UNCERTAINTY when applying Models 4 and 5. Using the alternative definition of EXCESS_PRICE (EXCESS_PRICE_2) in Model 4, does not change other finding other than UNCERTAINTY. As we test for the dependent variable INTANGIBLES in Model 5, the coefficient for UNCERTAINTY is not statistically significant associated with a dependent variable that includes both reported goodwill and recognized intangibles in the numerator. Because the dependent variable likely includes intangible assets with definite and indefinite useful life, it is not possible to determine whether there is no effect due to the correct application of the standards or whether the inclusion of a coarse measure is producing too much noise to reach sufficient statistical precision.

Among the control variables, we find that CFRIGHT and DUAL_SHARES consistently have a negative effect on the proportion of the purchase price accounted for as goodwill. A potentially important variable to control for is the previous accounting for goodwill. For this reason, we included the variable PAST_GW in the analysis. Coefficients for this variable are statistically significant in all tests but Model 5, which suggests that firms who have reported goodwill in previous acquisitions are more likely to report a larger proportion of the purchase price as goodwill. Finally, we find that the proportion of the purchase price accounted for as goodwill is lower when the acquiree prior to the acquisition has recognized specific intangible assets on its balance sheet (TRGT_INTANGIBLE). We attribute this finding to the higher visibility of specific intangibles at the time of the acquisition.

4.3. Robustness Tests

We also perform a number of robustness tests based on Models 1 and 5, as specified for the analyses in . In Columns 1 and 2 of , we test whether the findings hold when small acquisitions are excluded. We choose a purchase price cut-off of SEK 8mn (approximately equivalent to the common M&A threshold of USD 1mn). Results remain qualitatively the same as the coefficient for BONUS is not statistically significant whereas coefficients for all other test variables remain robust, with the exception for UNCERTAINTY.

Table 7. Robustness tests.

Columns 3 and 4 of are similar to Models 1 and 5 in , but here we have reduced the sample to acquisition analyses containing only one acquiree. We do so to ensure that the main results are not affected by a non-transparent build-up of multiple minor acquirees in the acquisition analysis. We find that results remain in large consistent. What stands out is that EXPERIENCE is not statistically significant for any of the two model specifications when dropping acquisition analyses that contain more than one takeover. This could be because experienced acquirers often include multiple small acquisitions in one acquisition analysis; this subsample contains fewer experienced acquirers. However, the size of each of these acquisitions that are combined in the acquisition analysis are often much larger than what smaller acquirers report as a significant business combination that are deemed to be reported as single takeover in the acquisition analysis. Overall, we conclude that our main results of interest are overall robust and valid.

Columns 5 and 6 of , are also similar to Models 1 and 5 in , but here we restrict the sample to acquirers with a market value of equity of at least SEK 800mn at the acquisition date. We do so because some small firms may not fully comply with IFRS. In some cases, the Swedish Inspectorate of Auditors has even issued disciplinary warnings to auditors for failing to acknowledge small listed firms’ non-compliance with mandatory IFRS.Footnote15 However, our results remain qualitatively the same as the coefficient for BONUS is not statistically significant whereas the coefficients for all other test variables remain robust, with the exception for the coefficient for UNCERTAINTY in Column 6.

5. Conclusions

We explore motives that shape the initial accounting for goodwill under the impairment-only approach in Sweden. The final sample includes 1112 acquisition analyses reported by 205 unique acquirers in the period 2005–2013. The study is different from previous studies not only because of its larger size, but primarily because the institutional setting, with many controlling family owners, better resembles most countries around the world. In previous literature, it is shown that management’s personal incentives play an important role when they apply professional judgment to the acquisition analysis.

In line with prior studies, our sample reveals that goodwill is by far the largest single accounting item reported in conjunction with an acquisition. As much as three-fourths of the purchase price is reported as acquired goodwill. But in contrast to prior studies, there is no association between the CEO’s earnings-based compensation and the proportion of the purchase price accounted for as goodwill. Our interpretation is that CEOs are considerably less powerful in Sweden compared to Anglo-Saxon CEOs in shaping the initial accounting for goodwill because CEOs cannot be the chairman of the board and ownership is more concentrated. Moreover, we investigate how family ownership shapes the initial accounting for goodwill. Across the world, family ownership is predominant and better knowledge of how family ownership influences accounting decisions is of importance for both researchers and standard setters. We show that family owners allocate more of the purchase price to goodwill. The reasons for such a behavior are not explicitly explored in our study, but we suspect that an increased opaqueness strengthens the position of a controlling family owner, relative to external stakeholders, by obscuring information about the acquiree.

The analysis also reveals that other economic motives shape the initial accounting for goodwill. Our findings suggest that the proportion of the purchase price reported as goodwill increases with payments above the industry-average for an acquiree’s book value of equity; and to some extent, with the uncertainty that comes with foreign acquisitions. These findings stress the difficulty of using professional judgment in the initial accounting for goodwill, and show systematic variation in how acquirees are accounted for. We also find that acquirers with past above-industry acquisition experience have a damening effect on the proportion of the purchase price reported as goodwill. This association is consistent for all but one alternative test; it becomes insignificant when including only acquisition analyses of one acquiree. This finding indicates that past experience improves the professional judgment of serial-acquirers; and as a consequence, they allocate more of the purchase price to specific assets and liabilities. Although experience matters, there seems to be no time trend in our sample, in the sense that the proportion allocated to goodwill does not decreases with time.

Foremost, the study contributes to the accounting literature by showing that the institutional context is important to understand the initial accounting for goodwill. Researchers studying the subsequent goodwill accounting decisions, such as impairments, should be aware of the varying motives that shape goodwill accounting choices. We also contribute to the literature on agency conflicts. In particular, we show that the discretion of fair-value measurements may not reflect managers’ personal motives, but instead ownership motives. In a broad sense, the case of goodwill accounting shows how fair-value estimates based on unobservable Level 3 inputs are affected by the institutional setting.

Our study should be of interest for international standard setters as it provides evidence that family ownership plays a role in the initial accounting for goodwill. It is, therefore, wise for standard setters to improve their understanding of how owners' motives affect goodwill accounting choices given that goodwill is a very large item in many firms’ balance sheets, and because family ownership is large and frequent around the world. We encourage more research exploring different motives that shape the initial accounting for goodwill, and how motives in different institutional settings may have different effect on the use of fair-value measures in the accounting for business combinations. Another interesting avenue of future research is to test how decisions in the initial accounting for goodwill affect subsequent goodwill accounting choices. Finally, it is important to further our understanding about what factors incentivize high-quality acquisition analysis to provide investors with a better understanding of payments and the underlying acquired business.

Acknowledgments

We thank Kjell Henry Knivflå, Stefan Sundgren, Dennis Sundvik and seminar participants at the 2016 FIBE Conference, 2017 AAA Annual Meeting in San Diego, 2017 EAA Annual Congress in Valencia, Norwegian School of Economics, Umeå University, for useful comments. Special thanks are due to two anonymous referees for detailed comments and helpful suggestions. Earlier versions of this paper were called ‘The Purchase Price Allocation Decision'.

Disclosure Statement

No potential conflict of interest was reported by the author(s).

Notes

1 The European Union made the International Accounting Standards Board’s (IASB) standard IFRS 3 (Business Combinations) (IASB, Citation2008) mandatory as of January 2005, which altered how most European firms account for business combinations. IFRS 3 originated from a joint project with the Financial Accounting Standards Board (FASB) in the United States, and the FASB introduced SFAS 141 (Business Combinations) (FASB, Citation2001a) in 2001. The subsequent valuation of goodwill is regulated by SFAS 142 (Goodwill and Other Intangible Assets) (FASB, Citation2001b) in the U.S. and by IAS 36 (Impairment of Assets) (IASB, Citation2004) in Europe. Because the main features are similar, we frequently refer to them as the impairment-only regime. Most prior research in the area is based on the U.S. adoption of SFAS 141 and 142.

2 Prior to the adoption of IFRS 3, accounting standards did typically not require substantial disclosures on the acquired firm and the acquisition analysis. Consequently, studies on how acquiring firms valued the acquired entity’s assets, liabilities and the goodwill were unfeasible due to lack of data.

3 We use the terms acquiree and target firm synonymously throughout the paper.

4 In the U.S., corporate ownership is more dispersed. Aminadav and Papaioannou (Citation2020) document that the average largest owner of a U.S. firm holds 13.0% of the voting rights as compared to the world average of 31.5%. Family ownership is less pronounced in the U.S. relative to other countries: La Porta et al. (Citation1999) find that 10% of large U.S. and UK firms were family-controlled. In Sweden and the rest of the world, the percentage is much higher. Adams et al. (Citation2010) survey several studies and find that almost half of the board members of U.S. firms are inside or affiliated directors. In more than two thirds of U.S. firms, the CEO also acts as chairman of the board (Tinaikar, Citation2017).

5 The purchase price and the goodwill balance do not include any cost related to due diligence, legal fees or other expenses related to the acquisition. We do so to make goodwill comparable overall years as these fees are only reported in detail for the years 2005 to 2009.

6 Many Swedish firms are controlled by a family that exercises ownership through a publicly listed investment company. Because we study ultimate ownership, we see through such pyramid structures. Data is collected in part from the book series Owners and Power (SIS Förlag 2005–13), and in part manually from each firm’s annual reports. We always take dual-classes of shares into consideration. For example, the Wallenberg family owns Electrolux through the publicly listed firm Investor. In 2005, the family owns 46.7% of Investor’s voting rights, and Investor owns 26.0% of Electrolux voting rights. In total, the Wallenberg family owns 12.1% of the voting rights (and 1.7% of the cash flow rights). The 12.1% of voting rights still means that the family has more voting rights than the next ten owners combined. Our measures resemble those in e.g. Holmén and Knopf (Citation2004).

7 A potential issue with our empirical models is that the dependent and some of the control variables (i.e., PAST_GOODWILL, ACQ_ROA, ACQ_DEBT, and ACQ_LIQUID) may be correlated with each other. This is because acquired goodwill will be part of future goodwill balances and of total assets. To ensure that no correlations over time between the dependent and independent control variables affect the results we have taken the following measures . First, we test whether multicollinearity is a problem using VIF scores, but no variable has a score higher than 2.66. Second, we test for univariate associations for each independent variable in (see Column Univariate), and find that all variables of interest continue to be significant, indicating that no independent variable of interest is inflated by the control variables. Third, we use the Fractional Response Model (see Gallani et al., Citation2015). Results from these untabulated tests are in all material aspects similar to those reported in . These three steps suggest that our empirical model is valid.

8 In the literature, it is common to exclude acquisitions smaller than USD 1mn. This is approximately the same as SEK 8mn in 2013 prices.

9 The sample also includes 132 acquisitions of acquirees with negative equity at the acquisition date. Thus, TRGT_DEBT is sometimes above 1 (i.e., total debt is larger than total assets), and EXCESS_PRICE_2 is sometimes negative. We exclude acquisitions when there is no purchase price. Results are qualitatively similar when excluding acquisitions of acquirees with negative equity.

10 The number of complete fair-value reassessment of other assets than goodwill in the acquisition analyses decreases over time, coinciding with the reduced disclosure requirements of the revised IFRS 3(R) in 2010.

11 A negative revaluation of the acquiree’s net assets makes it possible to report more than 100% of the excess purchase price as goodwill (the maximum in the sample is 213%).

12 This is slightly lower than the reported Foreign acquisitions (%) of 65% in . The difference is caused by different sample restrictions in the main regression analyses where all acquisitions have to be confirmed non-Swedish.

13 All acquired intangibles with indefinite lives are only subject to impairment tests, and ideally, we would like to include all specific intangible assets with indefinite lives in the dependent variable. Many firms, however, do not specify in their acquisition analyses to what extent adjusted specific intangibles have a definite or indefinite life. Model 5 in and test and show that our findings are robust when including all adjusted intangibles as specified in the acquisition analyses. In other words, we added intangibles with both definite and indefinite life to the dependent variable. In addition, we perform untabulated tests where we add to Model 1 a dummy variable taking the value of one when the acquisition analysis includes an observable adjustment for intangibles with indefinite lives, and zero otherwise. None of our main findings are altered from this procedure. We thank an anonymous reviewer for suggesting these additional tests.

14 For robustness reasons, we re-run some of the tests without the control variables PAST_GW, ROA, DEBT and LIQUID because they can, by definition, be associated with the test variables. Untabulated results show that our results are robust to such modeling alterations.

15 We thank an anonymous reviewer for pointing this out to us.

References