3,685
Views
22
CrossRef citations to date
0
Altmetric
Articles

Retrospective voting and party support at elections: credit and blame for government and opposition

&

ABSTRACT

Retrospective voting is arguably one of the most important mechanisms of representative democracy, and whether or not the public holds the government accountable for its policy performance has been extensively studied. In this paper, we test whether retrospective voting extends to parties in the opposition, that is whether and how parties’ past performance evaluations affect their vote, regardless of whether they were in government or in opposition. Taking advantage of a rich set of questions embedded in a representative German national elections panel, we update our knowledge on the retrospective voting mechanism by modeling retrospective voting at the party level. The findings indicate that the incumbent status is not the only criterion for retrospective voting, ultimately suggesting that both government and opposition parties can expect credit and blame for their conduct and this should provide some impetus for responsive performance of all parties.

1. Introduction

Whether or not legislators are judged on what has happened in the past has significant implications for democratic accountability. Accordingly, a substantial literature has investigated the policy foci and time horizons that guide voters’ decisions. Almost without exception, the literature on electoral accountability examines voters facing a binary choice between either supporting the incumbent or not (e.g. Fiorina Citation1981; Berry and Howell Citation2007), mostly focused on the economic performance of government (e.g. Paldam Citation1991; Powell and Whitten Citation1993; Anderson Citation2007). This focus stems from the notion that evaluations of policy-making are restricted to parties in government (Duch and Stevenson Citation2008). Clearly, however, other parties influence policy-making and, in many contexts, (e.g. federal systems and minority governments), this influence is substantial (Strøm Citation1990; Powell and Whitten Citation1993; Lijphart Citation1999). Therefore, voters’ beliefs should reflect this wider notion of responsibility at the party level (Duch and Stevenson Citation2008; Duch and Falcó-Gimeno Citation2014). So far, very little empirical work has examined whether and how the public holds their representatives – and not only the government – accountable for the country’s current state of affairs.

We employ this wider notion of performance evaluations and model retrospective voting at the party level. While recent studies have started focusing on each party in the coalition government instead of the incumbent coalition governments as a whole (e.g. van der Brug, van der Eijk, and Franklin Citation2007; Fisher and Hobolt Citation2010; Debus, Stegmaier, and Tosun Citation2014; Williams, Stegmaier, and Debus Citation2015), we go one step further. First, we examine how retrospective evaluations of all parties, regardless of whether they were in office or not, affect the probability of voting for these parties. Second, we move beyond economic evaluations and examine the effect of different types of performance evaluations. We start with a focus on economic evaluations, by far the most extensively tested notion of retrospective behavior. We then move to a more general concept of retrospective accountability, since we know today that the economy is not the only area in which the public may want to hold their representatives accountable (e.g. Singer Citation2011; De Vries and Giger Citation2014). This enables us to obtain a fully fledged picture on whether and how accountability mechanisms can affect political parties as voters’ most evident representatives (e.g. Strøm Citation2000).

The substantial application investigates data from a long-term panel of the German Longitudinal Election Study (GLES) providing a set of new measures that directly capture (dis)satisfaction with the performance for all parties represented in the parliament, the Bundestag. Germany is a good example of a multi-party system where opposition parties have a relatively strong influence on the policy-making process (Duch and Stevenson Citation2008). In addition, its history of coalition governments, where multiple parties compete for shares of policy-making responsibility, calls for a focus on the party level, rather than on the more abstract level of government versus opposition (Debus, Stegmaier, and Tosun Citation2014; Williams, Stegmaier, and Debus Citation2015).

The results indicate that the common assumption of retrospective evaluations having a unique or a stronger effect on government parties, when compared to the opposition, does not hold. Electoral accountability occurs at the party level with party size playing an important role in responsibility attribution to single parties, regardless of whether they were in government or in opposition. It is not only the prime minister or chancellor party which is affected the most by retrospective voting (Fisher and Hobolt Citation2010; Debus, Stegmaier, and Tosun Citation2014), but also the largest opposition party. We conclude by stating that future research should examine electoral accountability mechanisms at the party level, considering both government and opposition.

2. Retrospective voting at the party level

In a simple understanding of political representation, citizens constitute the principal that delegates authority in decision-making to political actors by voting for them in elections (Strøm Citation2000). In this context, electoral accountability is said to exist when citizens can retrospectively hold politicians accountable, and reward or punish them with their vote (e.g. Zelle Citation1995; Gidengil et al. Citation2001; Bélanger Citation2004; Dassonneville, Blais, and Dejaeghere Citation2015).Footnote1 The existing literature has examined the reward/punish mechanism by mainly focusing on the economic performance of government parties (e.g. Anderson Citation2007; Lewis-Beck, Nadeau, and Elias Citation2008). Empirical analyses regularly find that “when economic conditions are bad, citizens vote against the ruling party” (Lewis-Beck Citation1991, 2), even if the strength of economic voting differs substantially across studies and across settings (Duch and Stevenson Citation2008; Hobolt, Tilley, and Banducci Citation2013).

Very recently, however, the retrospective voting approach of examining the government performance collectively has come under increasing pressure (e.g. Fisher and Hobolt Citation2010; Debus, Stegmaier, and Tosun Citation2014). This approach is particularly problematic in countries with multi-party systems and coalition governments. For one, voters cannot vote for the government as a whole but only for one party of the coalition. Assuming identical influence of past performance evaluations on all coalition partners is an unrealistic restriction (e.g. Anderson Citation2000; Williams, Stegmaier, and Debus Citation2015). For another, in many contexts (e.g. federal systems and minority governments), the influence of parties out of government on policy-making is substantial where the responsibility attribution is less clear-cut between government and opposition parties and controversial policy decision can only be made in cooperation with the opposition (Strøm Citation1990; Powell and Whitten Citation1993; Lijphart Citation1999). It is therefore likely that voters are aware of and use this wider notion of responsibility when choosing parties in elections (Anderson Citation2000; Sanders and Carey Citation2003; Duch and Stevenson Citation2008; Duch and Falcó-Gimeno Citation2014). To generally evaluate parties, voters might simply take into consideration the obligations that parties are expected to fulfil in their role of opposition or government party (e.g. Hobolt and Tilley Citation2014). Hence, they might use different information when weighting the performance evaluation of government and opposition parties. While government parties might be judged more on their policy performance, the evaluation of opposition parties might be more likely driven by institutional aspects. These circumstances make it necessary to test the retrospective voting mechanism not only on the government but also at the party level, hence for both the government and the opposition.Footnote2

In a first step, we examine the impact of economic evaluations on all parties. In keeping with the literature, a positive (negative) economic evaluation should increase (decrease) the likelihood to vote for parties in government, and should have an opposite or no influence on vote choice for parties in opposition. In addition, and again in line with the existing literature, the effect of retrospective voting on the government parties’ vote should be stronger when citizens assign responsibility for the economic situation to the government. In a second step, we move from economic-centric evaluations to a general performance evaluation of parties. Here, we follow the most recent literature indicating that accountability extends to party performance across an array of policy areas and not only the economy (e.g. Fisher and Hobolt Citation2010; Singer Citation2011; De Vries and Giger Citation2014). Again, in line with a common approach, performance evaluations should have a unique or stronger impact on parties in government when compared to parties in opposition. If however, as we claim, retrospective voting works for parties both in government and in opposition, we should observe economic voting as well as general performance evaluations to have a different effect across parties and to matter for parties regardless of their government status.

3. Data, variables and methods

The German Longitudinal Election Study, Component 8 (GLES) (Rattinger et al. Citation2014) (2009–2017) consists of several waves. It covers, among other things, the two federal elections of 2009 and 2013.Footnote3 Given that substantive conclusions are very similar for the two elections, in this paper, we only show the results for the 2013 elections and report results for the 2009 elections in the Appendix only ( and ).

Our dependent variable is party choice on Election Day. To measure the effect of retrospective evaluations on party choice, we apply multinomial logit models.Footnote4 The set of discrete alternatives consists of up to five parties that are regarded as being most likely to gain parliamentary representation: the two largest parties, the Christian Democratic Union/Christian Social Union (CDU/CSU) and the Social Democratic Party (SPD), and the smaller parties, the Free Democratic Party (FDP), the Greens and Die Linke (The Left).Footnote5

Turning to our independent variables, our main explanatory variable on economic performance is the economic situation as perceived by the voters: the variable measures whether the economy has worsened or improved using a scale from 1 (a lot worse) to 5 (improved a lot). A follow-up question asks respondents how strongly the policy of the federal government has affected the economic development, with options spanning from 1 (not at all) to 5 (very much), thus allowing respondents to ascribe levels of responsibility.

GLES also collects data on general performance for each of the parties represented in parliament using the following question: “How satisfied or dissatisfied are you with the performance of X party in the government [or in the opposition]?” The options available to respondents span a scale from −5 to +5 with higher scores representing a better policy performance. We recode all performance variables to range from 0 to 1, where 1 represents higher levels on that specific variable.

In all models, we include partisanship to isolate the effect of voters’ partisan affiliation on vote choice (e.g. Duch and Stevenson Citation2008; Tilley, Garry, and Bold Citation2008; Tilley and Hobolt Citation2011).Footnote6 We also control for satisfaction with democracy and several individual-level determinants such as age, gender and political interest.Footnote7

4. Empirical results

To test our expectations, we run three models of party choice for economic and general performance evaluations. Instead of presenting regression tables, we simply show the effect of each variable on the predicted probability of voting for a specific party; regression tables with the exact results are shown in the Appendix ().

Starting with the economy, the panel on the left of shows the effect of retrospective economic evaluations on party choice. The two government parties between 2009 and 2013 were the CDU/CSU and the FDP, the three opposition parties were the SPD, the Greens and Die Linke. We see that the CDU/CSU is the only party in government that was rewarded when respondents assessed the economy positively. The effect of positive economic evaluations on the junior coalition partner, the FDP, is very low to non-existent. For the parties in the opposition, the impact of positive economic retrospective evaluations is negative and only statistically significant for the largest party, the SPD, and the extreme party, Die Linke. The panel on the right shows the effect of retrospective economic evaluations on all parties; in this case, respondents regard the government as responsible for the actual situation of the economy in Germany. The effect on government is strong; however, the reward for positive economic evaluations is enjoyed only by the CDU/CSU. Again, only the SPD and Die Linke are affected in the opposition. In addition, it is important to note that the negative effect on opposition parties is only significant at the lower levels of economic evaluations (below 0.5 in the graph), and only when there is responsibility attribution (right panels). In sum, a positive economic evaluation benefits the largest government party and it has a negative effect on the largest party in the opposition; but it has a rather low effect on all other parties, regardless of whether they are in government or opposition.

Figure 1. Retrospective economic voting for all parties.

Note: The graph shows the predicted probability of voting for a specific party based on Models 1 and 2, . Figures with confidence intervals can be found in the Online Supporting material.
Figure 1. Retrospective economic voting for all parties.

In the next two steps, we examine performance evaluations beyond the economy. An overview across all panels of clearly indicates that the more citizens are (dis)satisfied with a party, the more likely they are (not) to vote for it. A closer look at each panel tells a more interesting story. On the one hand, concerning the two big parties, there is an almost parallel yet opposite effect of their performance on the probability of voting for the other party, respectively. On the other hand, the impact of the evaluations of the smaller parties on the probability of voting for one of the largest parties is quite low. Moving to the smaller parties, we see that the evaluations of the large parties exert a rather strong effect, pulling voters towards both large parties until the overall performance evaluations of that specific small party reach a point of moderate positive evaluations. At this point, the effect of retrospective evaluations on vote choice is quite large and just a little below the effects we observe for larger parties. While it seems that party size matters in establishing which performance is taken into account when citizens cast a ballot, we see that both large and small parties suffer from performance evaluations.Footnote8 The results are very similar if we look at the 2009 election (in the Appendix), which ended four years of a grand coalition government between the CDU/CSU and SPD that allowed both parties to control key cabinet posts for the economy (see Williams, Stegmaier, and Debus Citation2015). A comparison of the two elections indicates that past performance evaluations influence coalition partners differently, although the SPD in 2009 is affected much more by retrospective evaluations than the FDP in 2013 due to its more dominant role in the party system.

Figure 2. Retrospective general evaluations and vote choice for all parties.

Note: The graph shows the predicted probability of voting for a specific party based on Models 3, . Figures with confidence intervals can be found in the Online Supporting material.
Figure 2. Retrospective general evaluations and vote choice for all parties.

In sum, we find that the accountability mechanism does not appear to simply be a matter of government approval or rejection, but that it works mainly at the party level. In line with recent contributions (Debus, Stegmaier, and Tosun Citation2014; Duch and Falcó-Gimeno Citation2014; Williams, Stegmaier, and Debus Citation2015), our findings indicate that future research should examine electoral accountability mechanisms at the party level rather than at the more abstract level of government versus opposition. Above all, our findings show that both government and opposition parties can expect credit and blame for their past performance, and that both large and small parties are exposed to the workings of the retrospective mechanism. While these findings complement previous results for the European Parliament elections (Marsh Citation2009; Weber Citation2011), they are more meaningful as they show that opposition parties are also subject to retrospective voting in first-order elections.

5. Discussion and conclusion

This paper’s main aim was to update our knowledge on the retrospective voting mechanism by testing the notion that this mechanism works at the party level. This effort stems from two contentions. First, the retrospective voting mechanism, focusing on whether voters support or do not support the government, clearly works much better in single-party governments when compared to coalition governments. Second, the widespread disregard for parliamentary opposition in performance voting literature is largely unjustified when we move from plurality to consensual democracy and from two-party systems to multi-party systems. On the first issue, our results show that retrospective evaluations have a stronger effect on the senior coalition partner compared to the junior partner. This corroborates recent findings in the literature which indicate that the effect of past performance evaluations influences coalition partners differently (Fisher and Hobolt Citation2010; Debus, Stegmaier, and Tosun Citation2014; Williams, Stegmaier, and Debus Citation2015).

On the second issue, the often unspoken assumption in the literature that performance voting is based solely on voters’ evaluations of the government parties’ past performance does not find support in our study. In fact, higher expectations concerning the competence to deliver seem to become most noticeable among all parties, regardless of their government status. It shows that the mechanisms of electoral accountability function slightly more sophisticatedly than previously assumed.

Overall, our findings suggest that government parties should not be the only ones concerned about the blaming aspect, since all parties can suffer from it. Rather, it is the voters’ rationale to hold their previously supported party accountable and this is a key requirement for representative democracy (Strøm Citation2000). Given the significant implications of democratic accountability, it is clearly worth exploring whether our findings also hold in other countries. Therefore, we finally suggest that national election studies should adapt their measurement tools on electoral accountability to the party level for future analyses. In addition, while the focus on policy performance at the party level is well grounded and important, it would be worth establishing why people are satisfied with the performance of a given party regarding aspects such as the ability to compromise or vice versa of keeping closely to their positions.

Supplemental material

JEPOP-2016-0037.R2_ONLINE_APPENDIX.docx

Download MS Word (274.6 KB)

Disclosure statement

No potential conflict of interest was reported by the authors.

Notes on contributors

Carolina Plescia is Assistant Professor in the Department of Government at the University of Vienna. She holds a Ph.D. in Political Science from Trinity College Dublin. Her main research interests are on comparative electoral behavior, coalition governments, representation and research methodologies.

Sylvia Kritzinger is Professor in the Department of Government at the University of Vienna. She is one of the principle investigators of the Austrian National Election Study. Sylvia Kritzinger holds a Ph.D. in Political Science from the University of Vienna. Her research focuses on Political Behaviour and Electoral Research, Democratic Representation and Political Participation.

Additional information

Funding

This work was supported by Austrian Science Fund [Grant Number S10902-G11].

Notes

1 Voters may also decide to exit the system altogether (e.g. Weber Citation2011). Our data provide us with full information about vote choice. However, exit was rarely chosen, and for this reason, we do not focus on abstention in this paper. This decision also stems from the fact that our results must balance each other out and as support for one party goes up, support for some other party needs to go down.

2 Some research has also investigated retrospective voting at the level of the individual Member of Parliament (MP) finding that policy accountability of MPs is rather weak (e.g. Vivyan and Wagner Citation2012).

3 Sampling was based on multi-level random sampling of a population comprising all German residents of a minimum age of 16 years. Both the 2009 and 2013 surveys were face-to-face surveys with standardized questionnaires (CAPI). It is known that panelists are not a random sample out of the initial cross-section sample of respondents (Frankel and Hillygus Citation201Citation4; Warren and Halpern-Manners Citation2012). To address this issue, we run additional tests (e.g. Heckman probit selection models) to check whether the findings are sensitive to sample selection bias. Accounting for sample selection bias confirms our substantive conclusions.

4 A possible alternative to a multinomial logit model would be to run a conditional logit model for the general performance models and thereby include only one performance indicator for each party-choice. We, however, decided to run multinomial logit models for both the economic evaluation and the general performance to have the same dependent variable in both sets of models and provide a more straightforward comparison.

5 German voters cast two votes, a proportional vote to choose national parties and a plurality vote to choose local candidates. In this paper, we rely on the former because we are interested in the national performance of parties. Note, however, that switching to the candidate vote leads to similar albeit weaker conclusions. This would be in line with the idea that voter knowledge regarding candidates is lower than that of parties (e.g. Pattie and Johnston Citation2004).

6 Some have argued that people’s perceptions of policy performance are shaped by their political orientation – notably partisanship (Wlezien, Franklin, and Twiggs Citation1997; Duch, Palmer, and Anderson Citation2000; Evans and Andersen Citation2006) – others (e.g. Lewis-Beck, Nadeau, and Elias Citation2008) have questioned this. To account for a possible perceptual bias, that is, voters who feel close to a political party are likely to evaluate its performance more positively through a “partisan lens”, our supporting material shows additional models in which retrospective evaluations have been interacted with partisanship, and models in which party identification has been excluded all together. The findings support our substantive conclusions. In the Online Supporting Material, we also include Table S3 containing a correlation matrix of all evaluations and party identification variables.

7 Strategic voting is an important aspect of voting behavior within the German context (Pappi and Thurner Citation2002; Gschwend Citation2007). Using a 0–10 sympathy scale, we build a dummy variable that takes a value of 1 if the party voted for is the voter’s most preferred party, and 0 otherwise. Our results are robust to the addition of this variable.

8 Party size might capture other party characteristics such as the effect of mainstream versus that of niche parties.

References

  • Anderson, C. J. 2000. “Economic Voting and Political Context: A Comparative Perspective.” Electoral Studies 19 (2): 151–170. doi: 10.1016/S0261-3794(99)00045-1
  • Anderson, C. J. 2007. “The End of Economic Voting? Contingency Dilemmas and the Limits of Democratic Accountability.” Annual Review of Political Science 10 (1): 271–296. doi: 10.1146/annurev.polisci.10.050806.155344
  • Bélanger, É. 2004. “Antipartyism and Third-party Vote Choice: A Comparison of Canada, Britain, and Australia.” Comparative Political Studies 37 (9): 1054–1078. doi: 10.1177/0010414004268847
  • Berry, C. R., and W. G. Howell. 2007. “Accountability and Local Elections: Rethinking Retrospective Voting.” The Journal of Politics 69 (3): 844–858. doi: 10.1111/j.1468-2508.2007.00579.x
  • Dassonneville, R., A. Blais, and Y. Dejaeghere. 2015. “Staying with the Party, Switching or Exiting? A Comparative Analysis of Determinants of Party Switching and Abstaining.” Journal of Elections, Public Opinion and Parties 25 (3): 387–405. doi: 10.1080/17457289.2015.1016528
  • Debus, M., M. Stegmaier, and J. Tosun. 2014. “Economic Voting under Coalition Governments: Evidence from Germany.” Political Science Research and Methods 2 (1): 49–67. doi: 10.1017/psrm.2013.16
  • De Vries, C. E., and N. Giger. 2014. “Holding Governments Accountable? Individual Heterogeneity in Performance Voting.” European Journal of Political Research 53 (2): 345–362. doi: 10.1111/1475-6765.12033
  • Duch, R. M., and A. Falcó-Gimeno. 2014. “Decision-making in Coalitions and the Economic Vote.” Paper presented at the 4th EPSA Conference, Edinburgh, June 19–21.
  • Duch, R. M., H. Palmer, and C. Anderson. 2000. “Heterogeneity in Perceptions of National Economic Conditions.” American Journal of Political Science 44 (4): 635–649. doi: 10.2307/2669272
  • Duch, R. M., and R. T. Stevenson. 2008. The Economic Vote: How Political and Economic Institutions Condition Election Results. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
  • Evans, G., and R. Anderson. 2006. “The Political Conditioning of Economic Perceptions.” The Journal of Politics 68 (1): 194–207. doi: 10.1111/j.1468-2508.2006.00380.x
  • Fiorina, M. P. 1981. Retrospective Voting in American National Elections. New Haven: Yale University Press.
  • Fisher, S. D., and S. B. Hobolt. 2010. “Coalition Government and Electoral Accountability.” Electoral Studies 29 (3): 358–369. doi: 10.1016/j.electstud.2010.03.003
  • Frankel, L. L., and D. S. Hillygus. 2014. “Looking Beyond Demographics: Panel Attrition in the ANES and GSS.” Political Analysis 22 (3): 336–353. doi: 10.1093/pan/mpt020
  • Gidengil, E., A. Blais, N. Nevitte, and R. Nadeau. 2001. “The Correlates and Consequences of Anti-partyism in the 1997 Canadian Election.” Party Politics 7 (4): 491–513. doi: 10.1177/1354068801007004005
  • Gschwend, T. 2007. “Ticket-splitting and Strategic Voting under Mixed Electoral Rules: Evidence from Germany.” European Journal of Political Research 46 (1): 1–23. doi: 10.1111/j.1475-6765.2006.00641.x
  • Hobolt, S. B., and J. Tilley. 2014. “Who’s in Charge? How Voters Attribute Responsibility in the European Union.” Comparative Political Studies 47 (6): 795–819. doi: 10.1177/0010414013488549
  • Hobolt, S. B., J. Tilley, and S. A. Banducci. 2013. “Clarity of Responsibility: How Government Cohesion Conditions Performance Voting.” European Journal of Political Research 52 (2): 164–187. doi: 10.1111/j.1475-6765.2012.02072.x
  • Lewis-Beck, M. S. 1991. “Introduction.” In Economics and Politics: The Calculus of Support, edited by H. Norpoth, M. S. Lewis-Beck, and J. D. Lafay, 1–8. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.
  • Lewis-Beck, M. S., R. Nadeau, and A. Elias. 2008. “Economics, Party, and the Vote: Causality Issues and Panel Data.” American Journal of Political Science 52 (1): 84–95. doi: 10.1111/j.1540-5907.2007.00300.x
  • Lijphart, A. 1999. Patterns of Democracy: Government Forms and Performance in Thirty-six Democracies. New Haven: Yale University Press.
  • Marsh, M. 2009. “Vote Switching in European Parliament Elections: Evidence from June 2004.” Journal of European Integration 31 (5): 627–644. doi: 10.1080/07036330903145898
  • Paldam, M. 1991. “How Robust is the Vote Function? A Study of Seventeen Nations Over Four Decades.” In Economics and Politics: The Calculus of Support, edited by H. Norpoth, M. S. Lewis-Beck, and J. D. Lafay, 9–30. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.
  • Pappi, F. U., and P. W. Thurner. 2002. “Electoral Behaviour in a Two-vote System: Incentives for Ticket Splitting in German Bundestag Elections.” European Journal of Political Research 41 (2): 207–232. doi: 10.1111/1475-6765.00010
  • Pattie, C., and R. Johnston. 2004. “Party Knowledge and Candidate Knowledge: Constituency Campaigning and Voting and the 1997 British General Election.” Electoral Studies 23 (4): 795–819. doi: 10.1016/j.electstud.2003.12.001
  • Powell, G., and G. Whitten. 1993. “A Cross-national Analysis of Economic Voting: Taking Account of the Political Context.” American Journal of Political Science 37 (2): 391–414. doi: 10.2307/2111378
  • Rattinger, H., S. Roßteutscher, R. Schmitt-Beck, B. Weßels, C. Wolf, T. Rudi, and J. E. Blumenstiel. 2014. Long-term Panel 2009-2013-2017 (GLES 2013). GESIS Data Archive, Cologne. ZA5322 Data file Version 1.0.0. doi:10.4232/1.12060.
  • Sanders, D., and S. Carey. 2003. “Temporal Variations.” In Economic Voting, edited by H. Dorussen and M. Taylor, 200–232. London: Routledge.
  • Singer, M. M. 2011. “Who Says “It’s the Economy”? Cross-national and Cross-individual Variation in the Salience of Economic Performance.” Comparative Political Studies 44 (3): 284–312. doi: 10.1177/0010414010384371
  • Strøm, K. 1990. Minority Government and Majority Rule. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
  • Strøm, K. 2000. “Delegation and Accountability in Parliamentary Democracies.” European Journal of Political Research 37 (3): 261–289.
  • Tilley, J., J. Garry, and T. Bold. 2008. “Perceptions and Reality: Economic Voting at the 2004 European Parliament Elections.” European Journal of Political Research 47 (5): 665–686. doi: 10.1111/j.1475-6765.2008.00780.x
  • Tilley, J., and S. B. Hobolt. 2011. “Is the Government to Blame? An Experimental Test of How Partisanship Shapes Perceptions of Performance and Responsibility.” The Journal of Politics 73 (2): 316–330. doi: 10.1017/S0022381611000168
  • Van der Brug, W., C. van der Eijk, and M. Franklin. 2007. The Economy and the Vote: Economic Conditions and Elections in Fifteen Countries. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
  • Vivyan, N., and M. Wagner. 2012. “Do Voters Reward Rebellion? The Electoral Accountability of MPs in Britain.” European Journal of Political Research 51 (2): 235–264. doi: 10.1111/j.1475-6765.2011.01998.x
  • Warren, J. R., and A. Halpern-Manners. 2012. “Panel Conditioning in Longitudinal Social Science Surveys.” Sociological Methods & Research 41 (4): 491–534. doi: 10.1177/0049124112460374
  • Weber, T. 2011. “Exit, Voice, and Cyclicality: A Micrologic of Midterm Effects in European Parliament Elections.” American Journal of Political Science 55 (4): 907–922. doi: 10.1111/j.1540-5907.2011.00535.x
  • Williams, L. K., M. Stegmaier, and M. Debus. 2015. “Relaxing the Constant Economic Vote Restriction Economic Evaluations and Party Support in Germany.” Party Politics. doi:10.1177/1354068815593458.
  • Wlezien, C., M. Franklin, and D. Twiggs. 1997. “Economic Perceptions and Vote Choice: Disentangling the Endogeneity.” Political Behavior 19 (1): 7–17. doi: 10.1023/A:1024841605168
  • Zelle, C. 1995. “Social Dealignment Versus Political Frustration: Contrasting Explanations of the Floating Vote in Germany.” European Journal of Political Research 27 (3): 319–345. doi: 10.1111/j.1475-6765.1995.tb00473.x

APPENDIX

Table A1. Models of vote choice: multinomial logit models (2013).

2009 Elections

Figure A1. Retrospective economic voting for all parties (2009).

Figure A1. Retrospective economic voting for all parties (2009).

Figure A2. Retrospective evaluations and vote choice for all parties (2009).

Figure A2. Retrospective evaluations and vote choice for all parties (2009).