1,275
Views
6
CrossRef citations to date
0
Altmetric
Research Article

Delay in budget allocation for vaccination and awareness induces chaos in an infectious disease model

, , &
Pages 395-429 | Received 11 Sep 2020, Accepted 28 Jun 2021, Published online: 14 Jul 2021

Abstract

In this paper, we propose a model to assess the impacts of budget allocation for vaccination and awareness programs on the dynamics of infectious diseases. The budget allocation is assumed to follow logistic growth, and its per capita growth rate increases proportional to disease prevalence. An increment in per-capita growth rate of budget allocation due to increase in infected individuals after a threshold value leads to onset of limit cycle oscillations. Our results reveal that the epidemic potential can be reduced or even disease can be eradicated through vaccination of high quality and/or continuous propagation of awareness among the people in endemic zones. We extend the proposed model by incorporating a discrete time delay in the increment of budget allocation due to infected population in the region. We observe that multiple stability switches occur and the system becomes chaotic on gradual increase in the value of time delay.

1. Introduction

Infectious diseases are major threat to mankind, and are responsible for hindrance in social and economic development of any country. Vaccination coverage is one of the most powerful and cost-effective intervention to reduce the prevalence of disease. It saves countless lives and prevents an estimated 2.5 million deaths each year caused by whooping cough, influenza, measles, etc., [Citation54]. The global health communities, such as Global Alliance of Vaccination and Immunization (GAVI), Bill & Melinda Gates Foundation, and other government and non-government organizations of various countries are making much efforts to make the vaccines accessible to all the people across the globe. These non-profitable organizations along with government provide funds for vaccination and awareness as the underprivileged people do not have sufficient amount of money to go for self-financed vaccination and also lack of awareness regarding the vaccination campaigns. As a result, they deprive from the health benefit provided by the government and thus are at the risk of infection during the infection period. The public perception of the possible risks and misconception associated with vaccination has led to reduction in MMR vaccine uptake, resulting the re-emergence of measles epidemic in the UK [Citation25]. In this regard, the global information campaigns via TV, radio and social media (accessible to most of the population) play a crucial role to convey the important health messages to unaware people and inform them how immunizations help to save their lives.

Several studies have been conducted to assess the impact of vaccination coverage to control the spread of infectious diseases [Citation4Citation6–8Citation11Citation14Citation26Citation27Citation41Citation45Citation51Citation52Citation55]. The combined effects of education, vaccination and treatment are proven to be more effective to reduce the prevalence of HIV in comparison to the case when only one of them is applied [Citation11]. Agaba et al. [Citation1] have investigated the role of vaccination on the dynamics of infectious disease in presence of global information campaigns regarding the disease prevalence as well as local awareness due to direct interaction between unaware and aware individuals. It is observed that the delay in response to available information about the disease leads to destabilization of endemic state and the periodic oscillations arise. Their findings suggest that vaccination coverage in the presence of awareness is helpful to reduce the size of epidemic.

Although vaccination coverage is crucial for public health (as it triggers the immune response by developing antibodies), the awareness programs through TV, radio (a cost-effective and responsive medium in remote areas) and social media are also helpful in reducing the disease transmission by alerting the people to adopt practices that are requisite for disease prevention, such as go for vaccination, adopt sanitation practices, use of face mask, etc. The implementation of effective control strategies is beneficial to suppress the burden of disease. For instance, Guinea worm disease is eradicated only through proper program implementation strategies [Citation18]. Some mathematical studies are carried out to see the impact of awareness for the control of disease transmission. Authors considered media as a dynamic variable and assumed that awareness programs increase with the increase in the number of infected individuals [Citation15Citation24Citation32Citation34Citation37Citation38Citation43Citation44Citation46Citation48Citation50] or transmission rate decreases with the increase in infected individuals due to awareness [Citation2Citation10Citation30Citation40Citation47Citation49]. In [Citation38], the effect of behavioural changes induced by information campaigns for the control of infectious diseases by considering prevalence-dependent information campaigns is investigated. The study reveals that optimal media campaigns are effective and economical to control an epidemic. The findings of Huo et al. [Citation24] suggested that media serves as a good indicator during an epidemic outbreak and is helpful in reducing the disease burden. Misra and Rai [Citation33] have shown that the broadcastings via TV and radio regarding the control mechanisms are beneficial to reduce the spread of infectious diseases. The global information campaigns through TV, radio and social media encourage people to adopt preventive measures at the early stage of epidemic outbreak that helps to suppress the burden of disease. The other key tools to prevent a disease are medical health facilities, public health responses, health infrastructures, public education, vaccination coverage, etc. On the other hand, media has some negative effects as well. For example, the negative effects of media at the time of the plague outbreak in India during 1994 largely affected tourism and other businesses [Citation13]. The epicentre of plague was Surat, Gujarat; in total, 52 people died. Although, the plague lasted in two weeks but a large number of people left the city due to media-induced panic.

Some mathematical models are also proposed to assess the effect of time delay in implementation of awareness programs [Citation1Citation3Citation20Citation35Citation36]. It is observed that such time lag destabilizes the system via Hopf-bifurcation. Basir et al. [Citation3] have investigated the role of awareness programs on the control of infectious diseases. They observed that the incorporation of time delay in implementation of information campaigns and/or response of unaware (aware) susceptible individuals to become aware (unaware) destabilizes the system and periodic oscillations arise through Hopf-bifurcation. Their study shows that media campaigns influence the patterns of disease and also help to reduce the risk of infection. Misra et al. [Citation35] have also studied a nonlinear mathematical model to see how the introduction of delay in per-capita growth rate of budget allocation changes the dynamics of system. They observed that the propagation of awareness reduces the disease burden but the delay in providing funds destabilizes the system and may cause stability switches through Hopf-bifurcation. Their findings suggest that the continuous and timely allocation of funds are beneficial to reduce the disease prevalence.

Rai et al. [Citation43] have explored the combined actions of awareness and sanitation on the spread of infectious diseases. Their findings revealed that the sanitation and awareness programs have capability to reduce the epidemic threshold, and thus control the spread of infection. In the present paper, we investigate the impacts of vaccination coverage and information campaigns on the control of disease prevalence. Our model is different from the model proposed by Rai et al. [Citation43] in the following sense. In the present study, our goal is to assess the joint impacts of vaccination (a powerful and cost-effective intervention to protect the people against contracting the disease) and non-pharmaceutical interventions such as frequent hand washing, use of face mask, sanitizer, maintain social distancing, etc., induced by the information campaigns to control infectious diseases, which spread in the population through the direct contact with infected individuals, such as influenza, measles, etc., in the presence of budget allocation. On the other hand, Rai et al. [Citation43] have explicitly incorporated the combined effects of sanitation coverage (a rational step for the control of bacteria present in the environment) and awareness programs through budget allocation for the control of infectious diseases, such as typhoid fever which spreads in the population through the direct contact of susceptible with infected individuals as well as indirectly through bacteria present in the environment. Here, our aim is to explore whether disease can be eliminated by vaccination coverage and/or awareness programs. We also investigate the impact of time delay involved in the increment in budget allocation due to increased number of infected individuals.

The rest of the paper is arranged as follows: in the next section, we propose our model. In Section 3, we obtain equilibria of the system and study their stability behaviour. We find expression for the basic reproduction number, and investigate the direction of bifurcation whenever basic reproduction number is unity. Existence of Hopf-bifurcation is discussed with respect to the per-capita growth rate of budget allocation due to increased population of infectives; we also determine the conditions for direction and stability of bifurcating periodic solutions. In Section 4, we extend our model by considering the effect of time delay in the increments in budget allocation due to increased infected population. The delay system is analysed in the following section. We simulate our delay and non-delay systems in Section 6. Section 7 contains our conclusion.

2. Mathematical model

In the region under consideration, let N(t) be the total population at any time t>0, which is divided into three sub-populations: susceptible individuals S(t), infected individuals I(t) and vaccinated individuals V(t). Further, we denote by M(t), the budget allocation by the government for vaccination and awareness in the region at time t. In the modelling process, it is assumed that the growth rate of budget allocation regarding the protection against the disease follows the logistic growth with intrinsic growth rate r and carrying capacity K, and its per-capita growth rate increases in proportion to the number of infected individuals. It is assumed that the population is homogeneously mixed and the susceptible individuals contract the infection through the direct contact with infected individuals at the contact rate β. The interaction between susceptible and infected individuals is assumed to follow the simple law of mass action.

We assume that k1 fraction of the total allocated budget M (i.e. k1M, 0<k1<1) is used to warn people via propagating awareness regarding the risk of infection and its control mechanisms. As a result, the individuals change their behaviours and use precautionary measures during the infection period. Thus, the direct contact between susceptible and infected individuals decreases at a factor f1(M)=β1k1Mp+k1M. The reason behind considering this saturated type of functional response is that the amount of funds used to propagate awareness has limited impact to reduce the possibility of contracting the infection [Citation30]. Due to this, the effective contact between susceptible and infected individuals becomes β(M)=ββ1k1Mp+k1M. Further, the remaining part of budget, i.e. (1k1)M is used for vaccination coverage; the effective vaccination rate of susceptible individuals in the presence of budget is f2(M)=ϕ(1k1)Mq+(1k1)M. Again, a saturated type of functional response is considered here because of the cost and efficacy of the vaccines. Moreover, the vaccine is not fully effective and it wears off after certain period of time. After recovery, the infected individuals are assumed to join the susceptible class again. Individuals in each class have natural mortality while the individuals in the infected class also experience disease induced death.

In view of above assumptions, a schematic diagram for the proposed system is depicted in Figure , and the model equations are written as follows: (1) dSdt=Λββ1k1Mp+k1MSIϕ(1k1)Mq+(1k1)MS+νI+δVdS,dIdt=ββ1k1Mp+k1MSI(ν+α+d)I,dVdt=ϕ(1k1)Mq+(1k1)MS(δ+d)V,dMdt=rM1MK+θIM.(1) The initial conditions are assumed as, S(0)>0,I(0)0, V(0)0, M(0)0.For the feasibility of system (Equation1), we must have β1<β. All the parameters involved in system (Equation1) are assumed to be positive, and their descriptions are given in Table .

Figure 1. Schematic diagram for systems (Equation1) and (Equation16). Here, red colour denotes the impact of budget allocation in reducing the transmission rate by making people aware about the disease whereas blue colour stands for the utilization of budget on vaccinating the susceptible individuals; time delay involved in per-capita growth rate of budget allocation due to increase in infected individuals is represented by cyan colour.

Figure 1. Schematic diagram for systems (Equation1(1) dSdt=Λ−β−β1k1Mp+k1MSI−ϕ(1−k1)Mq+(1−k1)MS+νI+δV−dS,dIdt=β−β1k1Mp+k1MSI−(ν+α+d)I,dVdt=ϕ(1−k1)Mq+(1−k1)MS−(δ+d)V,dMdt=rM1−MK+θIM.(1) ) and (Equation16(16) dIdt=β−β1k1Mp+k1M(N−I−V)I−(ν+α+d)I,dVdt=ϕ(1−k1)Mq+(1−k1)M(N−I−V)−(δ+d)V,dNdt=Λ−dN−αI,dMdt=rM1−MK+θI(t−τ)M.(16) ). Here, red colour denotes the impact of budget allocation in reducing the transmission rate by making people aware about the disease whereas blue colour stands for the utilization of budget on vaccinating the susceptible individuals; time delay involved in per-capita growth rate of budget allocation due to increase in infected individuals is represented by cyan colour.

Table 1. Descriptions of parameters involved in system (Equation1).

As S + I + V = N, system (Equation1) reduces to following equivalent system: (2) dIdt=ββ1k1Mp+k1M(NIV)I(ν+α+d)I,dVdt=ϕ(1k1)Mq+(1k1)M(NIV)(δ+d)V,dNdt=ΛdNαI,dMdt=rM1MK+θIM.(2) Now onwards, we study the dynamics of system (Equation2) in detail.

Lemma 2.1

The following set contains the region of attraction for the system (Equation2) with initial conditions I(0)0, V(0)0, N(0)>0 and M(0)0, and attracts all solutions initiating in the interior of positive orthant: Ω=(I,V,N,M)R+4: 0I,VNΛd, 0MKrr+θΛd=Mr.

3. Mathematical analysis of system (2)

3.1. Equilibrium analysis

System (Equation2) exhibits four non-negative equilibria, which are listed as follows.

  1. The disease and budget-free equilibrium (DBFE) E1=(0,0,Λ/d,0), which always exists.

  2. The budget-free endemic equilibrium (BFEE) E2=(I2,0,N2,0), where (3) I2=βΛd(ν+α+d)β(α+d),N2=βΛ+α(ν+α+d)β(α+d).(3) The equilibrium E2 exists provided R0>1, where (4) R0=βΛd(ν+α+d).(4)

  3. The disease-free equilibrium (DFE) E3=(0,V3,Λ/d,K), where V3=ϕΛd(1k1)Kq+(1k1)Kϕ(1k1)Kq+(1k1)K+δ+d1.This equilibrium always exists.

  4. The interior equilibrium (IE) E=(I,V,N,M), where the values of I, V, N and M are positive solutions of the equilibrium equations of system (Equation2).

    From the third equilibrium equation of system (Equation2), we get (5) N=ΛαId.(5) From the last equilibrium equation of system (Equation2), we have (6) M=Kr(r+θI).(6) We have, (7) g(I)=(1k1)Mq+(1k1)M=(1k1)K(r+θI)qr+(1k1)K(r+θI).(7) Note that, g(I)=qr(1k1)Kθ[qr+(1k1)K(r+θI)]2>0.Using Equations (Equation5)–(Equation7) in the second equilibrium equation of system (Equation2), we get (8) V=ϕg(I){Λ(α+d)I}d{ϕg(I)+δ+d}.(8) Now, using Equations (Equation5), (Equation6) and (Equation8) in the first equilibrium equation of system (Equation2), we get (9) F(I)=ββ1k1K(r+θI)pr+k1K(r+θI)(δ+d){Λ(α+d)I}d{ϕg(I)+δ+d}(ν+α+d)=0.(9) Form Equation (Equation9), we observe that

    1. F(0)=ββ1k1Kp+k1KΛ(δ+d)dϕ(1k1)Kq+(1k1)K+δ+d1(ν+α+d),which is positive provided Rav>1, where Rav is defined in (Equation10).

    2. FΛα+d=(ν+α+d)<0.

    3. F(I)<0 for all I0,Λα+d.

    Thus, F(I)=0 has a unique positive root, say I in the open interval 0,Λα+d provided Rav>1. Now, using this positive value of I=I in Equations (Equation5), (Equation6) and (Equation8), we can obtain the positive values of N, M and V, respectively.

3.2. Basic reproduction number

To obtain the basic reproduction number (Rav) of model system (Equation2), we use next generation matrix approach [Citation12]. The new infection terms (F(x)) and transition terms (V(x)) of system (Equation2) are, respectively, given by F(x)=ββ1k1Mp+k1M(NIV)I000,V(x)=(ν+α+d)Iϕ(1k1)Mq+(1k1)M(NIV)+(δ+d)VΛ+dN+αIrM1MKθIM.The Jacobian matrix of F(x) and V(x) at the disease-free equilibrium E3 is obtained as, F=ββ1k1Kp+k1KΛdδ+dϕ(1k1)Kq+(1k1)K+δ+d000000000000000,V=0ϕ(1k1)qΛd(q+(1k1)K)2ϕ(1k1)Kq+(1k1)K+δ+d0rν+α+d00ϕ(1k1)Kq+(1k1)Kϕ(1k1)Kq+(1k1)K+δ+dϕ(1k1)Kq+(1k1)Kα0dθK000ϕ(1k1)qΛd(q+(1k1)K)2ϕ(1k1)Kq+(1k1)K+δ+d0r.Therefore, the basic reproduction number Rav=max{|ψ|:ψρ(FV1)} is spectral radius of the matrix FV1 and is obtained as, (10) Rav=ββ1k1Kp+k1KΛ(δ+d)d(ν+α+d)ϕ(1k1)Kq+(1k1)K+δ+d1.(10)

Remark 3.1

The quantity R0 is known as basic reproduction number in the absence of budget, which is defined as the number of secondary infectives produced by an infected individual during his/her whole infectious period in entirely susceptible population. The equilibrium E2 captures the dynamics of simple SIS model with immigration in the absence of vaccination and awareness through budget allocation. In the absence of funds if R0>1, there exists a unique budget-free endemic equilibrium, i.e. infection persists in the population if on average an infected individual infects more than one susceptible individuals during his/her whole infectious period. Allocation of budget to warn people and vaccination coverage reduces the epidemic threshold. Note that Rav<R0, emphasizing the role of vaccination coverage and awareness to control the spread of disease. From the expressions of R0 and Rav, it may be observed that the combined effects of vaccination and awareness through budget allocation are helpful in reducing the epidemic threshold.

Remark 3.2

We note that dIdk1<0 provided H1H2=ϕqββ1k1K(r+θI)pr+k1K(r+θI){qr+(1k1)K(r+θI)}{qr(δ+d)+(ϕ+δ+d)(1k1)K(r+θI)}β1p(pr+k1K(r+θI))2ϕqββ1k1K(r+θI)pr+k1K(r+θI){qr+(1k1)K(r+θI)}{qr(δ+d)+(ϕ+δ+d)(1k1)K(r+θI)}>0.This implies that the equilibrium number of infected individuals decreases as the budget allocation to warn people via propagating awareness (k1) increases. Further, we find that dIdk1>0, i.e. dId(1k1)<0 if H1H2<0. This tells that with increments in the budget allocation for vaccination coverage, the equilibrium number of infected individuals decline.

3.3. Local stability analysis

The local stability conditions of equilibria E1, E2, E3 and E are stated in the following theorem.

Theorem 3.1

  1. The equilibrium E1 is always feasible and unstable.

  2. The equilibrium E2 is feasible if R0>1 and is unstable.

  3. The equilibrium E3 is always feasible and is locally asymptotically stable if Rav<1, whereas it is unstable if Rav>1.

  4. The equilibrium E is feasible if Rav>1 and is locally asymptotically stable provided the following condition holds (11) A3(A1A2A3)A12A4>0,(11) where Ai's are defined in the proof.

For proof of this theorem, see Appendix 1.

3.4. Direction of bifurcation at Rav=1

From Theorem 3.1, it is clear that if we consider Rav as a bifurcation parameter, then at Rav=1 there is an exchange of stability properties between the equilibria E3 and E. This is a clear indication of the presence of a transcritical bifurcation when Rav=1. In order to investigate the nature of bifurcation involving equilibrium E3 at Rav=1, we employ central manifold theory [Citation9].

On introducing the new variables, x1=I, x2=V, x3=N, x4=M and β as a bifurcation parameter, the model system (Equation2) can be written as: (12) dx1dt=ββ1k1x4p+k1x4(x3x2x1)x1(ν+α+d)x1,dx2dt=ϕ(1k1)x4q+(1k1)x4(x3x2x1)(δ+d)x2,dx3dt=Λdx3αx1,dx4dt=rx41x4K+θx1x4.(12) At Rav=1, we note that β=β=β1k1Kp+k1K+d(ν+α+d)Λ(δ+d)ϕ(1k1)Kq+(1k1)K+δ+dand the disease-free equilibrium of the model system (Equation2) is x0=(x10,x20,x30,x40)=0,ϕΛ(1k1)Kq+(1k1)Kdϕ(1k1)Kq+(1k1)K+δ+d,Λd,K.The linearized matrix of the model system (Equation12) around the disease-free equilibrium x0 at β=β is Jx0(β)=0ϕ(1k1)qΛ(δ+d)d(q+(1k1)K)2ϕ(1k1)Kq+(1k1)K+δ+d0r000ϕ(1k1)Kq+(1k1)Kϕ(1k1)Kq+(1k1)K+δ+dϕ(1k1)Kq+(1k1)Kα0dθK000ϕ(1k1)qΛ(δ+d)d(q+(1k1)K)2ϕ(1k1)Kq+(1k1)K+δ+d0r.Note that Jx0(β) has an eigenvalue zero when Rav=1, and it is a simple eigenvalue and all other eigenvalues are negative. The right eigenvector corresponding to zero eigenvalue at (x0,β) is denoted by w=(w1,w2,w3,w4)T, where w1=1,w2=1ϕ(1k1)Kq+(1k1)K+δ+dθKrϕ(1k1)qΛ(δ+d)d(q+(1k1)K)2ϕ(1k1)Kq+(1k1)K+δ+d1+αdϕ(1k1)Kq+(1k1)Kϕ(1k1)qΛ(δ+d)d(q+(1k1)K)2ϕ(1k1)Kq+(1k1)K+δ+d,w3=αd, w4=θKr.Further, the left eigenvector of Jx0(β) corresponding to zero eigenvalue satisfying wTv=1 is given by v=(v1,v2,v3,v4)T, where v1=1, v2=0, v3=0, v4=0.

To determine the local dynamics of system (Equation12), we apply the result of Theorem 4.1 given in [Citation9]. For this, we calculate the values of a=k,i,j=14vkwiwj2fkxixj(x0,β),b=k,i=14vkwi2fkxiβ(x0,β).After algebraic manipulations, we get (13) a=2(δ+d)ββ1k1Kp+k1Kϕ(1k1)Kq+(1k1)K+δ+dϕ(1k1)qΛθKrd(q+(1k1)K)2ϕ(1k1)Kq+(1k1)K+δ+d+1+αd+β1k1pΛθKrd(p+k1K)2ββ1k1Kp+k1K,b=Λdδ+dϕ(1k1)Kq+(1k1)K+δ+d.(13) The previous considerations allow us to state the following theorem.

Theorem 3.2

Consider model (Equation2) and let a and b as given by (Equation13), where a<0 and b>0. The local dynamics of system (Equation2) around the equilibrium E3 can be stated as ‘when Rav<1 with Rav1, the equilibrium E3 is locally asymptotically stable, and there exists a negative unstable equilibrium E; when Rav>1 with Rav1, the equilibrium E3 is unstable, and there exists a positive locally asymptotically stable equilibrium E’. That is, at Rav=1, system (Equation2) undergoes a supercritical (or forward) bifurcation.

Proof.

It follows from [Citation9] Theorem 4.1 pp. 373, and Remark 1 pp. 375.

3.5. Global stability

In this section, we present the result of global stability of the interior equilibrium E using the Lyapunov's direct method by defining a suitable scalar valued positive definite function known as Lyapunov's function. In order to show the global stability of equilibrium E, we have the following theorem.

Theorem 3.3

The interior equilibrium E, if feasible, is globally asymptotically stable in the region Ω, if the following conditions hold. (14) β1k1Λd(p+k1M)<r3Kθββ1k1Mp+k1M,(14) (15) ϕ(1k1)Mϕ(1k1)M+(δ+d)(q+(1k1)M)2<14min14,dα,m3r3Kp+k1Mβp+(ββ1)k1MdMΛ2.(15)

For proof of this theorem, see Appendix 2.

Remark 3.3

From condition (Equation14), we may note that the per-capita growth rate of budget allocation due to prevalence of disease (θ) may have destabilizing effect over the system. It is observed that on increasing the value of θ, the local stability condition (Equation11) is violated. Thus, there is possibility of Hopf-bifurcation as the value of θ crosses a threshold value and interior equilibrium becomes unstable, which leads to onset of periodic oscillations.

3.6. Existence of Hopf-bifurcation

In this section, we show the existence of Hopf-bifurcation around the interior equilibrium E by taking per capita growth rate of budget allocation due to increase in infected individuals (θ) as a bifurcation parameter, keeping remaining parameters fixed. In this regard, we have the following theorem.

Theorem 3.4

System (Equation2) undergoes Hopf-bifurcation around the interior equilibrium E if there exists θ=θc such that,

  1. A3(θc)(A1(θc)A2(θc)A3(θc))A12(θc)A4(θc)=0,

  2. ddθ(A3(A1A2A3)A12A4)θ=θc0

and all other eigenvalues have negative real parts.

For proof of this theorem, see Appendix 3.

3.7. Stability and direction of Hopf-bifurcation

In this section, we state the result for the direction and stability of bifurcating periodic solutions around the interior equilibrium E. In this regard, we have the following theorem [Citation23].

Theorem 3.5

  1. The Hopf-bifurcation is supercritical or subcritical if μ2>0 or μ2<0, and the bifurcating periodic solutions exist for θ>θc or θ<θc.

  2. The bifurcating periodic solutions are stable or unstable according to β2<0 or β2>0.

  3. The period of the bifurcating periodic solutions increases or decreases according to T2>0 or T2<0.

Following the similar procedure as described in [Citation23Citation34], we can prove above theorem.

4. Effect of time delay in per-capita growth rate of budget allocation

In model system (Equation2), it is assumed that the per-capita growth rate of budget allocation for vaccination and awareness programme is proportional to the number of infected individuals at present. However, it may be noted that the number of infected individuals reported to government may be sometimes old and increment in the per-capita growth rate of budget allocation for vaccination and awareness programs depends upon these data, which leads to incorporation of intrinsic time delay in per-capita growth rate of budget allocation due to increase in infected individuals. In order to address this, we have considered that at time t, the per-capita growth rate of budget allotted to warn people and for vaccination coverage is in accordance with number of infected individuals reported at time tτ (for some τ>0). Under this consideration, system (Equation2) takes the following form: (16) dIdt=ββ1k1Mp+k1M(NIV)I(ν+α+d)I,dVdt=ϕ(1k1)Mq+(1k1)M(NIV)(δ+d)V,dNdt=ΛdNαI,dMdt=rM1MK+θI(tτ)M.(16) Initial conditions for system (Equation16) takes the form (17) I(φ)=ξ11(φ),V(φ)=ξ12(φ), N(φ)=ξ13(φ), M(φ)=ξ14(φ), τφ0,(17) where ξ1=(ξ11,ξ12,ξ13,ξ14)C+ such that ξ1i(φ)0, i=1,2,3,4  φ[τ,0] and C+([τ,0],R+04) be the Banach space of continuous functions mapping the interval [τ,0] into R+04. Denote norm of an element ξ1C+ by ξ1=sup{|ξ11(φ)|,|ξ12(φ)|,|ξ13(φ)|,|ξ14(φ)|}, τφ0.

5. Stability analysis in the presence of time delay

First, we linearized the model system (Equation16) about the equilibrium E by using the transformations I=I+i(t), V=V+v(t), N=N+n(t) and M=M+m(t). The linearized system about the equilibrium E is given as follows: (18) dYdt=M1Y(t)+M2Y(tτ),(18) where M1=m11m12m13m14m21(m21+δ+d)m23m24α0d0000rKM,M2=000000000000θM000, Y()=i()v()n()m(),with m11=m12=m13=ββ1k1Mp+k1MI,m14=β1k1p(NIV)I(p+k1M)2m21=m23=ϕ(1k1)Mq+(1k1)M,m24=ϕ(1k1)q(NIV){q+(1k1)M}2.Here, i(t), v(t), n(t) and m(t) are small perturbations around the equilibrium E.

The characteristic equation for the linearized system (Equation18) is obtained as, (19) D(ζ,τ)=ζ4+p1ζ3+p2ζ2+p3ζ+p4+(q0ζ2+q1ζ+q2)eζτ=0,(19) where p1=m11+m21+δ+2d+rMK,p2=m11(α+δ+2d)+d(m21+δ+d)+rMK(m11+m21+δ+2d),p3=m11(α+d)(δ+d)+rMK[m11(α+δ+2d)+d(m21+δ+d)],p4=m11(α+d)(δ+d)rMK,q0=θMm14, q1=θM{m11m24+m14(m21+δ+2d)},q2=dθM{m11m24+m14(m21+δ+d)}.As equation (Equation19) is transcendental in ζ, it would have infinitely many complex roots. The local stability of the interior equilibrium E will be determined by the signs of real parts of the roots of Equation (Equation19), which is complicated in the presence of delay as for τ>0, it has infinitely many roots. By Rouche's theorem and continuity in τ, sign of roots of Equation  (Equation19) will change if the principal pair of roots cross the imaginary axis, i.e.Equation (Equation19) has purely imaginary roots. Hence, putting ζ=iω (ω>0) in Equation (Equation19), and separating real and imaginary part, we have (20) ω4p2ω2+p4=q1ωsin(ωτ)(q2q0ω2)cos(ωτ),(20) (21) p1ω3p3ω=q1ωcos(ωτ)(q2q0ω2)sin(ωτ).(21) On squaring and adding Equations (Equation20) and (Equation21), and substituting ω2=η, we get the following equation (22) H(η)η4+C1η3+C2η2+C3η+C4=0,(22) where C1=p122p2,C2=p222p1p3+2p4q02,C3=p322p2p4q12+2q0q2, C4=p42q22.Now, we discuss the nature of roots of fourth degree polynomial equation in following cases.

H1: If all the coefficients Ci's (i=1,2,3,4) in H(η) are positive.

By Descartes' rule of signs, Equation (Equation22) has no positive real root. Thus, the characteristic equation (Equation19) has no pair of purely imaginary roots for any τ>0. Thus, all the roots of Equation (Equation19) lie in the left half of complex plane in the presence of delay (i.e. τ>0). In view of this, we have the following theorem.

Theorem 5.1

If condition (H1) is satisfied, then the interior equilibrium E, if feasible, is locally asymptotically stable for all τ>0 provided it is stable for τ=0.

H2: If not all the coefficients Ci's (i=1,2,3,4) of Equation (Equation22) are positive.

Using Descartes' rule of signs, we have following conditions in which Equation  (Equation22) has a unique positive real root: (D1) C1>0,C2>0, C3>0, C4<0.(D2) C1>0,C2>0, C3<0, C4<0.(D3) C1>0,C2<0, C3<0, C4<0.(D4) C1<0,C2<0, C3<0, C4<0.If any of the conditions Di (i=1,2,3,4) is satisfied, then Equation (Equation19) has pair of purely imaginary roots ±iω0. Thus, corresponding to positive values of ω0, from transcendental Equations (Equation20) and (Equation21), we have tan(ω0τ)=Θ1Θ2,where Θ1=(ω04p2ω02+p4)q1ω0+(p1ω03p3ω0)(q2q0ω02),Θ2=(ω04p2ω02+p4)(q2q0ω02)q1ω0(p1ω03p3ω0).Thus, the value of τk corresponding to positive values of ω0 may be obtained as follows: τk=kπω0+1ω0tan1Θ1Θ2,for k=0,1,2,3,.

Regarding transversality condition, we have the following lemma.

Lemma 5.2

Suppose (H2) holds, then the following transversality condition is satisfied: sgnRedζdττ=τ0>0.

Following the similar procedure as described in [Citation35Citation43], we can prove this lemma.

Now, we have the following result.

Theorem 5.3

If the condition (Equation11) holds and any of the conditions (Di) (i = 1−4) is satisfied, the interior equilibrium E is locally asymptotically stable for τ[0,τ0) and becomes unstable for τ>τ0. The model system (Equation16) undergoes supercritical Hopf-bifurcation when τ=τ0, yielding family of periodic solutions bifurcating from the equilibrium E as τ crosses a threshold value τ0 [Citation19].

Remark 5.1

If none of the conditions (Di) (i = 1, 2, 3, 4) holds, then Equation (Equation22) may have more than one positive real roots. As a result, Equation (Equation19) may have more than one pair of purely imaginary roots and the system may posses a finite number of stability switches as delay parameter τ increases.

H3: Analytically, it is not easy to find the exact condition in which Equation  (Equation22) has two positive real roots, i.e. Equation (Equation19) has two pairs of purely imaginary roots. So, we discuss the result numerically in which Equation (Equation22) has two positive real roots. Numerically, it is obtained that Equation (Equation22) has two positive real roots η+ (corresponding to ω+2) and η (corresponding to ω2) where η+>η, i.e. the characteristic equation (Equation19) has two pairs of purely imaginary roots ±iω±. For these positive values of ω±, from transcendental equations (Equation20) and (Equation21), we obtain positive values of τk± as follows: (23) τk±=(2k+1)πω±+1ω±tan1(ω±4p2ω±2+p4)q1ω±+(p1ω±3p3ω±)(q2q0ω±2)(ω±4p2ω±2+p4)(q2q0ω±2)q1ω±(p1ω±3p3ω±),(23) for k=0,1,2,. Using Buttler's lemma [Citation16], we can say that the equilibrium E of model system (Equation16) remains stable for τ<τk+ and unstable for τ<τk.

Now, we explore whether the Hopf-bifurcation occurs or not as τ passes through τk±. For this, we have the following lemma.

Lemma 5.4

If Equation (Equation22) has two positive real roots, then the following transversality conditions are satisfied: sgnRedζdττ=τk+>0,sgnRedζdττ=τk<0.

Following the similar procedure as described in [Citation35Citation43], we can prove this lemma.

Thus, in connection with Hopf-bifurcation of functional differential equation [Citation28], we have the following theorem.

Theorem 5.5

If Equation (Equation22) has two positive real roots and condition (Equation11) is satisfied, then there exists a positive integer m such that there are m switches from stability to instability and eventually the system (Equation16) becomes unstable. More precisely, if τ[0,τ0+), (τ0,τ1+), (τ1,τ2+),,(τm1,τm+), the equilibrium E is stable while it is unstable for τ(τ0+,τ0), (τ1+,τ1),,(τm1+,τm1).

6. Numerical simulation

Here, we present numerical simulations of systems (Equation1) and (Equation16) by taking hypothetical parameter values chosen within the ranges prescribed in the previous published papers [Citation17Citation29Citation35Citation43]. Unless otherwise mentioned, the parameter values are given in Table . For this set of parameter values, the condition for the feasibility of interior equilibrium E (i.e. Rav>1) and stability condition (Equation11) are satisfied. The components of the interior equilibrium E are obtained as, I=338.7390,V=23469.2294, N=48306.3048, M=669.3695.The eigenvalues of Jacobian matrix evaluated at interior equilibrium E for the system (Equation2) are obtained as 0.65939, 0.01031±0.00613i and 0.00006; two eigenvalues are negative whereas the other two eigenvalues are with negative real parts, which shows that the interior equilibrium E is locally asymptotically stable. The basic reproduction number in the absence of budget is found to be R0=3.53 whereas the basic reproduction number in the presence of budget is Rav=1.13, showing that the epidemic threshold decreases in the presence of vaccination and awareness through budget allocation. As Rav>1, disease always persists in the system. Further, for the parameter values given in Table , the critical values of β1 and ϕ are, respectively, found to be β1c=0.000014 and ϕc=0.005089. Thus, there is possibility of disease eradication only if Rav<1 which can be achieved for β1>β1c or ϕ>ϕc. Therefore, the control measures must focus to reach the latter goal.

6.1. Sensitivity analysis

We determine normalized forward sensitivity indices of Rav, β1c and ϕc to see the influence of model parameters on Rav, β1c and ϕc [Citation44]. The normalized forward sensitivity index of variable to a parameter is a ratio of the relative change in the variable to relative change in the parameter, i.e. the normalized forward sensitivity index of a variable γ that depends differentially on a parameter δ is defined as: Xδγ=γδ×δγ [Citation31]. We fix α=0.02 and keep rest of the parameters at the same values as in Table . In Figure (a–c), we plot the normalized forward sensitivity indices to each parameter involved in the expressions of Rav, β1c and ϕc, respectively. From these figures, it may be noted that the values of Rav, β1c and ϕc increase with increase in the values of the parameters Λ, β and δ as these parameters have positive indices with Rav, β1c and ϕc. On the other hand, from Figure (a), it is evident that the parameters β1, ϕ, K, ν, α and d possess negative indices with Rav. In Figure (b), the parameters having negative indices with β1c are ϕ, K, ν, α and d whereas from Figure (c), it is easy to note that the parameters having negative indices with ϕc are β1, K, ν, α and d. The increment in parameters having negative indices result in decline in the values of Rav, β1c and ϕc. From Figure (a–c), we observe that the parameter β is most sensitive for Rav, β1c and ϕc. The sensitivity indices give that increase in the parameter β by 1% will result in 1.67%, 2.29% and 3.33% increase in the values of Rav, β1c and ϕc, respectively. Note that our objective is to prefer the lower values of Rav, β1c and ϕc as they enhance the possibility of disease eradication. Therefore, increment in parameters β, Λ and δ must be preventable by all means, while increase in β1, ϕ, K, ν, α, d should instead be favoured. Thus, for disease eradication, any external measures by government officials and policy makers must focus to prevent an increase in the parameters having positive indices with basic reproduction number (Rav ), critical threshold of efficacy of budget allocation to reduce the contact rate via propagating awareness (β1c) and critical threshold of vaccination rate among susceptible individuals in the presence of budget allocation (ϕc) whereas the parameter having negative indices should be stimulated by all means.

Figure 2. Normalized forward sensitivity indices of (a) Rav, (b) β1c and (c) ϕc with respect to model parameters. Parameters are at the same values as in Table  except α=0.02.

Figure 2. Normalized forward sensitivity indices of (a) Rav, (b) β1c and (c) ϕc with respect to model parameters. Parameters are at the same values as in Table 1 except α=0.02.

Now, following the method of [Citation5Citation39], we determine semi-relative sensitivity solutions for the infective population and budget allocation with respect to some important parameters: β, β1, ϕ and θ. Let us denote Xw as the sensitivity function of a state variable X with respect to a parameter w, i.e.Xw(t,w)=wX(t,w). The semi-relative sensitivity solutions (i.e., wXw(t,w)), determine the change that doubling of a parameter yields in the value of a state variable. We fix the parameters at the same values as in Table , and plot the semi-relative sensitivity solutions for the infective population and budget allocation in Figure . It is apparent from the figures that doubling the contact rate in the absence of budget allocation β, increases the number of infected individuals by 9227 persons and amount of budget allocation by 4587 dollars in 100 days. There is decline in infective cases by 3870 persons and amount of budget regarding preventive measures by 1924 dollars on doubling the efficacy of budget allocation to reduce the contact rate via propagating awareness β1 in 100 days. A doubling of the vaccination rate in the presence of budget, ϕ, decreases the infective cases by 793 persons and amount of budget for vaccination and awareness by 388.3 dollars in 100 days. The number of infectives decreases by 194 persons whereas budget allocation increases by 56.29 dollars in 100 days when doubling the per-capita growth rate of budget allocation θ. It is clear that out of these four parameters, β has the maximum positive effect whereas β1 has the maximum negative effect on the number of infective cases. Thus, for disease eradication, the contact rate of susceptibles with infectives should be reduced while the amount of budget on broadcasting informations through different modes of social media like Twitter, Facebook and WhatsApp must be increased by the government officials.

Figure 3. Semi-relative sensitivity solutions for infective population (I) and budget allocation (M) with respect to the parameters β, β1, ϕ and θ. Parameters are at the same values as in Table .

Figure 3. Semi-relative sensitivity solutions for infective population (I) and budget allocation (M) with respect to the parameters β, β1, ϕ and θ. Parameters are at the same values as in Table 1.

6.2. Impacts of key parameters on Rav, β1c and ϕc

To explore the impacts of three important control parameters – the efficacy of budget allocation to reduce the contact rate (β1), the vaccination rate among susceptible individuals in the presence of budget allocation (ϕ) and carrying capacity of budget allocation (K), on the epidemic threshold (Rav ), we have drawn contour plots in Figure (a–b). From these contour plots, it is evident that for small values of β1, ϕ and K, the value of basic reproduction number (Rav) is higher; however upon increasing the values of these control parameters above a threshold value, the epidemic threshold (Rav) can be drawn below unity. Thus, using these figures, the requisite value of these parameters for attaining disease-free equilibrium can be computed. It is inferred that the epidemic threshold can be driven to disease free zone in the presence of allocation of budget for vaccination and awareness programs and thus can significantly reduce the burden of disease. Next, we plot the critical values β1c and ϕc, Figure . From these contour plots, it is inferred that the values of β1c and ϕc can be reduced with increase in the values of ϕ and β1, respectively, whereas increase in the parameter δ leads to rise in the values of β1c and ϕc.

Figure 4. Contour plots of the basic reproduction number (Rav) with respect to (a) β1 and K, and (b) ϕ and K. The dashed blue line represents Rav=1. Rest of the parameters are at the same values as in Table .

Figure 4. Contour plots of the basic reproduction number (Rav) with respect to (a) β1 and K, and (b) ϕ and K. The dashed blue line represents Rav=1. Rest of the parameters are at the same values as in Table 1.

Figure 5. Contour plots of (a) β1c with respect to ϕ and δ, and (b) ϕc with respect to β1 and δ. Rest of the parameters are at the same values as in Table .

Figure 5. Contour plots of (a) β1c with respect to ϕ and δ, and (b) ϕc with respect to β1 and δ. Rest of the parameters are at the same values as in Table 1.

6.3. Impacts of important parameters on disease control

In Figure , we plot the infective population by varying two parameters at a time viz. (β1,p), (ϕ,q), (K,δ) and (θ,δ). In the figures, surfaces represent the equilibrium level of infective population or the maximum and minimum values of infective population when they oscillate. From Figure (a,b), it is inferred that there is rapid decline in infective cases with the increase in efficacy of budget allocation to reduce the contact rate via propagating awareness and vaccination rate among susceptible individuals in the presence of budget whereas infective population increases with the increase in the values of p and q. This is because the contact rate between susceptible and infected individuals increases and vaccination rate in the presence of budget decreases with the increase in the values of these parameters. From Figure (c,d), it can be easily seen that the infective population increases very fast due to ineffectiveness of vaccine which can be prevented via continuous propagation of vaccination coverage. On the other hand, there is rapid decline in infective cases with increase in the per-capita growth rate of budget allocation due to increase in infected individuals and carrying capacity of budget allocation. Thus, to suppress the burden of disease among the community, budget allocation must be increased for vaccination and awareness programs.

Figure 6. Surface plots of infective population (I) with respect to (a) β1 and p, (b) ϕ and q, (c) K and δ, and (d) θ and δ. Rest of the parameters are at the same values as in Table .

Figure 6. Surface plots of infective population (I) with respect to (a) β1 and p, (b) ϕ and q, (c) K and δ, and (d) θ and δ. Rest of the parameters are at the same values as in Table 1.

In Figure , we plot the number of infected individuals with respect to time for different values of β1 and ϕ, keeping the rest of the parameters at the same values as in Table . First, we choose β1=ϕ=0, i.e.when individuals do not take any protective measures to avoid their contacts with infected individuals and there is no vaccination coverage in the region; we find that the equilibrium number of infectives is very high in such case. Next, we assume that the individuals started to adopt precautionary measures to avoid their contacts with infected individuals in the presence of budget allocation to warn people but there is no vaccination coverage in the region. In this case, the number of infectives is found to attain a lower equilibrium level than in the previous case. A substantial decrease in infected population is noted if there is continuous growth in vaccination coverage in the presence of budget despite of the fact that the efficacy of budget allocation to reduce the contact rate via propagating awareness is zero. Further, we consider that the individuals effectively adopt the protective measures to avoid their contact with infected individuals in the presence of awareness and there is continuous growth in vaccination coverage in the presence of budget allocation; due to this combined effects of vaccination and awareness among the individuals, the equilibrium number of infectives decreases to a much lower value. Finally, we see that the equilibrium level of infective becomes zero if there is continuous augmentation in vaccination coverage at higher rate and/or the individuals effectively adopt all precautionary measures to avoid their contacts with infectives. Thus, the combined effects of vaccination coverage and awareness among the individuals regarding protective measures in the presence of budget allocation have potential to reduce the equilibrium number of infectives and can drive the system to disease-free zone.

Figure 7. Effects of vaccination and awareness on the equilibrium level of infective population. Parameters are at the same values as in Table .

Figure 7. Effects of vaccination and awareness on the equilibrium level of infective population. Parameters are at the same values as in Table 1.

In Figure (a–b), we have plotted the variation of infected population I(t) with respect to time t for different values of k1 (when conditions H1>H2 (k1<k1c=0.4393) and H1<H2 (k1>k1c) are satisfied) to determine the effect of the fraction of budget allocation used to warn people via propagating awareness and for vaccination coverage. From these figures, it is apparent that the equilibrium number of infected individuals decreases with the increase in fractional constant of budget allocation used to warn people via propagating awareness up to a threshold value i.e. k1<k1c=0.4393 (when condition H1>H2 is satisfied). In this case, fraction of budget allocation used to warn people via propagating awareness is responsible to reduce the equilibrium number of infected individuals. However, further increase in values of k1 above a threshold value (k1>k1c), fraction of budget allocation used for vaccination coverage (i.e. 1k1) is responsible to reduce the equilibrium number of infected individuals. For the parameter values in Table , it is observed that up to 43.93% of budget used for awareness and the remaining 56.07% of budget used for vaccination is beneficial to reduce the disease prevalence.

Figure 8. Variation of infected population I(t) with respect to time t for different values of k1: (a) for H1>H2 i.e. k1<k1c=0.4393 and (b) for H1<H2 i.e. k1>k1c. Rest of the parameters are at the same values as in Table .

Figure 8. Variation of infected population I(t) with respect to time t for different values of k1: (a) for H1>H2 i.e. k1<k1c=0.4393 and (b) for H1<H2 i.e. k1>k1c. Rest of the parameters are at the same values as in Table 1.

In order to manifest the direction of bifurcation at the epidemic threshold Rav=1, we plot the equilibrium number of infectives with respect to Rav by taking β as a function of Rav, Figure . We observe that for small values of β (β<β=0.0000224), the value of Rav is less than unity and in this case, only the disease-free equilibrium is feasible and locally asymptotically stable. However, on increasing the values of β above the threshold value (β>β), the value of Rav crosses unity, and we find that the interior equilibrium E becomes feasible and locally asymptotically stable whereas the disease-free equilibrium becomes unstable. This implies that the disease can persists (or dies out) in the system whenever Rav>1 (or Rav<1 ). Now, we see the global stability of interior equilibrium E in IVM space, Figure . From this figure, it is apparent that all the solution trajectories in IVM space are approaching towards the point (I,V,M) inside the region of attraction Ω. Using this approach, the global asymptotic stability of the interior equilibrium E in other spaces can also be shown. Thus, the statement of the Theorem 3.3 is numerically verified. The global stability of interior equilibrium shows that disease persists in the population when the vaccination rate in the presence of budget and efficacy of budget allocation to reduce the contact rate via propagating awareness are not strong enough.

Figure 9. Forward bifurcation diagram of system (Equation2). Parameters are at the same values as in Table . Blue colour denotes stable disease-free equilibrium (E3), red colour represents unstable disease-free equilibrium (E3) and magenta colour stands for stable interior equilibrium (E).

Figure 9. Forward bifurcation diagram of system (Equation2(2) dIdt=β−β1k1Mp+k1M(N−I−V)I−(ν+α+d)I,dVdt=ϕ(1−k1)Mq+(1−k1)M(N−I−V)−(δ+d)V,dNdt=Λ−dN−αI,dMdt=rM1−MK+θIM.(2) ). Parameters are at the same values as in Table 1. Blue colour denotes stable disease-free equilibrium (E3), red colour represents unstable disease-free equilibrium (E3) and magenta colour stands for stable interior equilibrium (E∗).

Figure 10. Global stability of the equilibrium E in IVM space. Parameters are at the same values as in Table .

Figure 10. Global stability of the equilibrium E∗ in I−V −M space. Parameters are at the same values as in Table 1.

6.4. Existence of Hopf-bifurcation

In order to examine the existence of Hopf-bifurcation and the stability of bifurcating periodic solutions, we choose the following set of parameter values: (24) Λ=5,β=0.0000030, β1=0.0000018, k1=0.2, p=2000, ϕ=0.02, q=2500,δ=0.008,ν=0.22, α=0.00001, d=0.00004, r=0.006, K=500.(24) We draw the bifurcation diagram of system (Equation1) with respect to the per-capita growth rate of budget allocation due to increase in infected individuals (θ), Figure . From the figure, it is apparent that for small values of θ, all the variables settle down to their equilibrium values while an increase in the value of θ after a threshold value, periodic oscillations arise and the interior equilibrium changes its stability from stable to unstable state. The critical value of θ at which change in stability occurs is found to be θc=0.00005953. It is clear from the figure that the interior equilibrium is stable for θ<θc whereas loss of stability occurs for θ>θc and the interior equilibrium becomes unstable. Thus, system (Equation1) undergoes Hopf-bifurcation around the interior equilibrium at θ=θc. Further, the sign of μ2, β2, T2 at θ=θc are simulated to be 4.08×1012, 1.76×1011, and 9.24×1010, respectively. Therefore, using Theorem 3.5, we can say that Hopf-bifurcation is supercritical and bifurcating periodic solutions exist for θ>θc; the bifurcating periodic solutions are stable and period increases.

Figure 11. Bifurcation diagram of system (Equation1) with respect to θ. Rest of the parameters are at the same values as in (Equation24). Here, red colour represents the upper limit of oscillation cycle and blue colour represents the lower limit of oscillation cycle.

Figure 11. Bifurcation diagram of system (Equation1(1) dSdt=Λ−β−β1k1Mp+k1MSI−ϕ(1−k1)Mq+(1−k1)MS+νI+δV−dS,dIdt=β−β1k1Mp+k1MSI−(ν+α+d)I,dVdt=ϕ(1−k1)Mq+(1−k1)MS−(δ+d)V,dMdt=rM1−MK+θIM.(1) ) with respect to θ. Rest of the parameters are at the same values as in (Equation24(24) Λ=5,β=0.0000030, β1=0.0000018, k1=0.2, p=2000, ϕ=0.02, q=2500,δ=0.008,ν=0.22, α=0.00001, d=0.00004, r=0.006, K=500.(24) ). Here, red colour represents the upper limit of oscillation cycle and blue colour represents the lower limit of oscillation cycle.

6.5. Impact of delay in budget allocation

We choose the following set of parameter values for the simulation results of system (Equation16): (25) Λ=400,β=0.000048, β1=0.000040, k1=0.4, p=60, ϕ=0.005, q=120,δ=0.008,ν=0.3, α=0.02, d=0.01, r=0.005, K=500,θ=0.00005.(25) For the set of parameter values given in (Equation25), it is observed that Equation  (Equation22) has exactly one positive real root, i.e.transcendental equation (Equation19) has a pair of purely imaginary roots and the critical value of time delay is obtained as τ0=19.80 days at which the system's behaviour changes drastically. Using Theorem 5.3, we can say that the equilibrium E is stable for τ[0,τ0) and unstable for τ>τ0. To see the impact of time delay in per-capita growth rate of budget allocation, we draw the bifurcation diagram of system (Equation16) by taking time delay τ as a bifurcation parameter, Figure . The figure shows that all the variables settle down to their equilibrium values for τ[0,τ0) while for τ>τ0, the system exhibits unstable dynamics through limit cycle oscillations with increasing amplitude.

Figure 12. Bifurcation diagram of system (Equation16) with respect to τ. Rest of the parameters are at the same values as in (Equation25). Here, blue colour represents stability of the interior equilibrium and magenta colour corresponds to instability of the interior equilibrium.

Figure 12. Bifurcation diagram of system (Equation16(16) dIdt=β−β1k1Mp+k1M(N−I−V)I−(ν+α+d)I,dVdt=ϕ(1−k1)Mq+(1−k1)M(N−I−V)−(δ+d)V,dNdt=Λ−dN−αI,dMdt=rM1−MK+θI(t−τ)M.(16) ) with respect to τ. Rest of the parameters are at the same values as in (Equation25(25) Λ=400,β=0.000048, β1=0.000040, k1=0.4, p=60, ϕ=0.005, q=120,δ=0.008,ν=0.3, α=0.02, d=0.01, r=0.005, K=500,θ=0.00005.(25) ). Here, blue colour represents stability of the interior equilibrium and magenta colour corresponds to instability of the interior equilibrium.

Further, we observed that for β1=0.000034, p = 500, ϕ=0.05, q = 800 and δ=0.08, and rest of the parameters are at the same values as in (Equation25), Equation (Equation22) has two positive real roots η+=0.00146 and η=0.000394 (where η+>η) i.e. the characteristic equation (Equation19) has two pairs of purely imaginary roots ±ω±. For these positive values of ω± from equation (Equation23), we found the positive values of τk± (k=0,1,2,3,) as given in Table . Using Theorem 5.5, we can say that for the above set of parameter values, the interior equilibrium E is stable for τ[0,61)(156,225) and unstable for τ(61,156)(225,472).

Table 2. Critical values of τ.

We pick values of time delay from different intervals and plot the infective population (it is noted that other variables of the system (Equation16) have similar behaviours), Figure . From Figure (a), it is observed that for τ=30[0,61), the infected individuals settle down to their equilibrium value, showing the stable dynamics of system (Equation16). Further increase in the value of time delay τ=100(61,156) leads to limit cycle oscillations in the infected individuals with increasing amplitude, i.e. the interior equilibrium E shows unstable dynamics (see Figure (b)). From Figure (c), it is inferred that for τ=180(156,225), the dynamics of system is again stable focus. Furthermore, we see the dynamical behaviour of the system at higher values of time delay, at τ=400 days, the system enters into chaotic regime, Figure (d). The occurrence of chaotic oscillation may be explained through incommensurate limit cycle, i.e. the frequency of the first type of oscillation is not multiple of the frequency of the second type of oscillation [Citation21Citation22]. Thus, the interior equilibrium E of system (Equation16) switches from stable to unstable to stable state and eventually system enters into chaotic regime at very high value of time delay. For a better demonstration of the effect of time delay in per-capita growth rate of budget allocation, we draw bifurcation diagram of system (Equation16) by varying the delay parameter τ in the interval [0,500], Figure . From the figure, it is inferred that for τ[0,61)(156,225), all the dynamical variables attain their equilibrium values, i.e. interior equilibrium shows stable dynamics and for τ(61,156)(225,472), all the dynamical variables show oscillatory behaviour whose maximum and minimum values are apparent from the figure, i.e. interior equilibrium shows unstable dynamics and Hopf-bifurcation occurs at τ=61,156,225. Moreover, at very higher values of time delay τ400 days, the system (Equation16) enters into chaotic regime. Thus, the dynamics of system (Equation16) changes from stable to limit cycle oscillations to stable to limit cycle oscillations to chaos on increasing the values of time delay.

Figure 13. Time series of system (Equation16) for different values of τ. Systems shows (a) stable focus at τ=30, (b) limit cycle oscillations at τ=100, (c) stable focus at τ=180 and (d) chaotic dynamics at τ=400. Rest of the parameters are at the same values as in (Equation25) except β1=0.000034, p = 500, q = 800, ϕ=0.05, δ=0.08.

Figure 13. Time series of system (Equation16(16) dIdt=β−β1k1Mp+k1M(N−I−V)I−(ν+α+d)I,dVdt=ϕ(1−k1)Mq+(1−k1)M(N−I−V)−(δ+d)V,dNdt=Λ−dN−αI,dMdt=rM1−MK+θI(t−τ)M.(16) ) for different values of τ. Systems shows (a) stable focus at τ=30, (b) limit cycle oscillations at τ=100, (c) stable focus at τ=180 and (d) chaotic dynamics at τ=400. Rest of the parameters are at the same values as in (Equation25(25) Λ=400,β=0.000048, β1=0.000040, k1=0.4, p=60, ϕ=0.005, q=120,δ=0.008,ν=0.3, α=0.02, d=0.01, r=0.005, K=500,θ=0.00005.(25) ) except β1=0.000034, p = 500, q = 800, ϕ=0.05, δ=0.08.

Figure 14. Bifurcation diagram of system (Equation16) with respect to τ. Rest of the parameters are at the same values as in (Equation25) except β1=0.000034, p = 500, q = 800, ϕ=0.05, δ=0.08. Here, red colour represents the upper limit of oscillation cycle and blue colour represents the lower limit of oscillation cycle.

Figure 14. Bifurcation diagram of system (Equation16(16) dIdt=β−β1k1Mp+k1M(N−I−V)I−(ν+α+d)I,dVdt=ϕ(1−k1)Mq+(1−k1)M(N−I−V)−(δ+d)V,dNdt=Λ−dN−αI,dMdt=rM1−MK+θI(t−τ)M.(16) ) with respect to τ. Rest of the parameters are at the same values as in (Equation25(25) Λ=400,β=0.000048, β1=0.000040, k1=0.4, p=60, ϕ=0.005, q=120,δ=0.008,ν=0.3, α=0.02, d=0.01, r=0.005, K=500,θ=0.00005.(25) ) except β1=0.000034, p = 500, q = 800, ϕ=0.05, δ=0.08. Here, red colour represents the upper limit of oscillation cycle and blue colour represents the lower limit of oscillation cycle.

To confirm chaotic nature of the system (Equation16), we draw Poincaré map of the system (Equation16) in IVM space at S = 20000 for τ=4000 days, Figure (a). The scattered distribution of the sampling points implies the chaotic behaviour of the system. We also plot maximum Lyapunov exponent of the system (Equation16) at τ=400 days by using the algorithm of [Citation42Citation53], Figure (b). The maximum Lyapunov exponent has been proven to be most useful dynamical diagnostic for chaotic systems. It represents the average exponential rate of convergence/divergence of nearby orbits in the phase space. The idea of calculating its value is to follow two nearby orbits and calculate their average logarithmic rate of separation. Whenever they get too far apart, one of the orbits has to be moved back to the vicinity of the other along the line of separation. If the attractor is chaotic, the maximum Lyapunov exponent is positive; for a bifurcation point, the maximum Lyapunov exponent is zero; the negative values of maximum Lyapunov exponent correspond to a fixed point/periodic attractor. To plot the maximum Lyapunov exponent, the delayed system (Equation16) is first simulated, then by considering the time series solutions of each component of the system, the maximum Lyapunov exponent is computed. In Figure (b), the positive values of maximum Lyapunov exponent demonstrate the chaotic regime of system (Equation16).

Figure 15. (a) Poincaré map of the system (Equation16) in IVM space at S = 20000 for τ=4000 days, and (b) maximum Lyapunov exponent of the system (Equation16) at τ=400 days. Rest of the parameters are at the same values as in (Equation25) except β1=0.000034, p = 500, q = 800, ϕ=0.05, δ=0.08.

Figure 15. (a) Poincaré map of the system (Equation16(16) dIdt=β−β1k1Mp+k1M(N−I−V)I−(ν+α+d)I,dVdt=ϕ(1−k1)Mq+(1−k1)M(N−I−V)−(δ+d)V,dNdt=Λ−dN−αI,dMdt=rM1−MK+θI(t−τ)M.(16) ) in I−V −M space at S = 20000 for τ=4000 days, and (b) maximum Lyapunov exponent of the system (Equation16(16) dIdt=β−β1k1Mp+k1M(N−I−V)I−(ν+α+d)I,dVdt=ϕ(1−k1)Mq+(1−k1)M(N−I−V)−(δ+d)V,dNdt=Λ−dN−αI,dMdt=rM1−MK+θI(t−τ)M.(16) ) at τ=400 days. Rest of the parameters are at the same values as in (Equation25(25) Λ=400,β=0.000048, β1=0.000040, k1=0.4, p=60, ϕ=0.005, q=120,δ=0.008,ν=0.3, α=0.02, d=0.01, r=0.005, K=500,θ=0.00005.(25) ) except β1=0.000034, p = 500, q = 800, ϕ=0.05, δ=0.08.

7. Conclusion and discussion

In this paper, we investigated the effects of budget allocation for vaccination and awareness to control the directly transmitted diseases. The model analysis reveals that the increment in budget allocation for vaccination coverage and awareness among the individuals regarding protective measures have potential to reduce the epidemic size and drives the system to disease-free zone. Our sensitivity results suggest that the government officials and policy makers should pay significant attention to allocate funds for vaccination coverage and broadcasting of information regarding protective measures so that individuals adopt all precautionary measures in order to eliminate the burden of disease in the community. Although, the ineffectiveness of vaccine causes longer persistence of disease in the society, budget allocation can maintain active vaccination coverage in the society, and subsequently control the spread of infection. A significant decrease in infective population is noted with the increment in budget allocation.

The model analysis showed that up to 43.93% of budget should be used for awareness and the remaining 56.07% of budget should be used for vaccination to reduce the severity of disease. The simulation results indicate that if the vaccine is not effective, then one should focus on the propagation of awareness programs at higher level for disease eradication. Similarly, if the people are not much aware about the disease, the prevalence of disease can be terminated by raising the efficacy of vaccines. Moreover, the combined effects of vaccination of high quality and the propagation of awareness at higher rate are beneficial to control the spread of disease in the population. Our simulation results showed that the increment in per-capita growth rate of budget allocation due to increase in infected individuals after a threshold value destabilizes the system and periodic oscillations arise through Hopf-bifurcation.

To predict more realistic situation on system dynamics, a discrete time delay is incorporated in per-capita growth rate of budget allocation due to increase in infected individuals. Our findings indicate that continuous and timely allocation of funds regarding preventive measures is beneficial to suppress the burden of disease in the community. However, longer delay in reported cases of infected individuals, i.e. delay in providing funds by government officials and policy makers destabilizes the system and unpredictable behaviour may be observed in the system, which brings challenges to predict and control the epidemic, and have possibility of occurrence of multiple epidemic outbreaks. Previous studies have shown the occurrence of limit cycle oscillations and multiple stability switches due to delay involved in increments of budget allocation [Citation35Citation43]. Our study shows an extra and interesting dynamics; chaotic behaviour is observed in the delayed system through incommensurate limit cycle for longer delay in per-capita growth rate of budget allocation due to rise in infected population.

Nowadays, due to emergence of coronavirus pandemic, developing and underdeveloped countries are facing huge economic crisis due to long-term lockdowns and cuts in businesses and other economic activities which resulted in rapid decline in government revenue. To overcome this, government of several countries have started to breakdown and cut in education funds, health-care funds, health infrastructure, medical health facilities etc., in coming days. However, public self-awareness regarding preventive measures such as frequent hand washing, maintaining social distance, having a healthy diet, use of face masks, regularly sanitizing etc., help people to fight against the pandemic together. Thus, the self-induced behavioural changes are vital options if there is delay in implementation of health care policies to fight against the pandemic.

Acknowledgements

The authors thank the associate editor and anonymous reviewers for their valuable comments, which contributed to the improvement in the presentation of the paper.

Disclosure statement

No potential conflict of interest was reported by the author(s).

References

  • G.O. Agaba, Y.N. Kyrychko, and K.B. Blyuss, Dynamics of vaccination in a time-delayed epidemic model with awareness, Math. Biosci. 294 (2017), pp. 92–99.
  • G.O. Agaba, Y.N. Kyrychko, and K.B. Blyuss, Mathematical model for the impact of awareness on the dynamics of infectious diseases, Math. Biosci. 286 (2017), pp. 22–30.
  • F. Al Basir, S. Ray, and E. Venturino, Role of media coverage and delay in controlling infectious diseases: A mathematical model, Appl. Math. Comput. 337 (2018), pp. 372–385.
  • C.T. Bauch, Imitation dynamics predict vaccinating behaviour, Proc. R. Soc. B. 272 (2005), pp. 1669–1675.
  • D.M. Bortz and P.W. Nelson, Sensitivity analysis of a nonlinear lumped parameter model of HIV infection dynamics, Bull. Math. Biol. 66 (2004), pp. 1009–1026.
  • B. Buonomo, Effects of information-dependent vaccination behavior on coronavirus outbreak: Insights from a SIRI model, Ricerche di Mate. 69 (2020), pp. 1–17.
  • B. Buonomo, A. d'Onofrio, and D. Lacitignola, Global stability of an SIR epidemic model with information dependent vaccination, Math. Biosci. 216(1) (2008), pp. 9–16.
  • B. Buonomo and R.D. Marca, Oscillations and hysteresis in an epidemic model with information-dependent imperfect vaccination, Math. Comput. Simulat. 162 (2019), pp. 97–114.
  • C. Castillo-Chavez and B. Song, Dynamical models of tuberculosis and their applications, Math. Biosci. Eng. 1(2) (2004), pp. 361–404.
  • J. Cui, Y. Sun, and H. Zhu, The impact of media on the control of infectious diseases, J. Dyn. Differ. Equ. 20(1) (2008), pp. 31–53.
  • S. Del Valle, A.M. Evangelista, M.C. Velasco, C.M. Kribs-Zaleta, and S.H. Schmitz, Effects of education, vaccination and treatment on HIV transmission in homosexuals with genetic heterogeneity, Math. Biosci. 187 (2004), pp. 111–133.
  • P. van den Driessche and J. Watmough, Reproduction numbers and sub-thershold endemic equilibria for compartmental models of disease transmission, Math. Biosci. 180 (2002), pp. 29–48.
  • A. Dutt, Surat plague of 1994 re-examined, Review 37 (2006), pp. 755–760.
  • X.C. Duan, I.H. Jung, X.Z. Li, and M. Martcheva, Dynamics and optimal control of an age-structured SIRVS epidemic model, Math. Meth. Appl. Sci. 43(7) (2020), pp. 4239–4256.
  • B. Dubey, P. Dubey, and U.S. Dubey, Role of media and treatment on an SIR model, Nonlinear Anal. Model. Cont. 21(2) (2016), pp. 185–200.
  • H.I. Freedman and V.S.H. Rao, The trade-off between mutual interference and time lags in predator-prey systems, Bull. Math. Biol. 45 (1983), pp. 991–1004.
  • H. Gaff and E. Schaefer, Optimal control applied to vaccination and treatment strategies for various epidemiological models, Math. Biosci. Eng. 6(3) (2009), pp. 469–492.
  • I. Ghosh, P.K. Tiwari, S. Mandal, M. Martcheva, and J. Chattopadhyay, A mathematical study to control Guinea worm disease: A case study on Chad, J. Biol. Dyn. 12(1) (2018), pp. 846–871.
  • K. Gopalsamy, Stability and Oscillations in Delay Differential Equations of Population Dynamics, Kluwer Academic, Dordrecht, Norwell, MA, 1992.
  • D. Greenhalgh, S. Rana, S. Samanta, T. Sardar, S. Bhattacharya, and J. Chattopadhyay, Awareness programs control infectious disease – multiple delay induced mathematical model, Appl. Math. Comput. 251 (2015), pp. 539–563.
  • J. Guckenheimer and P. Holmes, Nonlinear Oscillations, Dynamical Systems, and Bifurcations of Vector Fields, Vol. 42, Springer, Berlin, 2013.
  • A. Hastings and T. Powell, Chaos in a three-species food chain, Ecology 72(3) (1991), pp. 896–903.
  • B.D. Hassard, N.D. Kazarinoff, and Y.H. Wan, Theory and Applications of Hopf-bifurcation, Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, 1981.
  • H.F. Huo, P. Yang, and H. Xiang, Stability and bifurcation for an SEIS epidemic model with the impact of media, Phys. A 490 (2018), pp. 702–720.
  • V.A.A. Jansen, N. Stollenwerk, H.J. Jensen, M.E. Ramsay, W.J. Edmunds, and C.J. Rhodes, Measles outbreaks in a population with declining vaccine uptake, Science 301(5634) (2003), pp. 804.
  • T.K. Kar and A. Batabyal, Stability analysis and optimal control of an SIR epidemic model with vaccination, BioSystems 104 (2011), pp. 127–135.
  • C.M. Kribs-Zaleta and J.X.V. Hernandez, A simple vaccination model with multiple endemic states, Math. Biosci. 164 (2000), pp. 183–201.
  • Y. Kuang, Delay Differential Equations with Application in Population Dynamics, Mathematics in Science and Engineering, Academic Press Inc., New York, Vol. 191, 1992.
  • S. Lee, G. Chowell, and C. Castillo-Chavez, Optimal control for pandemic influenza: The role of limited antiviral treatment and isolation, J. Theor. Biol. 265 (2010), pp. 136–150.
  • Y. Liu and J. Cui, The impact of media convergence on the dynamics of infectious diseases, Int. J. Biomath. 1 (2008), pp. 65–74.
  • M. Martcheva, An Introduction to Mathematical Epidemiology, Springer, New York, 2015.
  • A.K. Misra and R.K. Rai, Impacts of TV and radio advertisements on the dynamics of an infectious disease: A modeling study, Math. Meth. Appl. Sci. 42 (2019), pp. 1262–1282.
  • A.K. Misra and R.K. Rai, A mathematical model for the control of infectious diseases: Effects of TV and radio advertisements, Int. J. Bifurcat. Chaos. 28(3) (2018), pp. 1850037(1–27).
  • A.K. Misra, R.K. Rai, and Y. Takeuchi, Modeling the control of infectious diseases: Effects of TV and social media advertisements, Math. Biosci. Eng. 15(6) (2018), pp. 1315–1343.
  • A.K. Misra, R.K. Rai, and Y. Takeuchi, Modeling the effect of time delay in budget allocation to control an epidemic through awareness, Int. J. Biomath. 11(2) (2018), pp. 1850027(1–20).
  • A.K. Misra, A. Sharma, and V. Singh, Effect of awareness programs in controling the prevalence of an epidemic with time delay, J. Biol. Syst. 19(2) (2011), pp. 389–402.
  • A.K. Misra, A. Sharma, and J.B. Shukla, Modeling and analysis of effects of awareness programs by media on the spread of infectious diseases, Math. Comput. Model. 53 (2011), pp. 1221–1228.
  • A.K. Misra, A. Sharma, and J.B. Shukla, Stability analysis and optimal control of an epidemic model with awareness programs by media, BioSystems 138 (2015), pp. 53–62.
  • A.K. Misra, P.K. Tiwari, and E. Venturino, Modeling the impact of awareness on the mitigation of algal bloom in a lake, J. Biol. Phys. 42(1) (2016), pp. 147–165.
  • F. Nyabadza, C. Chiyaka, Z. Mukandavire, and S.D. Hove-Musekwa, Analysis of an HIV/AIDS model with public-health information campaigns and individual withdrawal, J. Biol. Syst. 18(20) (2010), pp. 357–375.
  • A. d'Onofrio, P. Manfredi, and P. Poletti, The interplay of public intervention and private choices in determining the outcome of vaccination programmes, PLoS ONE 7(10) (2012), pp. e45653.
  • T. Park, A matlab version of the Lyapunov exponent estimation algorithm of Wolf et al., Physica 16d (2014), p. 1985. Available at https://www.mathworks.com/matlabcentral/fileexchange/48084-lyapunov-exponent-estimation-from-a-time-series-documentation-added.
  • R.K. Rai, A.K. Misra, and Y. Takeuchi, Modeling the impact of sanitation and awareness on the spread of infectious diseases, Math. Biosci. Eng. 16(2) (2019), pp. 667–700.
  • R.K. Rai, P.K. Tiwari, Y. Kang, and A.K. Misra, Modeling the effect of literacy and social media advertisements on the dynamics of infectious diseases, Math. Biosci. Eng. 17(5) (2020), pp. 5812–5848.
  • A. Sharma and A.K. Misra, Modeling the impact of awareness created by media campaigns on vaccination coverage in a variable population, J. Biol. Syst. 22(2) (2014), pp. 249–270.
  • S. Samanta, S. Rana, A. Sharma, A.K. Misra, and J. Chattopadhyay, Effect of awareness programs by media on the epidemic outbreaks: A mathematical model, Appl. Math. Comput. 219 (2013), pp. 6965–6977.
  • C. Sun, W. Yang, J. Arino, and K. Khan, Effect of media-induced social distancing on disease transmission in a two patch setting, Math. Biosci. 230 (2011), pp. 87–95.
  • J. Tchuenche and C. Bauch, Dynamics of an infectious disease where media coverage influences transmission, ISRN Biomath 581274 (2012), pp. 1–10.
  • J. Tchuenche, N. Dube, C. Bhunu, and C. Bauch, The impact of media coverage on the transmission dynamics of human influenza, BMC Public Health 11(1) (2011), pp. 1–5.
  • P.K. Tiwari, R.K. Rai, A.K. Misra, and J. Chattopadhyay, Dynamics of infectious diseases: Local versus global awareness, Int. J. Bifurcat. Chaos 31(7) (2021), p. 2150102.
  • R. Vardavas, R. Breban, and S. Blower, Can influenza epidemics be prevented by voluntary vaccination? PLoS Comput. Biol. 3(5) (2007), p. e85.
  • X. Wang, H. Peng, B. Shi, D. Jiang, S. Zhang, and B. Chen, Optimal vaccination strategy of a constrained time-varying SEIR epidemic model, Commun. Nonlinear Sci. Numer. Simulat. 67 (2019), pp. 37–48.
  • A. Wolf, J.B. Swift, H.L. Swinney, and J.A. Vastano, Determining Lyapunov exponents from a time series, Phys. D 16(3) (1985), pp. 285–317.
  • World Health Organisation, Global Vaccine Action Plan 2011-2020. Available at http://www.who.int/immunization/global_vaccine_action_plan/GVAP_doc_2011_2020/en/.
  • J. Yang, M. Martcheva, and L. Wang, Global threshold dynamics of an SIVS model with waning vaccine-induced immunity and nonlinear incidence, Math. Biosci. 268 (2015), pp. 1–8.

Appendix 1

The Jacobian matrix of system (Equation2) is J=[Jij]4×4, whose entries are given by J11=ββ1k1Mp+k1M(N2IV)(ν+α+d),J12=ββ1k1Mp+k1MI,J13=ββ1k1Mp+k1MI,J14=β1k1p(NIV)I(p+k1M)2, J21=ϕ(1k1)Mq+(1k1)M,J22=ϕ(1k1)Mq+(1k1)M+δ+d,J23=ϕ(1k1)Mq+(1k1)M, J24=ϕ(1k1)q(NIV)(q+(1k1)M)2,J31=α,J33=d, J41=θM, J44=r12MK+θI, J32=J34=J42=J43=0.

  1. Evaluating the Jacobian matrix J at the equilibrium E1, we get the four eigenvalues as, (ν+α+d)(R01), (δ+d), d and r. Since one eigenvalue is always positive, this equilibrium is unconditionally unstable.

  2. At equilibrium E2, the Jacobian matrix immediately gives one eigenvalue as r+θI2, which is always positive. The remaining three eigenvalues are given by roots of the cubic, (A1) ξ3+B1ξ2+B2ξ+B3=0,(A1) where B1=δ+2d+βI2,B2=(α+d)βI2+(δ+d)(d+βI2), B3=(α+d)(δ+d)βI2.Clearly, all Bi's are positive. Further, B1B2B3 is also found to be positive. Thus, the roots of cubic equation (EquationA1) are either negative or have negative real parts. Since one eigenvalue is always positive, the equilibrium remains unstable.

  3. Eigenvalues of the Jacobian matrix J at the equilibrium E3 are obtained as. (ν+α+d)(Rav1),ϕ(1k1)Kq+(1k1)K+δ+d, d, r.The last three eigenvalues are always negative whereas the first one is positive if Rav>1 and negative if Rav<1. Thus, the disease-free equilibrium is stable if Rav<1 and unstable whenever interior equilibrium E exists.

  4. Jacobian matrix J at the equilibrium E leads to the matrix, JE=a11a12a13a14a21(a21+δ+d)a23a24α0d0θM00rKM, where a11=a12=a13=ββ1k1Mp+k1MI,a14=β1k1p(NIV)I(p+k1M)2,a21=a23=ϕ(1k1)Mq+(1k1)M,a24=ϕ(1k1)q(NIV)(q+(1k1)M)2.The characteristic equation for the matrix JE is given by, (A2) ψ4+A1ψ3+A2ψ2+A3ψ+A4=0,(A2) where A1=a11+a21+rMK+δ+2d,A2=(α+δ+2d)a11+d(a21+δ+d)+(a11+a21+δ+2d)rMK+θMa14,A3=(α+d)(δ+d)a11+[(α+δ+2d)a11+d(a21+δ+d)]rMK+θM[a11a24+a14(a21+δ+2d)],A4=a11(α+d)(δ+d)rMK+θdM[a11a24+a14(a21+δ+d)].Note that all Ai's are positive. Thus, by Routh–Hurwitz criterion, all the roots of Equation (EquationA2) are either negative or have negative real parts if and only if condition (Equation11) holds.

Appendix 2

Consider the following positive definite function, (A3) G=IIIlnII+12m1(VV)2+12m2(NN)2+m3MMMlnMM,(A3) where m1, m2 and m3 are positive constants to be chosen appropriately.

Differentiating Equation (EquationA3) with respect to time t along the solution of model system (Equation2), choosing m2=1αββ1k1Mp+k1M, and rearranging the terms, we get dGdt=ββ1k1Mp+k1M(II)2m1ϕ(1k1)Mq+(1k1)M+δ+d(VV)2dαββ1k1Mp+k1M(NN)2m3rK(MM)2ββ1k1Mp+k1M(II)(VV)m1ϕ(1k1)Mq+(1k1)M(II)(VV)β1k1p(NIV)(p+k1M)(p+k1M)(II)(MM)+m3θ(II)(MM)+m1ϕ(1k1)Mq+(1k1)M(VV)(NN)+m1ϕ(1k1)Mq+(1k1)M(VV)(NN)+m1ϕ(1k1)q(NIV)(q+(1k1)M)(q+(1k1)M)(VV)(MM).Thus, dGdt will be negative definite inside the region of attraction Ω if the following inequalities are satisfied: (A4) β1k1Λd(p+k1M)2<m3r3Kββ1k1Mp+k1M,(A4) (A5) m3θ2<r3Kββ1k1Mp+k1M,(A5) (A6) ββ1k1Mp+k1M<m14ϕ(1k1)Mq+(1k1)M+δ+d,(A6) (A7) m1ϕ(1k1)Mq+(1k1)M2<14ββ1k1Mp+k1Mϕ(1k1)Mq+(1k1)M+δ+d,(A7) (A8) m1ϕ(1k1)Mq+(1k1)M2<dαββ1k1Mp+k1Mϕ(1k1)Mq+(1k1)M+δ+d,(A8) (A9) m1ϕΛ(1k1)d(q+(1k1)M)2<m3r3Kϕ(1k1)Mq+(1k1)M+δ+d.(A9) From inequalities (EquationA4) and (EquationA5), we can choose the positive value of m3 provided the inequality (Equation14) holds. Then, from inequalities (EquationA6)–(EquationA9), we can choose the positive value of m2 provided the inequality (Equation15) is satisfied.

Appendix 3

Coefficients of characteristic Equation (EquationA2) can be written as a function of θ i.e. (A10) ψ4+A1(θ)ψ3+A2(θ)ψ2+A3(θ)ψ+A4(θ)=0.(A10) It is noted that Ai(θ)>0 (i=1,2,3,4) for any θ>0. Let at θ=θc, (A11) A3(θc)A1(θc)A2(θc)A3(θc)A12(θc)A4(θc)=0.(A11) Thus, at θ=θc, Equation (EquationA2) can be rewritten as, (A12) ψ2+A3A1ψ2+A1ψ+A1A4A3=0.(A12) The above equation has four roots, say ψi (i=1,2,3,4), with pair of purely imaginary roots ψ1,2=±iω¯0, where ω¯0=A3A11. For the existence of Hopf-bifurcation, all the roots except ±iω¯0 (i.e.ψ3 and ψ4) should be either negative or with negative real parts. In order to identify the nature of remaining two roots, we have (A13) ψ3+ψ4=A1,(A13) (A14) ω¯02+ψ3ψ4=A2,(A14) (A15) ω¯02(ψ3+ψ4)=A3,(A15) (A16) ω¯02ψ3ψ4=A4.(A16) If ψ3 and ψ4 are real roots, then from Equations (EquationA13) and (EquationA16), it may be concluded that ψ3 and ψ4 are negative. If ψ3 and ψ4 are complex conjugates, then from Equation (EquationA13), we have 2Re(ψ3)=A1 or 2Re(ψ4)=A1. This implies that ψ3 and ψ4 have negative real parts. Thus, ψ3 and ψ4 lie in the left half of the complex plane.

Further, we obtain the transversality condition under which Hopf-bifurcation may occur. For this, let at any point θ(θcϵ,θc+ϵ), ψ1,2=χ+iσ. Substituting this in Equation (EquationA10), we get (A17) χ4+A1χ3+A2χ2+A3χ+A4+σ46χ2σ23A1χσ2A2σ2=0,(A17) (A18) 4χσ(χ2σ2)A1σ3+3A1χ2σ+2A2χσ+A3σ=0.(A18) As σ(θ)0, from Equation (EquationA18), we have (A19) (4χ+A1)σ2+(4χ3+3A1χ2+2A2χ+A3)=0.(A19) Substituting the value of σ2 in Equation (EquationA17), we have (A20) 64χ696A1χ516(3A12+2A2)χ48A1(A12+4A2)χ34(A22+2A12A2+A1A34A4)χ22A1(A1A3+A224A4)χ{A3(A1A2A3)A12A4}=0.(A20) Differentiating Equation (EquationA20) with respect to θ and using the fact that χ(θc)=0, we have dχdθθ=θc=ddθ{A3(A1A2A3)A12A4}2A1(A1A3+A224A4)θ=θc.From Equation (EquationA11), it is easy to note that A4(θc)=A3(θc){A1(θc)A2(θc)A3(θc)}A12(θc).Thus, we have dχdθθ=θc=ddθ{A3(A1A2A3)A12A4}2A1A1A3+2A3A12+A2222A3A1A2θ=θc.This implies that, dχdθθ=θc=ddθ{A3(A1A2A3)A12A4}2A1A1A3+2A3A1A22θ=θc0provided ddθ{A3(A1A2A3)A12A4}θ=θc0.