8,281
Views
19
CrossRef citations to date
0
Altmetric
Original Articles

Mapping, measuring and managing African national systems of innovation for policy and development: the case of the Ghana national system of innovation

&

Abstract

The systemic approach to innovation as key to economic development, in the context of the knowledge-based economy is increasingly evident and is of strategic value in terms of industrial and development policy (Bartels et al. Citation2012). The national system of innovation (NSI) of a country is therefore vital for enabling increased competitiveness through accelerated economic performance (Bartels and Voss Citation2005) and is crucial for developing countries hoping to catch up with advanced industrialised economies (Arocena and Sutz Citation2000). Innovation and NSI, previously seen linearly, are now viewed with a systemic network perspective. This perspective yields improved policy craft (Balzat Citation2002). In order to allocate limited resources effectively and efficiently through targeted policy, to increase industrial development and competitiveness, there is the need to map, measure and thereby manage the interactions of the core actors and barriers to innovation within the NSI (Bartels et al. Citation2009). The approach herein encapsulates the simultaneous application of a single data acquisition survey instrument (DASI) to the four core actors in the NSI (government, medium-and high-technology industry, knowledge-based institutions, arbitrageurs).

Introduction

This paper addresses the challenges of policy analysis with respect to the mapping, measuring and managing and thus monitoring, the national system of innovation (NSI) for the formulation of coherent, evidence-based science, technology and innovation policy. The case in point is the methodology applied to the Ghanaian national system of innovation (GNSI) (Koria and Koseigi 2011). It presents a four-dimensional ICT-intense methodology (Koria et al. Citation2012) for mapping, measuring and hence managing NSI. This methodology takes its departure from Leydesdorff and Etzkowitz's (Citation1996) triple helix model and elaborates the model as a triple helix model type 4 model (TH-4).

The approach first encapsulates the four core actors in the NSI: government (GOV); industry, specifically medium-and high-technology industry (MHTI); knowledge-based institutions (KBIs); and arbitrageurs (ARBs) (knowledge-brokers, venture capital, financial institutions). Secondly, it articulates the simultaneous application of a single data acquisition survey instrument (DASI) to respondents from the four core actors in the national system of innovation. Thirdly, it reflects the four phases of innovation policy of which a significant part is the involvement of knowledge-brokers (KBs), venture capital (VC) and financial institutions (FIs). The identification of the four core actors of the NSI advances the triple helix model (Etzkowitz and Leydesdorff Citation2000) as a TH-4 embedded within an environment of diffused information communications technology (ICT) (Koria et al. Citation2014).

National systems of innovation or national innovation systems (NSI/NIS) are crucially important to long-term economic competitiveness (Stern et al. Citation2000) and are of strategic policy concern for an increasing number of countries. This concern is accentuated by the global innovation divide (Sachs Citation2003) and the ever-widening ‘digital divide/digital inequality’ (White et al. Citation2011, DiMaggio and Hargittai Citation2001). The operative core of the NSI concept goes back a very long way and features in the economic work of Ricardo, Veblen, Schumpeter, Keynes, Solow and Romer. The original conceptualisation of the NSI can be attributed to Adam Smith in his 1776 analysis in terms of ‘knowledge creation in relation to directly productive activities but also specialised services of scientists’ (Lundvall et al. Citation2002, 5). The modern articulation of the concept is provided by List. According to Freeman (Citation1995, 5):

Friedrich List's conception of ‘The National System of Political Economy’ (1841) … might … have been called ‘The National System of Innovation’. The main concern of List was with the problem of Germany overtaking England and, for underdeveloped countries (as Germany then was in relation to England), he advocated not only protection of infant industries but a broad range of policies designed to accelerate, or to make possible, industrialization and economic growth. Most of these policies were concerned with learning about new technology and applying it.

We map and measure NSI with one DASI applied simultaneously to all actors. Our TH-4 approach adds a distinctive feature which is missing from the traditional triple helix model, defined by the Institute for Triple Helix Innovation, as follows: ‘Academia, government and industry constitute the three helices that engage in triple helix innovation’ (Taxonomy of Triple Helix Innovation, White Paper, The Institute for Triple Helix Innovation). While this definition does not restrict the types of industry in triple helix innovation, we argue first that the role of abitrageurs is so central to innovation that they must be formally and distinctively included (Stern et al. Citation2000, Delgado et al. Citation2012, Gaba and Bhattacharya Citation2011). Secondly, we argue that, as per the diffusion of innovation paradigm (Rogers Citation2003), it is MHTI (ISIC Rev. 3), embodying innovators, early adopters and the early majority, that possesses the economies of scale and scope, as well as the economically significant capability and capacity to innovate (even though innovation can take place in low-tech industry). Furthermore, MHTI not only represents a disproportionately high percentage of the contribution to GDP but also, in developing countries, is more ICT-connected than low-tech industry. Thirdly, we aver that communications infrastructure in the form of diffused ICT is of crucial importance in intensifying the connectedness of NSI actors (Hilbert et al. Citation2010) and facilitating the flow of knowledge and resources between actors (Koria et al. Citation2012).

Literature review

Background to the recent evolution of literature

The intense debate on the roots of economic growth (Nelson and Phelps Citation1966), whether institutional and/ or technological, invokes a growing intellectual acceptance of the NSI as a vitally important research priority for crafting development policy (Ushakov Citation2012, Samara et al. Citation2012, Groenewegen and Van der Steen Citation2006). This debate has expanded the architecture of NSI literature to include the economics of innovation and technology, systems of innovation (at different ‘nested’ and networked vertical and horizontal levels of operation including local, sub-regional, national and supra-regional on the one hand and sector and technological on the other hand), industrial dynamics, organisational and policy dimensions of structural change, national innovation capacity (Bartels et al. Citation2012, Chang and Lin Citation2012) and transfer of technology. The international business facet, manifest as the transfer of technology and innovation through internalisation (Buckley and Carter Citation2004, Buckley and Hashai Citation2004, Dunning Citation2003, Buckley and Casson Citation2002) across the organisational boundaries of the firm via foreign direct investment (FDI) and foreign market servicing strategies, by multinational enterprises (MNEs), is equally of great consequence and a critical research concern. However, the dynamics of innovation inside MNEs within countries are beyond the scope of the paper.

A measure of the intensifying relevance of NSI is provided by expanding practitioner and research coverage. The 1999 DRUID conference on ‘National Innovations Systems, Industrial Dynamics and Innovation Policy’ suggested eight dimensions of NSI. The DRUID 2012 conference on ‘Innovation and Competitiveness – Dynamics of Organizations, Industries, Systems and Regions’ presented 67 parallel paper sessions ranging from 1 – Theoretical Perspectives on Regional Clusters to 67 – Emergence and Evolution of Technologies and Industries. The taxonomy of NSI has also been extended over organisational structures (‘soft’, ‘hard’), communication, co-operation, co-ordination, command and control, spatial dynamics, knowledge dynamics, knowledge stock, technology dynamics, functionality, industry-market dynamics and path dependency functions (Daneke Citation1998).

However, two provocative perspectives on NSI are cogent. First, according to Gatignon et al. (2001, 2), ‘Innovation and technical change are at the core of dynamic organizational capabilities … Yet after more than 30 years of research on innovation and organisational outcomes, fundamental concepts and units of analysis are often confused and/or ambiguous’. Secondly, according to Moldaschl (Citation2010, 8) innovation theories make no sense because in ‘the last two decades … the semantics of innovation has quasi overflowed, lost any limits and thus inevitably become more meaningless’. It is not surprising, therefore, that, within this dynamic field, attention is focused more on conceptualisation and measurement issues at the different echelons: meta-, macro-, meso-, micro- and firm-level (Chaminade et al. Citation2012, Montalvo and Moghayer Citation2012, Freeman Citation2002, Carlsson et al. Citation2002, Sornn-Friese Citation2000, Patel and Pavitt Citation1994) rather than on empirical investigations of systems of innovation (Becheikh et al. Citation2006). Furthermore, given the centrality of institutions (i.e. the ‘rules of the game’), the contribution that distinguishes between institutions and organisations – following the separation of institutions and competencies (Patel and Pavitt Citation1994) – is of significant value (Edquist and Johnson Citation1997).

Despite the wealth of contributions, statistical assessments that use factor analysis to scrutinise NSI are fewer than expected (Bartels et al. Citation2012, Chang and Lin Citation2012). This is firstly due to the multiple challenges of measurement and secondly to the difficulty in selecting variables relevant to and capable of being responded to by all four core actors in the NSI. Notable exceptions model indicators of technological advancement in growth accounting and Patel and Pavitt (Citation1994) use correlations to analyse sectoral specialisation. A seminal exception to the less than expected volume of quantitative evaluations is Nasierowski and Arcelus (Citation1999), who employ factor analysis and structural equation modelling (SEM) to analyse NSI relationships. Also noteworthy is the SEM modelling of inter-firm competencies (Nooteboom et al. Citation1998) and the confirmatory factor analysis of Gatignon et al. (2001 2002). However, none of the above map and measure simultaneously all four core NSI actors. Therefore, more comparative analysis is called for; particularly, ‘much more NSI work on economies that are either underdeveloped or in the process of catching-up needs to be done’ (Sornn-Friese Citation2000, 10). Descriptive analyses, which hallmark innovation reports, can thus be complemented by rigorous quantitative analysis of the interdependencies among NSI actors, along with the factors that enable (or disable) the NSI, in terms of data, information, statistics and knowledge (DISK).

The main contributions have focused almost exclusively on NSI in industrial countries. While fruitful, the exclusive focus on advanced industrial country NSI, as suggested by Arocena and Sutz (Citation2000), should carry an injunction against adoption of ‘Northern’ NSI characteristics without adaptation through local cultural and institutional lenses in the ‘South’ (Da Motta e Albuquerque Citation1999).

It is therefore our intention to expand the common NSI configuration (OECD Citation1999, Nasierowski and Arcelus Citation1999, Leydesdorff and Etzkowitz Citation1996, Lundvall Citation1992) in application to developing countries and present the factors or variables for policy recommendations. illustrates the interface between public (government) and private (investor) interventions in the dynamics of innovation.

Figure 1. Policy stages in the dynamics of innovation. (Adapted from Foxon et al. Citation2004).

Figure 1. Policy stages in the dynamics of innovation. (Adapted from Foxon et al. Citation2004).

The literature and its evolution

The first formal but unpublished use of the term ‘national systems of innovation’ was by Freeman in work in 1982 for an OECD expert group on Science, Technology and Competitiveness (Lundvall Citation2003, Carlsson Citation2006). Arguably, the operable key analytical framework for dealing with NSI was presented by Andersen and Lundvall (Citation1988) as a system of: (1) backward linkages in flows of information; (2) learning by doing and searching; (3) distinctions between industrial subsystems at different stages in terms of life cycle; and (4) the open economy (Lundvall et al. Citation2002).

This conceptual frame, focusing on the development of technology and user-producer interactions, produced one definition of NSI as ‘ … the elements and relationships which interact in the production, diffusion and use of new and economically useful, knowledge are either located within or rooted inside the borders of a nation state’ (Lundvall Citation1992, 2). There are many definitions of NSI (UNIDO Citation2012, 16, Bartels et al. Citation2012, Achim and Popescu Citation2009). A more comprehensive definition, in policy, systemic and organisational capital terms, is provided by Bartels et al. (Citation2012, 6) as ‘the envelope of conforming policies as well as private and public organisations, their distributed institutional relations and their coherent social and capital formations, that determine the vector of technological change, learning and application in the national economy.’

The two definitions above – separated by two decades and encompassing micro-level interactive production elements and relationships and macro-level conforming policies that determine technological change, learning and application – are contoured by interdisciplinary approaches within long-term comparative economic performance (von Tunzelmann Citation1997), national competitiveness (Porter Citation1990) and growth accounting (Greenwood and Jovanovic Citation1998, Jovanovic and Rob Citation1989, Arrow Citation1962, Solow Citation1960). These approaches have brought sharply into relief the indispensability of technological innovation and organisational capital in industrial dynamics and development (Squicciarini and Le Mouel Citation2012).

Economic performance is fundamentally determined by ‘deep determinants’ of income, which, according to Rodrik and Subramanian (Citation2003, 32), are: geographygeology (or space) – the key to climatic advantages and natural resource endowments; integration – the role of international trade as a determinant of productivity change; and institutions – which determine the roles of property rights, the rule of law and the ‘rules of the game’ in society. These deep determinants in turn influence five drivers of development: multi-lateral organisation, macro-economics, factor inputs and suppliers, industry characteristics and competitive scope, which operate non-linearly (Porter Citation1990), across geo-economic space, as a complex adaptive eco-system of innovation, at supranational or meta-, national or macro-, cluster or meso-, industry or micro- and firm levels (Bramwell, Hepburn and Wolfe Citation2012). The crucial property enabling innovation in terms of capacity – and innovativeness in terms of capability – is the quality of reciprocating vertical and horizontal linkages in the innovation eco-system, connecting actors and the innovation assets infrastructure and facilitating the flow of DISK in the NSI. The density, distribution, directionality and strength of the linkages thus determine ‘the extent to which the potential for innovation induced by the common innovation infrastructure is translated into specific innovative outputs in a nation's clusters’ (Stern et al. Citation2000, 13).

Within these levels, the NSI conforms a geo-economic space of firms and strategies in a complex ecology wherein technological functions are essential (Ricart et al. Citation2004, 191, Wang and von Tunzelmann Citation2000). The ‘new’ empirics of growth (Durlauf and Quah Citation1998) emphasise these underpinnings, first identified in endogenous growth and technological change (Romer Citation1990). Contemporaneously, the institutionalised and spatially distributed network of market and non-market actors engaged in technology-related change-generating activities have attracted the rubric NSI (Dosi et al. Citation1988, Freeman Citation1987), with variations in the nomenclature depending on the unit or level of analysis.

Further elaborated since the 1990s within institutional literature (Hollingsworth and Boyer Citation1997), NSI is now viewed as vital to the effective co-ordination of inter-organisational relations in which knowledge is the currency of exchange in technological development (Edquist Citation1997, Lundvall Citation1995). This is due to the consistent affirmation that DISK and innovation, in co-determining patterns and trajectories of economic growth, are the key salient ingredients in the modern economy (Quatraro Citation2012, OECD Citation2011, Vania Citation2004). Nations must therefore access and develop new technologies if they do not wish to find themselves on the wrong side of the bifurcation in cross-country income distributions since the 1960s (Barro Citation1998, Durlauf and Quah Citation1998).

The central role of NSI in the dynamics of economic growth thus well acknowledged (Freeman Citation2002), invokes noteworthy portrayals in the taxonomy of structure and process in NSI. Among the earliest, Sábato and Botana (Citation1968) indicated that relations between the government, the productive structure and the scientific and technological infrastructure are key to innovativeness. Pavitt's (Citation1984) concept of innovative industrial patterns suggested the dimensions: supplier dominated; scale intensive; specialised supplier dominated; and science-based. In 1992 the OECD elaborated a taxonomy of industry and high- or low-tech dimensions (OECD Citation1992). Useful as they are, taxonomies based on size, sector and locational classifications have given way to those with systemic knowledge, human, social and organisational capital dimensions (van Ark and Hulten Citation2007). These latter taxonomies place greater emphasis on the emergent properties, complex adaptive system and non-linear properties of the NSI (Dasgupta Citation2002, Etzkowitz and Leydesdorff Citation2000, Lundvall Citation1998).

Archibugi and Iammarino (Citation1999) develop a taxonomy of the globalisation of innovation with respective dimensions, level of formality and distance from innovation process and actions and forms. They indicate that global techno-scientific collaboration, an activity manifest at the interfaces of NSI actors, is archetypically performed by universities, public research centres and national and international firms. These are the actors in Leydesdorff's (Citation2001, 1) ‘neo-evolutionary model of a triple helix of university-industry-government relations’.

The taxonomy of Braadland and Anders (Citation2002), based on skills and the extent to which innovation is systemic, classifies the firm level component of NSI with the metric skilled worker or engineering density. Furthermore, Kaiser and Prange (Citation2004) propose a territorial configuration to delineate NSI. In their taxonomy, regulatory policies and spatiality constitute the dimensions of NSI. Bjørnskov and Svendsen (Citation2004) use the extent of decentralisation and availability of social capital to delineate the economic performance of Scandinavia relative to Eastern and Western Europe. In contrast, Asheim and Coenen (Citation2004) and Munk and Vintergaard (Citation2004) propose a taxonomy at meso-, or cluster-level in which the knowledge base, organisational nature, institutional characteristics and involvement in innovation are the four dimensions of classification.

On one hand, these taxonomies of NSI accentuate the complex externalities and dynamics of knowledge and innovation with their formal as well as informal organisational characteristics and direct and indirect involvement in processes of innovation (Munk and Vintergaard Citation2004, 4, Braadland and Anders Citation2002, 8). On the other hand, the taxonomies bring into relief ‘the complex dynamics … composed of subdynamics like market forces, political power, institutional control, social movements, technological trajectories and regimes. The operations (therefore) can be expected to be nested and interacting’ (Etzkowitz and Leydesdorff Citation2000, 113). The evolutionary model (Leydesdorff Citation2001, Citation2012), with functional and organisational dimensions (science-economy vs. public-private), reflects NSI actors and linkages that need accurate portrayal for policy analysis (OECD Citation1999). Herein, knowledge generation and diffusion by organisations and knowledge deployment moderated by institutions are viewed as the NSI capability that leads to innovativeness. NSI capacity is seen as the strength of links between actors, supply and market factor conditions, communication infrastructures, education/training and the macro- economic and regulatory contexts that lead to innovation. This bilateral perspective informs our method of mapping and measuring NSI (Koria et al. Citation2012).

As the NSI encapsulates and articulates the effectiveness and efficiency of technological change in the economy, it is important to recognise three basic constructs. First, translating systemic innovation into competitive performance is a function of close and stable relationships between economic actors (Richardson Citation1972). Secondly, these relationships are contextualised by non-market interactions (Lundvall Citation1985, Williamson Citation1985). Thirdly, the relationships and interactions are differentially moulded by specificities of national institutional ‘rules of game’ (Edquist Citation1997). To these three, a distinctive fourth construct may be added – differences in stocks and quality and rates of flows, of industrial knowledge as well as their management carry implications for the relationships between economic actors (Asheim and Coenen Citation2004).

It is therefore obvious that in circumscribing the concept of NSI, the social system constituted by institutional arrangements, resource capacities and proprietary functional capabilities is constructively important (Van de Ven Citation1993). With this perspective, Park and Park (Citation2003, 403), pointing to the significant correlation between R&D and industrial structures, suggest their notion of NSI as ‘the structural and functional profiles of a nation that determine its innovative capability and economic performance.’ Echoing Van de Ven (Citation1993), Wijnberg (Citation1994, 316) uses a content rich ‘structure-conduct-performance model’ to identify the NSI in terms of the policy framework that affects the evolution of industrial development. Respectively, resource capacities or structure, institutional arrangements or conduct and proprietary functional capabilities or performance may be taken as constituting the NSI. For Wijnberg (Citation1994, 318) the NSI is ‘a set of policies that influence the structural characteristics, the dominant type of innovation in particular industries, the risk-taking propensity of enterprises in these industries and the selection environment in which these industries develop’.

As sophisticated performance of the resource elements within NSI is associated with advanced economic and industrial development (Freeman Citation2002, Furman, et al. 2002) and vice versa (Hall Citation2004, Kremp and Mairesse Citation2004, Comin Citation2004), it is not surprising that innovation and NSI research are largely concentrated on and in, OECD countries (Mohnen et al. Citation2006, Hall and Mairesse Citation2006). A major contribution to the literature has been the ‘RISE’ project (1999). Farina and Preissl (Citation1999) depict a taxonomy with private–public and knowledge generation–knowledge application as principal dimensions. They indicate that NSI resource capacities (R&D oriented) are relatively less important than proprietary functional capabilities. Crucially important for developing countries, they conclude that ‘the success of innovation is increasingly dependent on functions that are not R&D, like organisational re-adjustments, training of personnel, design of prototypes and procedural blue-prints, market research, availability of venture capital, integration of existing equipment and stocks of knowledge with new knowledge inputs’ (Farina and Preissl Citation1999, Chapter 6, 24).

The NSI literature on developing countries does not depart radically from the mainstream ideas identified above. Arocena and Sutz (Citation2000, 58) point to the ‘four main aspects of the NIS concept’ as ‘an ex-post concept’, one that ‘carries a normative weight’ and is ‘relational’, as well as being path dependent and evolutionary and is therefore ‘a policy subject’. However, the interesting implication of the normative aspect, from the perspective of developing countries, is that ‘there are some general “good ways” and some ways that appear to be “better” than others’ and that it is important ‘to avoid copying or just following the latest policy fashion’ (Arocena and Sutz. Citation2000, 59). The concept of NSI in developing countries’ industrial development has received deserved attention in terms of case studies (Schiller Citation2006, Yeh and Chang Citation2003, Intarakumnerd et al. Citation2002) and policy (Edquist Citation2001).

Cassiolato and Lastres (Citation2000) discuss NSI within the international production network of spatially distributed production context of policies to attract FDI and MNEs, which results in lessening emphasis on endogenous innovative activities. They conclude that, as the generation of innovation by MNEs is still dominated by the home country bias (Tsuge and Bartels Citation2003), simply exposing domestic firms to either FDI or MNEs sub-contracting/supply relationships (Bartels, et al. Citation2009) is necessary but insufficient. They highlight ‘the importance of continuous public and private policies and efforts aiming at promoting the capacity to acquire and use knowledge and to innovate’ (Cassiolato and Lastres Citation2000, 51). This is highly applicable to African countries.

Given the nuances in the conceptualisation of NSI, it is not surprising that empirical measurement is meagre in comparison with voluminous articulations of the concept (Becheikh et al. Citation2006). With this background and the definition of NSI by Bartels et al. (Citation2012), –Triple Helix Type 4 – illustrates our model for mapping and measuring NSI.

Figure 2. Triple Helix Type 4 (an extension of the Triple Helix of Etzkowitz and Leydersdorff 1996).

Figure 2. Triple Helix Type 4 (an extension of the Triple Helix of Etzkowitz and Leydersdorff 1996).

Methodology

Collecting evidence through surveying

Basically, ‘evidence based policy making refers to the notion that policy intervention and direction are underpinned by an understanding of how things develop’ (Gera et al. Citation2006, 58) arrived at, in the case of NSI, by mapping and measurement. Essentially there are two forms of data collection, interviews and self-administered questionnaires (Lozar and Vehovar 2008). Data collection processes are complex and require careful consideration of a multitude of parameters as well as issues of statistical reliability and validity. The main issues in data collection methods are: cost, coverage and quality of response.

The accelerated proliferation of the ‘new techno-economic paradigm, centred on information and communication technologies (ICT), have [sic] accelerated and deepened both the codification of knowledge and the spread of information’ (Lastres et al. Citation2005, 1) and overall quality of data acquisition. The ability to access DISK is a key factor in developing competitiveness and engaging globally.1 However, the ‘digital divide’ is partly due to the minimal availability of ICT access in developing countries as compared to developed countries. Our methodology exploits free open source software (FOSS) which assists in bridging the digital divide. FOSS by its constitution – non-rivalry and non-excludability – acts as a public good. Mueller (Citation2003) notes the positive correlation between the growth of a FOSS developer base and innovative capacities.

Mapping and measuring NSI using FOSS

This section addresses the FOSS application Lime Survey. illustrates the methodology.

Figure 3. Stages in the GNSI methodology. (Adapted from Koria & Köszegi Citation2011).

Figure 3. Stages in the GNSI methodology. (Adapted from Koria & Köszegi Citation2011).

In survey design, questionnaire length is an important predictor of response rate (Tomaskovic-Devey 1994, Berdie Citation1973). Regarding the GNSI survey, variables were constructed from the NSI literature,2 and the DASI was created using a multi-step process: (1) Performing in 2007 a comprehensive NSI literature survey (including all innovation surveys since 2000). (2) From this, 300 NSI variables were extracted, which were reduced to 138 variables3 (Bartels et al. Citation2009). (3) Using the 138 variables, a survey instrument was designed to measure NSI actor perceptions (Clason and Dormody Citation1994, Garland Citation1991) using a five-point Likert scale. Strong empirical evidence supports the treatment of ordinal variables as conforming to interval scales (Labovitz Citation1967 1970 1971). (4) The DASI was then refined through peer review.4 The resultant version of the DASI is herein referred to as DASI-V1. (5) The DASI-V1 was then reverse translated into French and Spanish for the sake of accuracy and embedded into the web-based electronic survey FOSS Lime Survey. (6) The DASI-V1 was launched in seven emerging market economies (EMEs)5 on the basis of the Survey of Surveys of Innovation6 which had examined innovation surveys in EMEs. A second Survey of Surveys of Innovation in EMEs was conducted in 2012. The updated Survey of Surveys of Innovation shows that of the 128 surveys conducted since 1990 in EMEs,7 none can be strictly defined as a NSI survey, in terms of the same DASI being applied to all four core NSI actors.8 The crucially important characteristic differentiating our methodology from other methodologies, including the Frascati and Oslo manuals, is the fact that our survey applies contemporaneously the same DASI-V1 to the three core actors of the NSI as well as to a fourth actor, arbitrageurs, acknowledged to play a crucial role of intermediation between sources of knowledge and commercialisation of knowledge; and, furthermore, the DASI-V1 is applied using ICT. The GNSI survey obtained valid and reliable responses as shown in .

Table 1. GNSI Universe and Convenient Sample of Respondents

The methodology is based on the ‘triple helix model’ (Etzkowitz and Leydesdorff 1996), but includes the extra intermediary body, arbitrageurs (Koria & Köszegi Citation2011). Arbitrageurs, not represented in the traditional model, are of crucial importance as innovation requires internal and external knowledge and arbitrageurs provide links, resources and even technical knowledge so that firms can improve their performance, survival rate as well as accelerate and increase the effectiveness of their innovation processes (Zook Citation2003, Baygan and Freudenberg Citation2000, Hargadon 1998). Their resource allocation role is based on advantages in information asymmetries (Williamson Citation1969 1971 1973).

The next point of discussion is response rate. Low response rates are seen as problematic (Harzing Citation2007). Response rates differ significantly cross-sectionally across professions, occupational groups and countries. Evidence suggests that response rates by managerial staff are lower than those of non-managerial staff (Baruch Citation1999). Cycyota and Harrison (Citation2006) identified an overall top manager response rate of 32%. Various strategies exist to increase response rates (Dillman Citation2000, Zwane et al. Citation2010) and steps were taken to maximise our response rate. For clarity and ease of response, the direction and strength of measurement scales were carefully considered within the DASI-V1. Therefore, the DASI-V1 for the GNSI deploys a five-point Likert scale with a midpoint, thus reducing the bias towards both extreme answers and towards false negatives (Matell and Jacoby 1972, Garland Citation1991).

From survey delivery options of mail, telephone, interactive voice response and internet,Footnote9 we chose the internet justified by: (1) covering larger sample sizes than conventional mail surveys (Berrens Citation2003), (2) shorter time (Cobanoglu 2001), (3) superior quality of retrieved data, in terms of non-responses and including discreetly conditionality (Olsen Citation2009) and (4) higher reliability of data due to elimination of data entry (Bartels and Lederer Citation2009, Muffo et al. Citation2003).

Analysis

In analysis the cross-tabulations the five-point Likert scales are dichotomised into the limits of the measurement scale of statistically significant variables as follows:

  • Very Important - Irrelevant (VI-I)

  • Very Strong – Very Weak (VS-VW)

  • Very Positive – Very Negative (VP-VN)

  • Very High Innovativeness – Very Low Innovativeness (VHI-VLI)

  • Very Highly Successful – Not Successful (VHS-NS)

  • Very High Constraint – Very Low Constraint (VHC-VLC).

Neutral was assigned to the negative side on the basis that a neutral perception by an expert respondent is not positive.

The variables analysed, reported and discussed are:

  • Actor importance and strength of inter-, intra-actor linkages (cross-tabulation)

  • Factor constraints on innovation (factor analysis).

Cross-tabulation permits the examination of statistically significant observations (i.e. the inter-linkages between GNSI actors and NSI variables) using the Chi-square test of significance reported at a confidence level of 95% or above to indicate significant systematic relationships.

Factor analysis reduces observed variables into factors within a pattern matrix (clusters of inter-correlated variables) with ‘mutual interdependence’ (Gaur Citation1997). The factors represent the underlying structure that influences the variation of variables in the data, sample and hence the population and universe of Respondents (Kim and Mueller Citation1978, 54, Kaiser Citation1974, Dziuban and Shirkey Citation1974, 359, Rummel Citation1970).

Factor analysis permits ‘the correlations or covariance between a set of observed variables [that] arise from the relationship of these variables to a small number of underlying, unobservable, latent variables, usually known as the common factors’ (Everitt Citation2002, 140) to be captured. We use exploratory factor analysis, as a priori constraints are not imposed on the data and this enables parsimonious reduction while maintaining the underlying pattern of the variation of variables (Hair et al. Citation1998). We use the Kaiser criterion (Kaiser Citation1960) for the number of factors extracted. Furthermore, for robust explanatory power, we require the extracted factors to explain at least 50% of the total cumulative variance. As we do not stipulate the factors to be uncorrelated, we use oblique rotation.

To maintain statistical significance, variables with less than 0.55 coefficient loading (equal to 30.25% of the variance accounted for by the factor) are suppressed. Cut-off criteria for factor loadings remain a matter of debate (Cudeck and O'Dell Citation1994, Bowles Citation2006, Hair et al. Citation1998). Shapiro et al. (Citation2002) indicate several factor coefficient loading cut-offs.Footnote10 Heuristics suggest that loadings of>0.30 are salient and cut-off selection between 0.30 and 0.60 is representative in the literature (Bagozzi and Yi Citation1998, Swisher et al. Citation2004).

Results and discussion

The results, discussion and policy implications are presented, after which a complement of select policy recommendations is indicated.

Cross-tabulations

To portray actor inter-, intra-linkages, the convention used in our findings is as follows:

  • Government inter-linkage with knowledge-based institutions; proactive inter-linkage, i.e. government to knowledge-based institutions is GOV–KBI

  • passive inter-linkage (from government perspective) KBI–GOV

  • Government intra-linkage GOV–GOV.

We find that GOV respondents have no statistically significant assessment of other actors’ inter-linkages. The MHTI view is striking for the absence of significant relationships KBI–GOV, as is that from KBIs, who do not have a significant assessment of MHTI–GOV (or vice versa) inter-linkages. Finally, ARBs do not have a significant assessment of the inter-linkages KBI–GOV, MHTI– KBI (or vice versa), MHTI–GOV (or vice versa). It should be noted that from an actor-centric view, ARBs indicate only two proactive linkages with respect to GOV and MHTI, notably [GOV]ARB–GOV, 83.4% and MHTI [BE] ARB–BE, 50.0% (see below). While there is no significant perception by MHTI of KBI–GOV relations, the majority of KBIs perceive VI-VS relationships between KBI–GOV and GOV–KBI with the exception of RI–ISTC linkages (only 26.4% KBIs assess this as VI-VS). Clearly, these two views of MHTI and KBIs are asymmetric.

Figure 4. Actor-Centric Assessment of Inter-Linkages (Very Important-Very Strong)

Figure 4. Actor-Centric Assessment of Inter-Linkages (Very Important-Very Strong)

The policy implications of this asymmetry in actor importance and linkage strengths are: (1) insufficient information exchange between MHTI and KBIs with respect to KBI–GOV relations, which raises the policy question of whether there is sufficient dialogue that facilitates information and knowledge exchange; (2) ARBs are isolated from the GNSI and play no significant role in terms of intermediating knowledge transfers through modalities such as intellectual property rights (IPRs) and licensing regarding IPRs emanating either from KBIs, or flowing between KBIs and MHTI; and (3) the ARBs’ intra-linkages, perceived as VI-VS, have very few (if any) significant externalities.

With respect to MHTI perception of the tri-lateral relationship between GOV–ARB–KBI, in which there are more significant relations (ARB–GOV, GOV–ARB, ARB– KBI, KBI–ARB) than GOV–KBI or KBI–GOV. The minority of MHTI perceive VI-VS inter-linkages. There are ten significant linkages in GOV–ARB–KBI (unidirectional) compared to two GOV–KBI (bidirectional).

Again, this asymmetry suggests the following policy implications as absence of: (1) reciprocating relations of communications, co-operation, co-ordination and exchange functions formalised through well-functioning standing committees and conferences between GOV-ARB-KBI; and, (2) operative high-performance councils on Science, Engineering, Technology and Innovation, as well as on economic and social research and on the ‘knowledge brokering’ role of ARBs.

With respect to the actor-centric view regarding VI-VS inter-linkages (see ) there are no significant relations between ARBs and KBIs, only one ARB–GOV and one ARB–MHTI.

The key policy implication is that the isolation of ARBs infers, at best, a very limited intermediary role either in creating DISK, or as ‘pumps’ for flows of DISK, in the GNSI. At worst, ARBs have no functioning intermediation role. Specifically: (1) the absence of significant linkages ARB–KBI, KBI–ARB means that ARBs do not have access to DISK created by and held within, KBIs. Therefore, ARBs are prevented from acting as conduits to MHTI or investing directly in KBI-hosted spin-offs; (2) the [BE]ARB–BE linkage has less depth to it in the absence of ARBs’ access to DISK from KBIs; and (3) the [GOV]ARB–GOV linkage is devoid of the practicability of ARBs being able to persuade convincingly GOV towards policies that enhance the stocks and flows of knowledge in and throughout, the GNSI (i.e. from KBIs to MHTI directly, or indirectly, via ARBs, e.g. through advocacy and lobbying pressure).

Notwithstanding the overall weakness of inter-linkages among actors in the GNSI, from a triangular perspective the relationship GOV–ARB–KBI, the densest of this relationship is along the axis KBI–GOV. This reflects the traditional role of GOV in funding KBIs.

The policy implications of this public goods provision by GOV, in the context of the isolation of ARBs and their insubstantial intermediating role and overall VI-VW systemic inter-linkages, are: (1) very low returns from the expenditure in treasury, organisational effort and transaction costs,Footnote11,Footnote12,Footnote13 and (2) externalities – the fundamental reason for providing the public goods – are extremely limited, thus reducing the effectiveness and efficiency of the GNSI.

Importantly, the perception of KBI–GOV relations by KBIs is asymmetric to the perception of GOV–KBIs relations. KBIs perceive a bi-directional relationship, whereas GOV perceives no significant relationship (see ).

Policy implications from the asymmetry between KBIs and GOV regarding their inter-linkages have profound consequences. These policy implications are: (1) the GOV framework of incentives for KBIs (fiscal, monetary, regulatory, standards and performance) is mostly ineffective in that GOV demands little from KBIs in return for providing financial support to KBIs (and students) in Science, Technology, Engineering, Mathematics and Information Technology (STEMIT) programmes; (2) GOV-supported institutions supporting technical change (ISTC) inter-linkages with KBIs are largely ineffective (with respect to [ISTC]RI–ISTC; 61.4% of KBIs respondents indicate VI-VW); (3) the performance required from KBIs by GOV is limited at best and at worst does not encourage KBIs to engage proactively with other GNSI actors; (4) recalibration of STEMIT under-and post-graduate courses to the inter-disciplinary needs of MHTI; (5) reconfiguring the national service programme toward internships in MHTI for STEMIT students; and (6) conditioning financial support (research ‘top up’ grants, etc.) on joint research with MHTI.

Whereas the majority (51.1%–56.3%) of KBIs perceive KBI–GOV (bidirectional) as VI-VS, only a minority (26.4%) of KBIs perceive the crucial transformational RI–ISTC linkageFootnote14 as VI-VS (the majority of KBIs (61.4%) assess [ISTC]RI–ISTC as VI-VW) (see ).

Figure 5. Actor-centric assessment of inter-linkages (Very Important – Very Weak)

Figure 5. Actor-centric assessment of inter-linkages (Very Important – Very Weak)

The policy implications of this VI-VW inter-linkage between RI–ISTC include: (1) truncated relations with demand and factor markets and with MHTI in the commercialisation of KBI's IPRs; (2) VI-VW KBI passive [HE]BE–HE inter-linkages; (3) the stocks of RI and KBIs IPRs find little or no receptive outlets either in ISTC or MHTI and hence there is little or no flow of intellectual property and knowledge within the GNSI; and, (4) limited GOV performance requirements from RI and ISTC.

MHTI see a significant bi-directional relationship between GOV and KBIs, but none with respect to KBI– GOV. Critically, while, GOV respondents do not mirror this view, KBIs do have a view of KBI–GOV inter-linkages (see ). This divergence between MHTI and GOV with respect to GOV–KBI and asymmetry between MHTI and KBIs with respect to KBI–GOV inter-linkages is indicative of discordance within the GNSI and, its pre-adolescent stage of evolution in terms of the TH-4 GOV–KBI–MHTI–ARB transactional and transformational linkages.

Policy implications arising from the policy analysis and of the actor-centric mapping in terms of the TH-4 relations include: (1) conspicuous gaps in GOV–MHTI and ARB–KBI (and vice versa) linkages; (2) noting that GOV Respondents have no significant assessment of inter-linkages among other actors in the GNSI, the policy levers available to GOV are, at best, articulated insufficiently well and at worst are far too remote for efficient policy craft and effective policy direction; (3) notably, ARBs mirror MHTI view of a significant bi-directional inter-linkage GOV–KBI in terms of [GOV]GOV–RI and [GOV]HE–GOV; [GOV]GOV–HE, [HE]GOV–HE and [GOV]HE–GOV, [HE]HE–GOV; and (4) the absence of actor-centric ARB–KBI (and vice versa) and GOV–MHTI ( and vice versa) inter-linkages points to limited ability on the part of GOV to enforce innovation policy with respect to KBI–ARB inter-linkages and MHTI.

In summary, the policy implications of the gaps identified in mapping and measuring the GNSI may be grouped into: (1) information asymmetries; (2) co-ordination failures; (3) lack of significant externalities; (4) glacial flows of DISK; (5) an ineffective framework of incentives; (6) lack of connectivity between actors; and, (6) unarticulated policy levers.

and map and measure statistically significant actor-centric assessments of their inter-linkages with other actors (i.e. how one actor views its inter-linkages with another actor) in proactive, that is, for example from the perspective of GOV (GOV–KBI), or passive, that is, for example (KBI–GOV), along the dimension importance of actor and strength of actor-actor inter-linkages measured as VI-VS and VI-VW. The diagrams require viewing in tandem.

The policy implications of the asymmetrical dimension of actor importance and strength of actor-actor inter-linkages include: (1) a GNSI that is seriously deficient overall along the axes GOV–MHTI (and vice versa), GOV–ARB, GOV–KBI, ARB–KBI (and vice versa), MHTI–ARB, in bi-directional terms (proactive and passive inter-linkages); (2) this deficiency is compounded by the isolation of ARBs, absence of MHTI– ARB and KBI's passive MHTI–KBI, inter-linkages; (3) the inter-actor dialogue on innovation and innovation policy is therefore far from complete with respect to GOV–MHTI, GOV–ARB, GOV–KBI, MHTI–ARB (and vice versa) and ARB–KBI (and vice versa) inter-linkages; and (4) the lateral side of the TH-4 (GOV–MHTI) on which innovation policy, industrial policy and industrial innovation should be manifest is entirely missing.

The policy recommendations to address these asymmetries, defects and deficiencies include; (1) initiation of a formal consultative process on innovativeness and innovation in the national economy; (2) harmonising standards, managerial requirements and governance across KBIs; (3) eliminating constraints preventing public-sector institutions from engaging in STEMIT activities with the private sector; and (4) adopting common performance agreements (linked to funding) that have external relationship indicators across KBIs.Footnote15

Latent factors to barriers to innovation – ALL respondents

The variables which constrain innovation and innovativeness in Ghana were measured on a Likert scaleFootnote16 and factor analysed. The results are presented in : Latent factors to barriers to innovation (ALL) below.

Table 2. Factors underlying barriers to innovation

In , total variance explained (TVE) indicates the amount of variance (variation) accounted for by the factor. It signals the extent of the influence of the factor. The Kaiser-Meyer-Olkin (KMO) is a measure of sampling adequacy and indicates the robustness and reliability of factors. The Bartlett's test of sphericity (BTS) designates the significant confidence level regarding the coherence of factors, reproducibility and generalisability of the resultsFootnote17 (Kaiser Citation1974, Dziuban and Shirkey Citation1974, 359, Kim and Mueller Citation1978, 54, Rummel Citation1970). Also the dominant heuristic for describing internal consistency and reliability using Cronbach's alpha, is indicated in (George and Mallery Citation2003, Kline Citation1998, Cortina Citation1993).

Table 3. Internal consistency of factor

Four factors are responsible for 58.7% of the total variance of the variables constituting barriers to innovation in the GNSI. The reliabilities between 0.757 and 0.833 are deemed ‘acceptable’ and ‘good’. The coherence of the factors is indicated by the ‘meritorious’ KMO of 0.817 and the highly significant BTS. From a dimensional perspective, the four factors suggest that the barriers to innovation and innovativeness in the GNSI are: (1) organisational capital; (2) market transactional dysfunctions; (3) fiscal shortfalls; and (4) organisational risks.

In , Factor 1 <Skills–ICT Capability/Capacity> is the highest, most significant barrier to innovation in the GNSI, in which ‘Quality of Technically Trained Manpower’ is the most crucial variable. Factor 1 accounts for 63.5% (0.7972×100) of the variation in this variable.

Factors 2 <Unsophisticated Markets>, 3 <Deficient Fiscal Policy> and 4 <Reduced Organisational Risks> are also significant barriers to innovation; however, individually each explains less than a third of the TVE of Factor 1. These factors account for 79.6%, 59.3% and 64.5% of the variation in the variables ‘Lack of Demanding Customers’, ‘Lack of Finance’ and ‘Excessive Perceived Economic Risk’, respectively.

Factor 1 affirms our TH-4 model and underlines the critical importance of talent and the diffuseness of ICT for enhancing the stocks and flows of DISK and skills. These forms of intangible or organisational capital (Corrado et al. Citation2006, Kim Citation2007, Sullivan and Sullivan Citation2000) are crucial in cohering the NSI (Niosi Citation2002).

Factor 2, consistent with findings in the literature (Bartels et al. Citation2012, Delgado et al. Citation2012, Porter Citation1990), demonstrates the consensus on the importance of markets for driving innovation through demanding customers, innovative customers and competition.

The key policy implication is that without threshold levels in skills-ICT capability/capacity economy-wide innovativeness and innovation is extremely difficult to attain.Footnote18 Specifically, policy implications include: (1) in resource constrained circumstances, the crucial choice is for fiscal and monetary incentives, as well as regulation, standards and performance requirements, to be directed to improve the most significant Factor 1 <Skills-ICT Capability/Capacity>, through improving the ‘Quality of Technically Trained Manpower’ and the ‘Rate of Access to ICT’; and (2) in terms of the sequencing of policy implementationFootnote19; F1 <Skills-ICT Capability/Capacity> is relatively short term (1-3 years) given the capacity aspect of ICT; F2 <Unsophisticated Markets> and F3 <Deficient Fiscal Policy> are medium-term (3-5 years) given the legislative aspect of fiscal policy; F4 <Reduced Organisational Risks> is long term (5-10 years) given organisational culture and time taken to change institutional behavior.Footnote20

Conclusions

The results of our TH-4 approach to mapping and measuring the GNSI show evidently that firstly, in terms of actor importance and strength of inter-linkages, the GNSI is asymmetrically oriented with a bias to KBI–GOV and GOV–MHTI. Secondly, significant relationships GOV–KBI, GOV–MHTI and MHTI–GOV, ARB–KBI and KBI–ARB, MHTI–ARB, GOV–ARB are missing. Thirdly, the factors that underlie the barriers to innovation and innovativeness are identified as absence of skills, markets, finances and presence of risks.

In mapping and measuring empirically the GNSI, we have found significant gaps, asymmetries, low densities and weaknesses in the distribution of intra- and inter- linkages in the multifaceted relationships among and between the core actors. We have also identified significantly high barriers to innovation. These deficiencies point to a GNSI that is far from a well-integrated TH-4 model. The policy implications of these deficiencies have serious consequences for the rate at which the country may develop economically despite recent indications of confidence reflected in increased investment flows (UNCTAD Citation2013). The findings may be articulated in the following dimensions: (1) high information asymmetries – which signify that risks cannot be adequately priced with confidence that encourages innovativeness by entrepreneurs; (2) extensive co-ordination failures – which mean misapplication of precious resources as well as truncated public goods provision; (3) serious lack of significant externalities – that point to isolation of innovative activities; (4) glacial flows of DISK – which denotes that investments in human capital are largely unrealised; (5) an ineffective framework of incentives – which results in the inability of government to shape the innovation landscape to its purposes; (6) lack of connectivity between actors – which means that barriers to innovation are likely to be persistent; and (6) unarticulated policy levers – which suggest that the government strategic intentions are unlikely to be achieved.

NSI and the triple helix approach are increasingly the salient ingredient of economic development policy (Natario et al. Citation2012, Chang and Lin Citation2012). Our mapping and measurement of the NSI using the TH-4 framework and applying the DASI to all four actors simultaneously provides a comprehensive view of the GNSI. Our methodology is not only parsimonious in transaction costs but also results in an enhanced rate of survey responses. The use of FOSS to deploy the DASI-V1 is an innovative methodology that is advantageous in resource constrained developing economies, attempting to generate coherent evidence-based policies on science, technology and innovation.Footnote21

These results and recommendations enable policy makers to target specificities and to use the DASI-V1 to monitor policy implementation and effectiveness. More importantly they enable policy makers to decide effectively on the inevitable trade-offs involved in policy craft for economic development on the basis of robust evidence.

Notes

1 See the Communications Infrastructure measurement in the Competitiveness Framework Structure of the determinants of national competitiveness in Delgado et al. (Citation2012, Appendix Table A1, 45).

2 Under the direction of Frank L. Bartels in the UNIDO Statistical Research and Regional Analysis Unit.

3 Thus achieving a high level of internal and construct validity.

4 In 2007 the questionnaire was sent to Prof. J. Howells at the Centre for Research on Innovation and Competition (CRIC), UK and Prof. S. Mani at the Centre for Development Studies, India, for peer review, additional suggestions and inputs.

5 As classified by Institute of International Finance (IIF), Egypt, Morocco, Chile, Peru, Malaysia, Thailand and the Ukraine – these countries were chosen as either no survey had been conducted or not for a long time.

6 The Survey of Surveys of Innovation was conducted by Ms. Simone Carneiro, UNIDO Consultant in 2007.

7 A breakdown of the 128 surveys conducted indicates: 60 Emerging Europe, 34 Latin America 19 Asia and 15 Africa/ Middle East.

8 Etzkowitz, H. (2003), Research groups as ‘quasi-firms’: the invention of the entrepreneurial university. Research Policy 32: 109–121, Leydesdorff, L. (2005). The triple helix model and the study of knowledge-based innovation systems. International Journal of Contemporary Sociology 42(1), Shinn, T. (2002), The triple helix and new production of knowledge: pre-packaged thinking on science and technology. Social Studies of Science 32(4): 599–614, Leydesdorff, L. and Meyer, M. (2006), Triple helix indicators of knowledge-based innovation systems: introduction to the special issue. Research Policy 35(10): 1441–1449.

9 Given the specific targeting of respondents in the four communities respectively, the survey participation invitation email, sent en-masse to all respondents, contains a link leading to the electronic questionnaire. To enhance data reliability and validity, the link was equipped with an authorisation token to restrict the access of people who had not received a token and ensure that each respondent was only able to answer the questionnaire once.

10 These range from≥0.400 to≥0.600.

11 % GDP spent on R&D – South Africa 0.9, Ghana 0.2, Kenya 0.4, Tanzania 0.4, Botswana 0.5. Sources: The World Bank (2012), World Development Indicators. Research and development expenditure % of GDP, 2005–2007, Washington, DC: The World Bank.

12 The expenditure on KBIs by government with respect to research and development is erratic while allocations to CSIR-STIPR are utilised 81% for staff costs and 9% for research (UNCTAD, Citation2011).

13 According to UNCTAD (Citation2011) the low expenditure on R&D is hardly compensated for by either the private sector efforts which amount to about 2% of all funding for R&D or arbitrageurs. These figures represent the importance given to Science, Technology, Engineering, Mathematics and Information Technology (STEMIT) in national priorities; and the serious challenges facing the implementation of the technology and innovation policies indicated in the Ghana Industrial Policy.

14 That is, the transformation function of RI and ISTC in respect to innovation in contrast to the transaction, or exchange, function via market mechanisms and price signalling (Dunning Citation2003).

15 For a comprehensive view of recommendations see UNIDO (Citation2012), Evidence-based policy making: the Ghana national system of innovation – measurement, analysis & policy recommendations, UNIDO, Vienna 2012, authored by Frank L. Bartels and Ritin Koria.

16 1 – Very High Constraint, 2 – High Constraint, 3 – Neutral, 4 – Low Constraint and 5 – Very Low Constraint.

17 Arbitrageurs did not produce a factor result as the number of respondents, while entirely adequate for cross-tabulation, did not meet the statistical requirements necessary to conduct a factor analysis.

18 With respect to the global competitiveness index (GCI), Ghana's ranking across a range of indicators relevant to innovation is: GCI 2010–2011 (out of 139) = 114; GCI 2009–2010 (out of 133) = 114; GCI 2008–2009 (out of 134) = 102. Innovation and sophistication factors = 100 (Business sophistication = 97; Innovation = 99); Basic requirements = 122 (Institutions = 67; Infrastructure = 106; Macroeconomic environment = 136; Health and primary education = 122); Efficiency enhancers = 96 (Higher education and training = 108; Goods market efficiency = 75; Labour market efficiency = 93; Financial market development = 60; Technological readiness = 117; Market size = 83). Source: World Economic Forum, 2010. The Global Competitiveness Report 2010–2011.

19 Notwithstanding the electoral cycle, or the time taken for legislative and regulatory processes to place policy on statute via parliamentary fiscal and monetary decisions (white paper, green paper, committee stage, bill and law). It is fully recognised firstly that such temporal characteristics are subject economically to the consequences (time delay, dislocation, discontinuities) of: (1) exogenous shocks; (2) market failures; and (3) government failures. Secondly, policy business plans and managerial actions are expected to be of a ‘rolling’ nature in order to attain, through incremental advances, as well as accelerated spurts, higher levels of innovativeness and innovation throughout the economy in the long-term.

20 While Ghana has improved its performance in the World Bank ‘Doing Business’ variables since 2004 much more needs to be done. Scrutiny of Ghana's performance in the ‘Doing Business’ surveys shows relative decline in the face of absolute improvements from 2004–2012 in: starting a business; dealing with construction permits; getting electricity; registering property; getting credit; paying taxes; trading across borders (but costs have risen); enforcing contracts; resolving insolvency. No improvement in protecting investors. However, despite these improvements, Ghana's rank position has slipped between 2011 and 2012 in all the above categories except: getting electricity; enforcing contracts and resolving insolvency. With reference to a key variable in innovation, starting a business, Ghana slipped 19 rank positions between 2011 and 2012. See IFC (International Finance Corporation) and World Bank, 2012. Doing Business 2012: Doing Business in a More Transparent World. Economy Profile: Ghana. Washington DC: The World Bank Group.

21 See final technical report, national innovation systems of BRICS countries, IDRC Center File 10422-1001, September 2007 to October 2010.

References

  • Achim, I.M. and Popescu, T. (2009), The systemic approach to national innovation systems in a knowledge-based economy. Annales Universitatis Apulensis: Series Oeconomica 11(2): 946–952.
  • Andersen, E.S. and Lundvall, B.-Å. (1988), Small national innovation systems facing technological revolutions: an analytical framework. In Freeman, C. and Lundvall, B.-Å. (eds), Small countries facing the technological revolution, London: Pinter Publishers.
  • Archibugi, D. and Iammarino, S. (1999), The policy implications of the globalisation of innovation. Research Policy 28: 317–336. doi: 10.1016/S0048-7333(98)00116-4
  • Arocena, R. and Sutz, J. (2000), Looking at national systems of innovation from the South. Industry & Innovation 7(1): 55–75. doi: 10.1080/713670247
  • Arrighi, G. (2002), The African crisis: world systemic and regional aspects. New Left Review 15.
  • Arrow, K. (1962), Economic welfare and the allocation of resources for invention. In: National Bureau Committee for Economic Research and Committee on Economic Growth of the Social Science Research Council, editors the rate and direction of inventive activity: economic and social factors – A conference of the universities. Princeton, NJ.
  • Asheim, B.T. and Coenen, L. (2004), The role of regional innovation systems in a globalizing economy: comparing knowledge bases and institutional frameworks of Nordic clusters. Working Paper 03/2005. Lund: Centre for Innovation, Research and Competence in the Learning Economy (CIRCLE).
  • Avnimelech, G. and Teubal, M. (2005), Evolutionary innovation and high tech policies: what can we learn from the Israel's targeting of venture capital? Science, Technology and Economic Program (SETE). Working Paper Series WP-25-2005, Neaman Institute, Technion-Israel Institute of Technology.
  • Avnimelech, G. and Teubal, M. (2006), Creating venture capital industries that co-evolve with high tech: Insights from an extended industry life cycle perspective of the Israeli experience. Research Policy 35(10): 1477–1498. doi: 10.1016/j.respol.2006.09.017
  • Bagozzi, R.P. and Yi, Y. (1998), On the evolution of structural equation models. Academy of Marketing Science 16(1): 74–94. doi: 10.1007/BF02723327
  • Balzat, M. (2002), The theoretical basis and the empirical treatment of national innovation systems. Institute for Economics, University of Augsburg, Paper No 232.
  • Barro, R.J. (1998), Determinants of economic growth: a cross-country empirical study, 1st edn., vol. 1. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.
  • Bartels, F.L. (2007), Industry in growth and development: a review of contending development policy advisory directions. Staff Working Paper 01/2007, June. Vienna: Research and Statistics Branch, UNIDO.
  • Bartels, F.L., Buckley, P. and Mariano, G. (2009), Multinational enterprises’ foreign direct investment location decisions within the global factory. Working Paper 04/2009, Vienna: Research and Statistics Branch, UNIDO.
  • Bartels, F.L. and Lederer, S. (2009), Changing patterns in industrial performance – A UNIDO competitive industrial performance perspective: Implications for industrial development. Working Papers, No. 05/2009, Vienna: Research and Statistics Branch, UNIDO.
  • Bartels, F. and Voss, H. (2005), Determinants of national innovation systems. 14th International Conference for the International Association of Management of Technology, Vienna, 22– 26 May 2005.
  • Bartels, F., Voss, H., Bachtrog, C. and Lederer, S. (2012), Determinants of national innovation systems: policy implications for developing countries. Innovation Management Policy and Practice 14(1): 2–18. doi: 10.5172/impp.2012.14.1.2
  • Baruch, Y. (1999), Response rate in academic studies – A comparative analysis. Human Relations 52(4): 421–438.
  • Baygan, G. and Freudenberg, M. (2000), The internationalisation of venture capital activity in OECD countries: implications for measurement and policy. OECD Science, Technology and Industry Working Papers 2000/7, Paris: OECD.
  • Becheikh, N., Landry, R. and Amara, N. (2006), Lessons from innovation empirical studies in the manufacturing sector: a systematic review of the literature from 1993–2003. Technovation 26: 644–664. doi: 10.1016/j.technovation.2005.06.016
  • Berdie, D.R. (1973), Questionnaire length and response rate. Journal of Applied Psychology 58(2): 278–280. doi: 10.1037/h0035427
  • Berrens, R.P. et al. (2003), The advent of internet surveys for political research: a comparison of telephone and internet samples. Political Analysis 11(1): 1–22. doi: 10.1093/pan/11.1.1
  • Bjørnskov, C. and Svendsen, G.T. (2002), Why does the Northern light shine so brightly? decentralisation, social capital and the economy. Working Paper 15/2002. Aarhus: Aarhus School of Business.
  • Bjørnskov, C. and Svendsen, T.G. (2004), Measuring social capital – is there a single underlying explanation? Working Paper 03-05, Aarhus: Aarhus School of Business.
  • Bowles, T.V. (2006), The adaptive change model: an advance on the transtheoritical model of change. Journal of Psychoogy 140(5): 439–457. doi: 10.3200/JRLP.140.5.439-457
  • Braadland, T.E. and Anders, E. (2002), Innovation in Norwegian industries – testing a new taxonomy. STEP Report Series 200206. Oslo: The STEP Group.
  • Bramwell, A., Hepburn, N. and Wolfe, D.A. (2012), Growing innovation ecosystems: university-industry knowledge transfer and regional economic development in Canada, Knowledge Synthesis Paper on Leveraging Investments in HERD, Final Report to the Social Sciences and Humanities Research Council of Canada.
  • Buckley, P.J. and Carter, M.J. (2004), A formal analysis of knowledge combination in multinational enterprises. Journal of International Business Studies 35(5): 371–384. doi: 10.1057/palgrave.jibs.8400095
  • Buckley, P.J. and Casson, M. (2002), The future of the multinational enterprise: 25th anniversary edition, London: Palgrave Macmillan.
  • Buckley, P.J. and Hashai, N. (2004), A global systems view of firm boundaries. Journal of International Business Studies 35(1): 33–45. doi: 10.1057/palgrave.jibs.8400059
  • Carlsson, B., Jacobsson, S., Holmén, M. and Rickne, A. (2002), Innovation system: analytical and methodological issues. Research Policy 31(2): 233–245. doi: 10.1016/S0048-7333(01)00138-X
  • Carlsson, B. (2006), Internationalisation of innovation systems: a survey of literature. Research Policy 35: 56–67. doi: 10.1016/j.respol.2005.08.003
  • Cassiolato, J. and Lastres, H. (2000), Local systems of innovation in Mercosur countries, Industry and Innovation 7(1): 33–53. doi: 10.1080/713670250
  • Chaminade, C., Intarakumnerd, P. and Sapprasertc, K. (2012), Measuring systemic problems in national innovation systems. an application to Thailand. Research Policy 41(8): 1476–1488. doi: 10.1016/j.respol.2012.04.004
  • Chang, S.H. and Lin, P.H. (2012), A preliminary study on the structural model of national innovation capability. Journal of International Management Studies 7(1): 128–137.
  • Clason, D.L. and Dormody, T.J. (1994), Analyzing data measured by individual Likert-type items. Journal of Agriculture and Education 35(4): 4–35.
  • Cobanoglu, C., Warde, B. and Moreo, P.J. (2001), A comparison of mail, fax and web-based survey methods. International Journal of Market Research 43(4): 441–452.
  • Comin, D. (2004), R&D: a small contribution to productivity growth. NBER Working Paper 10625.
  • Corrado, C.A., Hulten, C.R. and Sichel, D.E. (2006), Intangible capital and economic growth, NBER Working Paper No. 11948.
  • Cortina, J.M. (1993), What is coefficient alpha? An examination of theory and applications. Journal of Applied Psychology 78(1): 98–104. doi: 10.1037/0021-9010.78.1.98
  • Cudeck, R. and O'Dell, L.L. (1994), Applications of standard error estimates in unrestricted factor analysis: significance tests for factor loadings and correlations. Psychological Bulletin 115(3): 475–487. doi: 10.1037/0033-2909.115.3.475
  • Cycyota, C.S. and Harrison, D.A. (2006), What (not) to expect when surveying executives. Organizational Research Methods 9(2): 133–60. doi: 10.1177/1094428105280770
  • Da Motta e Albuquerque, E. (1999), National systems of innovation and non-OECD countries: notes about a rudimentary and tentative ‘typology’. Brazilian Journal of Political Economy 19(4),
  • Daneke, G.A. (1998), Beyond Schumpeter: non-linear economics and the evolution of the US innovation system. Journal of Socio-Economics 27(1): 97–117. doi: 10.1016/S1053-5357(99)80079-1
  • Dasgupta, P. (2002), Social capital and economic performance: pnalytics. In Ostrom, Elinor and Ahn, Toh-Kyeong (eds.), Social capital: a reader. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.
  • Delgado, M., Ketels, C., Porter, M.E. and Stern, S. (2012), The determinants of national competitiveness, NBER Working Paper No. 18249.
  • Dillman, D.A. (2000), Mail and internet surveys: the tailored designed method, 2nd edn. New York: Wiley.
  • DiMaggio, P. and Hargittai, E. (2001), From the ‘digital divide’ to ‘digital inequality’: studying internet use as penetration increases, Center for Arts and Cultural Policy Studies, Princeton University, Working Paper No 15.
  • Dosi, G., Freeman, C., Nelson, R.R., Silverberg, G. and Soete, L. (1988), Technical change and economic theory. London: Pinter.
  • Dunning, J.H. (2003), Some antecedents of internalization theory. Journal of International Business Studies 34(2): 108–115. doi: 10.1057/palgrave.jibs.8400010
  • Durlauf, S.N. and Quah, D.T. (1998), The new empirics of economic growth. Working Paper 6422. The National Bureau of Economic Research, Cambridge, MA.
  • Dziuban, C.D. and Shirkey, E.S. (1974), When is a correlation matrix appropriate for factor analysis? some decision rules. Psychological Bulletin 81: 358–361. doi: 10.1037/h0036316
  • Edquist, C. (1997), Systems of innovation: technologies, institutions and organizations. London: Pinter.
  • Edquist, C. (2001), The systems of innovation approach and innovation policy: an account of the state of the art. DRUID Summer Conference, Aalborg, Denmark.
  • Edquist, C. and Johnson, B. (1997), Institutions and organizations in systems of innovation. In Edquist, C. (ed.), Systems of innovation, technologies, institutions and organizations, pp. 41–63. London: Pinter.
  • Etkowitz, H. and Leydersdorff, L. (1996), Emergence of a triple helix university-industry-government relations. Science and Public Policy 23(5): 279–286.
  • Etzkowitz, H. and Leydesdorff, L. (2000), The dynamics of innovation: from national systems and ‘mode 2’ to a triple helix of university-industry-government relations. Research Policy 29: 109–123. doi: 10.1016/S0048-7333(99)00055-4
  • Etzkowitz, H. (2003), Research groups as ‘quasi-firms’: the invention of the entrepreneurial university. Research Policy 32: 109–121. doi: 10.1016/S0048-7333(02)00009-4
  • Everitt, B.S. (2002), The Cambridge dictionary of statistics, 2nd edn., p. 140. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
  • Farina, C. and Preissl, B. (1999), Research and technology organisations in national systems of innovation. Chapter 6 in Research and technology organisations in the service economy, RISE project. Brighton: University of Brighton.
  • Fisher, M., Revilla-Diaz, J. and Snickars, F. (2001), Metropolitan innovation system: theory and evidence from metropolitan regions in Europe. New York: Springer.
  • Foxon, T., Makuch, Z., Mata, M. and Pearson, P. (2004), Innovation systems and policy-making processes for the transition to sustainability. In Klaus Jacob, Klaus, Binder, Manfred and Wieczorek, Anna (eds.), Governance for Industrial Transformation. Proceedings of the 2003 Berlin Conference on the Human Dimensions of Global Environmental Change. pp. 96–112. Berlin: Environmental Policy Research Centre.
  • Freeman, C. (1987), Technology policy and economic performance: lessons from Japan. London: Pinter.
  • Freeman, C. (1995), The ‘national system of innovation’ in historical perspective. Cambridge Journal of Economics 19: 5–25.
  • Freeman, C. (2002), Continental, national and sub-national innovation systems – complementarity and economic growth, Research Policy, 31: 191–211. doi: 10.1016/S0048-7333(01)00136-6
  • Gaba, V. and Bhattacharya, S. (2011), Aspirations, innovation and corporate venture capital: a behavioral perspective. INSEAD Working Paper 2011/126/OB/TOM.
  • Garland, R. (1991), The mid-point on a rating scale: is it desirable? Research Note 3, Marketing Bulletin 2: 66–70.
  • Gatignon H., Tushman M.L., Smith W. and Anderson P. (2001), A structural approach to assessing innovation: construct development of innovation locus, type and characteristics, INSEAD Working Paper, 21 November 2001/97/MKT.
  • Gatignon, H., Tushman, M.L., Smith, W. and Anderson, P. (2002), A Structural Approach to Assessing Innovation: Construct Development of Innovation Locus, Type and Characteristics, INSEAD Working Paper, May 2002/71/MKT.
  • Gaur, S. (1997), Adelman and Morris factor analysis of developing countries. Journal of Policy Modeling 19(4) 407–415. doi: 10.1016/S0161-8938(96)00062-2
  • George, D. and Mallery, P. (2003), SPSS for Windows step by step: a simple guide and reference. 11.0 update, 4th edn. Boston: Allyn & Bacon.
  • Gera, S., Roy, R. and Songsakul, T. (2006), The role of benchmarks and targets in Canadian innovation policy. In Earl, L. and Gault, F. (eds.), National innovation indicators and policy. p. 58. Northampton: Edward Elgar Publishing. Global Information Technology Report 2012
  • Greenwood, J. and Jovanovic, B. (1998), Accounting for growth. NBER Working Paper No. 6647.
  • Groenewegen, J. and van der Steen, M. (2006), The evolution of national innovation systems. Journal of Economic Issues 40: 277–285.
  • Hair, F.J., Anderson, R.E., Tatham, R.L. and Black, W.C. (1998), Multivariate data analysis, 5th edn. New Jersey: Prentice Hall.
  • Hall, B.H. (2004), Innovation and diffusion. NBER Working Paper 10212.
  • Hall, B.H. and Mairesse, J. (2006), Empirical studies of innovation in the knowledge driven economy, NBER Working Paper No. 12320.
  • Harzing, A.W. (2007), Journal quality list, 28th edn. Available at: http://www.harzing.com
  • Hilbert, M., P., López and C., Vásquez (2010), Information societies or ‘ICT equipment societies?’ Measuring the digital information-processing capacity of a society in bits and bytes. The Information Society 26(3): 157–178. doi: 10.1080/01972241003712199
  • Hollingsworth, R. and Boyer, R. (eds.) (1997), Contemporary capitalism: the embeddedness of institutions. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
  • Intarakumnerd, P., Chairatana, P. and Tangchitpiboon, T. (2002), National innovation systems in less successful developing countries: the case of Thailand. Research Policy 31: 1445–1457. doi: 10.1016/S0048-7333(02)00074-4
  • Jaffe, A.B., Lerner, J. and Stern, S. (2001), Innovation policy and the economy, vol. 1. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.
  • Jovanovic, B. and Rob, R. (1989), The growth and diffusion of knowledge. Review of Economic Studies 56: 569–582. doi: 10.2307/2297501
  • Kaiser, H.F. (1960), The application of electronic computers to factor analysis. Educational and Psychological Measurement 20: 141–151. doi: 10.1177/001316446002000116
  • Kaiser, H.F. (1974), An Index of Factorial Simplicity. Psychometrika 39: 31–36. doi: 10.1007/BF02291575
  • Kaiser, R., Prange, H. (2004), The reconfiguration of National Innovation Systems – the example of German biotechnology. Research Policy 33(3): 395–408. doi: 10.1016/j.respol.2003.09.001
  • Kim, Y.G. (2007), A survey on intangible capital, centre for economic institutions. Working Paper Series, CEI No. 2007-10, Institute of Economic Research, Hitotsubashi University, Japan.
  • Kim, J.O. and Mueller, C.W. (1978), Factor analysis: statistical methods and practical issues. Quantitative applications in social sciences series, 14. Thousand Oaks, CA: Sage.
  • Kline, R.B. (1998), Principles and practice of structural equation modeling. New York: Guilford Press.
  • Koria, R., Bartels, F.L., Andriano, L., Köszegi, S. (2014), Effectiveness and efficiency of national systems of innovation: the importance of ict, the cases of Ghana and Kenya. In Cunningham, Paul and Cunningham, Miriam (eds.), IST-Africa 2014 Conference Proceedings, Mauritius, 6–9 May 2014. International Information Management Corporation.
  • Koria, R., Bartels, F.L., Köszegi, S. and Carneiro, S. (2012), Free open source software (FOSS) and survey methodologies: the case of the Ghana national system of innovation survey, In Cunningham, Paul and Cunningham, Miriam (eds.), IST-Africa 2012 Conference Proceedings, Dar es Salaam 9–11 May 2012. International Information Management Corporation.
  • Koria, R. and Köszegi, S. (2011), National systems of innovation (NSI): measurement and implications for science technology and innovation policy in Ghana. UNIDO Conference on Competitiveness & Diversification: Strategic Challenges in a Petroleum-Rich Economy. Accra, Ghana 14–15 March 2011, p.8.
  • Kremp, E. and Mairesse, J. (2004), Knowledge management, innovation and productivity: a firm level exploration based on French manufacturing CIS3 data. The National Bureau of Economic Research, working paper No. 10237.
  • Labovitz, S. (1967), Some observations on measurement and statistics. Social Forces 46(2): 151–160. doi: 10.2307/2574595
  • Labovitz, S. (1970), The assignment of numbers to rank order categories. American Sociological Review 35(2): 515–524. doi: 10.2307/2092993
  • Labovitz, S. (1971), In defence of assigning numbers to ranks. American Sociological Review 36(4): 521–22. doi: 10.2307/2093099
  • Lastres, H.M.M., Cassiolato, J.E. and Maciel, M.L. (2005), Systems of innovation for development in the knowledge era: an introduction. In Cassiolato, J.E., Lastres, H.M.M. and Maciel, M.L. Systems of innovation and development – evidence from Brazil. Cheltenham, Northampton, MA: Edward Elgar.
  • Leydesdorff, L. (2001), Knowledge-based innovation systems and the model of a triple helix of university-industry-government relations. In: Universitá degli Studi di Salerno, Conference on New Economic Windows: Paradigms for the New Millennium. Salerno, Italy.
  • Leydesdorff, L. and Etzkowitz, H. (1996), Emergence of a triple helix of university-industry-government relations. Science and Public Policy 23(5): 279–286
  • Leydesdorff, L. and Meyer, M. (2006), Triple helix indicators of knowledge-based innovation systems: introduction to the special issue. Research Policy 35.
  • Leydesdorff, L. (2012), The triple helix, quadruple helix and an n-tuple of helices: explanatory models for analyzing the knowledge-based economy? Journal of the Knowledge Economy 3(1): 25–35. doi: 10.1007/s13132-011-0049-4
  • List, F. (1841), The national system of political economy, English edn. (1904). London: Longman.
  • Lozar, K.M. and Vehovar, V. Chapter 14 – Internet Surveys., In De Leeuw, E.D., Hox, J.J. and Dillman, D.A. International handbook of survey methodology. London: CRC Press.
  • Lundvall, B.Å. (1985), Product innovation and user-producer interaction. Aalborg: Aalborg University Press.
  • Lundvall, B-Å. (2007), National innovation systems – analytical concept and development tool. Industry and Innovation 14(1), 95–119. doi: 10.1080/13662710601130863
  • Lundvall, B-Å. (ed.) (1992), National systems of innovation: towards a theory of innovation and interactive learning, London: Pinter.
  • Lundvall, B.-Å. (ed.) (1995), National systems of innovation: towards a theory of innovation and interactive learning. London, New York: Pinter.
  • Lundvall, B.Ă (1998), Why study national systems and national styles of innovation? Technology Analysis & Strategic Management, 10(4): 407–421. doi: 10.1080/09537329808524324
  • Lundvall, B-Å. (2003), National Innovation Systems: History and Theory. Working Paper. Aalborg University.
  • Lundvall, B.Å., Johnson, B. Andersen, E.S. and Dalum, B. (2002), National systems of production, innovation and competence building. Research Policy 31(2): 213–231. doi: 10.1016/S0048-7333(01)00137-8
  • Malerba, F. (2002), Sectoral systems of innovation and production. Research Policy 31: 247–264. doi: 10.1016/S0048-7333(01)00139-1
  • Mattel, M.S. and Jacoby, J. (1972), Is there an optimal number of alternatives for Likert-scale items? Journal of Applied Psychology 56: 506–509. doi: 10.1037/h0033601
  • Mohnen, P., Mairesse, J. and Dagenais, M. (2006), Innovativity: a comparison across seven European countries, NBER Working Paper No. 12280.
  • Moldaschl, M. (2010), Why innovation theories make no sense, Department of Innovation Research and Sustainable Resource Management (BWL IX), Chemnitz University of Technology, Paper No. 9/2010, July.
  • Montalvo, C. and Moghayer, S. (2012), State of an innovation system: theoretical and empirical advance towards an innovation efficiency index, Paper presented at DRUID 2012 Conference, June 19–21, Copenhagen Business School, Copenhagen, Denmark, Available at: http://druid8. sit.aau.dk/acc_papers/ukybfr5naguxynl4a7970lerkrp5.pdf [Accessed 10 December 2014]
  • Mueller, D. (2003), Public choice. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
  • Muffo, J.M., Sinclair, A. and Robson, V. (2003), A comparison of web versus paper alumni surveys. Paper presented at the Annual Forum of the Association for Institutional Research, Tampa, USA, 17–21 May.
  • Munk, K.B. and Vintergaard, C. (2004), Venture capitalists in systems of innovation. MPP Working Paper No. 1/2004, Department of Management, Politics and Philosophy, Copenhagen Business School.
  • Nasierowski, W. and Arcelus, F.J. (1999), Interrelationships among the elements of national innovation systems: a statistical evaluation. European Journal of Operational Research, 119: 235–253. doi: 10.1016/S0377-2217(99)00128-9
  • Natario, M.M., Couto, J.P. and De Almeida, C.F. (2012), The triple helix model and dynamics of innovation: a case study. Journal of Knowledge-based Innovation in China, 4(1). doi: 10.1108/17561411211208758
  • Nelson, E.R. (1963), National innovation systems: a comparative analysis. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
  • Nelson, R.R. (1993), National innovation systems: a comparative analysis. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
  • Nelson, R.R. and Phelps, E.S. (1966), Investments in humans, technological diffusion and economic growth. American Economic Review 56: 69–75.
  • Niosi, J. (2002), National systems of innovations are ’x-inefficient’ (and x-effective) – why some are slow learners. Research Policy 31: 291–302. doi: 10.1016/S0048-7333(01)00142-1
  • Nooteboom, B., DeJong, G., Vossen, R.W., Helper, S. and Sako, M. (1998), Competence in mutual dependence. Conference paper for DRUID conference on competence, governance and entrepreneurship, Bornholm, Denmark, 9–11 June 1998.
  • OECD (1992), Technology and the economy – The key relationships. Paris: OECD.
  • OECD (1999), Managing national innovation systems. Paris: OECD.
  • OECD (2002), Dynamising national innovation systems. Paris: OECD.
  • OECD (2011), OECD science, technology and industry scoreboard 2011: innovation and growth in knowledge economies.
  • Oinas, P. and Malecki, E.J. (2002), The evolution of technologies in time and space: from national and regional to spatial innovation systems. International Regional Science Review 25(1): 102–131. doi: 10.1177/016001702762039402
  • Olsen, S.B. (2009), Choosing between internet and mail survey modes for choice experiment surveys considering non-market goods. Environmental and Resource Economics 44(4): 591–610. doi: 10.1007/s10640-009-9303-7
  • Park, Y. and Park, G. (2003), When does a national innovation system start to exhibit systematic behaviour? Industry and Innovation 10: 403–414. doi: 10.1080/1366271032000163649
  • Patel, P. and Pavitt, K. (1994), National innovation systems: why they are important and how they might be measured and compared. Economics of Innovation and New Technology 3(1): 77–95. doi: 10.1080/10438599400000004
  • Pavitt, K. (1984), Sectoral patterns of technical change: towards a taxonomy and a theory. Research Policy 13(6): 343–373. doi: 10.1016/0048-7333(84)90018-0
  • Porter, M.E. (1990), The competitive advantage of nations. London: Macmillan.
  • Quatraro, F. (2012), The economics of structural change in knowledge. London: Routledge.
  • Ricart, J.E., Enright, M.J., Ghemawat, P., Hart, S.L. and Khanna, T. (2004), New frontiers in international strategy. Journal of International Business Studies 35: 175–200. doi: 10.1057/palgrave.jibs.8400080
  • Richardson, G.B. (1972) The organization of industry, Economic Journal 82(327): 883–896. doi: 10.2307/2230256
  • Rockefeller Foundation (2003), Knowledge flows and knowledge collectives: understanding the role of science and technology policies in development. Vol. 1, Global Inclusion Program.
  • Rodrik, D. and Subramanian, A. (2003), The primacy of institutions. Finance & Development, June 2003: 31–34.
  • Rogers, E.M. (2003), Diffusion of innovations. 5th edn. New York: Free Press
  • Romer, P.M. (1990), Endogenous technological change. Journal of Political Economy 98: 71–102. doi: 10.1086/261725
  • Rummel, R.J. (1970), Applied factor analysis. Evanston: North Western University Press.
  • Sábato, J.A. and Botana, N. (1968), La ciencia y la tecnología en el desarrollo futuro de América Latina. Revista de la Integración 3(11): 15–36.
  • Sachs, J. (2003), The global innovation divide. In: Jaffe, A.B., Lerner, J. and Stern, S. (eds.), NBER book innovation policy and the economy. 3: 131–141, MIT Press.
  • Samara, E., Georgiadis, P., Bakouros, I. (2012), The impact of innovation policies on the performance of national innovation systems: a system dynamics analysis. Technovation 32(11): 624. doi: 10.1016/j.technovation.2012.06.002
  • Schiller, D. (2006), Nascent innovation systems in developing countries: university responses to regional needs in Thailand, Industry and Innovation 13(4): 481–504. doi: 10.1080/13662710601032903
  • Shapiro, S.E., Lasarev, M.R. and McCauley., L. (2002), Factor analysis of Gulf War illness: what does it add to our understanding of possible health effects of deployment? American Journal of Epidemiology 156: 578–585. pmid: 12226005 doi: 10.1093/aje/kwf087
  • Solow, R. (1960), Investment and technological progress. In Arro, K., Kalin, S. and Suppes, P. (eds.). Mathematical methods in the social sciences pp. 89–104. Stanford, CA: Stanford University Press.
  • Sornn-Friese, H. (2000), Frontiers of research in industrial dynamics and national systems of innovation. Industry and Innovation 7: 1–13. doi: 10.1080/713670246
  • Squicciarini, M. and Le Mouel, M. (2012), Defining and measuring investment in organisational capital: using US microdata to develop a task-based approach. OECD Science, Technology and Industry Working Papers 2012/05, OECD Publishing. http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/5k92n2t3045b-en
  • Stern, S., Porter, M.E. and Furman, J.L. (2000), The determinants of national innovative capacity, NBER Working Paper No. 7876.
  • Stern, S., Porter, M.E. and Furman, J.L. (2002), The determinants of national innovative capacity. Research Policy 31: 899–933. doi: 10.1016/S0048-7333(01)00152-4
  • Sullivan, Jr. P.H. and Sullivan, Sr., P.H. (2000), Valuing intangibles companies – an intellectual capital approach. Journal of Intellectual Capital 1(4): 328–340. doi: 10.1108/14691930010359234
  • Swisher, L.J., Beckstead, J.W. and Bebeau, M.J. (2004), Factor analysis as a tool for survey analysis using a professional role orientation inventory as an example. Journal of the American Physical Therapy Association 84: 784–799.
  • Tidd, J. (2006), A review of innovation models. Discussion Paper 1/1, Imperial College London, Tanake Business School.
  • Tomaskovic-Devey, D., Leiter, J. and Thompson, S. (1994), Organisational survey non-response. Administrative Science Quarterly 39(3): 439–57. doi: 10.2307/2393298
  • Tsuge, H. and Bartels, F.L. (2003), FDI promotion strategies of developing countries: A look at the spatial distribution of the automotive industry. SAIS Working Paper Series WP/06/03.
  • UNCTAD (2011), Science, technology and innovation policy Review. Geneva: UNCTAD.
  • UNCTAD (2013), World investment report 2013: global value chains: investment and trade for development. Geneva: UNCTAD.
  • UNIDO (2002/2003), Competing through innovation and learning. Industrial development report 2202/2003; UNIDO. Vienna.
  • UNIDO (2012), Evidence-based policy making: the Ghana national system of innovation – measurement, analysis and policy recommendations, UNIDO, Vienna 2012, authored by Frank L. Bartels and Ritin Koria.
  • Ushakov, D.S. (2012), Innovative capacity as a modern factor of countries’ investment attractiveness dynamic. International Journal of Organizational Innovation 4(4): 6–20.
  • Van Ark, B. and Hulten, C. (2007), Innovation, intangibles and economic growth: towards a comprehensive accounting of the knowledge economy. Yearbook on Productivity 2007. pp. 127–146. Statistics Sweden 2008.
  • Van de Ven, A. (1993), A community perspective on the emergence of innovations. Journal of Engineering and Technological Management 10: 265–298. doi: 10.1016/0923-4748(93)90071-P
  • Vania, S. (2004), The return of the prince of Denmark: A survey on recent developments in the economics of innovation. Economic Journal 114: 312–332. doi: 10.1111/j.1468-0297.2004.00225.x
  • Von Tunzelmann, G.N. (1997), Innovation and industrialization: a long-term comparison. Technological Forecasting and Social Change 56: 1–23. doi: 10.1016/S0040-1625(97)00027-9
  • Wang, Q. and von Tunzelmann, G.N. (2000), Complexity and the functions of the firm: breadth and depth. Research Policy 29(7/8): 805–818. doi: 10.1016/S0048-7333(00)00106-2
  • White, S.D., Gunasekaran, A., Shea, T.P. and Ariguzo, G.C. (2011), Mapping the global digital divide. International Journal of Business Information Systems 7(2): 207–219. doi: 10.1504/IJBIS.2011.038512
  • Wijnberg, N.M. (1994), National systems of Innovation: Selection environments and selection processes. Technology in Society 16(3): 313–320. doi: 10.1016/0160-791X(94)90005-1
  • Williamson, O.E. (1969), Allocative efficiency and the limits of antitrust. American Economic Review, American Economic Association 59(2): 105–18.
  • Williamson, O.E. (1971), The vertical integration of production: Market failure considerations. American Economic Review, American Economic Association 61(2): 112–23.
  • Williamson, O.E. (1973), Markets and hierarchies: Some elementary considerations. American Economic Review, American Economic Association 63(2): 316–25.
  • Williamson, O.E. (1985), The economic institutions of capitalism: Firms, markets, relational contracting. New York: Free Press.
  • Yeh, C.-C. and Chang, P.-L. (2003), The Taiwan system of innovation in the tool machine industry: a case study. Journal of Engineering and Technology Management 20: 367–380. doi: 10.1016/j.jengtecman.2003.08.005
  • Zook, M.A. (2003), The knowledge brokers: Venture capitalists, tacit knowledge and regional development. Paper presented at DRUID Summer Conference 2003 on Creating and Sharing, Sharing and Transferring Knowledge. The Role of Geography, Institutions and Organizations. Copenhagen, Denmark.
  • Zwane, A.P., Zinman, J., Dusene, E.V., Pariente, W., Null, C., Miguel, E., Kremer, M., Karlan, D.S., Hornbeck, R., Gin, X., Duflo, E., Devoto, F., Crepon, B. and Banerjee, A. (2010), Being surveyed can change later behavior and related parameter estimates. PNAS 108(5): 1821–1826. doi: 10.1073/pnas.1000776108