189
Views
1
CrossRef citations to date
0
Altmetric
Article

Detecting multiple equilibria for continuous dependent variables

Pages 635-656 | Published online: 05 Aug 2021
 

Abstract

This article considers structural equations where continuous dependent variables are related to independent variables and unobservables through a nonparametric function. Multiple equilibria may arise when the structural equations admit multiple solutions. This article proposes a detecting criterion for the existence of multiple equilibria. The main finding is that multiple equilibria would reveal itself in the form of jump(s) in the density function of the dependent variables. When there is a unique equilibrium, the density function of dependent variables will be continuous, whereas when there are multiple equilibria, the density will have jump(s) under reasonable conditions.

JEL Classification::

Notes

1 We use the terms dependent variables, endogenous variables, and outcome variables interchangeably.

2 For example, Berry et al. (Citation1999) assume that “the equilibrium is unique (or at least that we solve for the relevant one.)” (p. 418)

3 An alernative identification approach relies on the completeness condition of the joint distribution of the endogenous and exogenous variables [see Assumption 4 in the work by Berry and Haile (Citation2014, p. 1961)], which resembles the one used in nonparametric IV literature (Newey and Powell, Citation2003). However, the completeness condition is high level and difficult to interpret in economic models. Berry and Haile (Citation2018) commented that “a high-level assumption like completeness implicitly places further restrictions on the model, although the nature of these restrictions is typically unclear.” (p. 290)

4 Throughout this article, continuity at a point means that the limits from all directions coincide. It does not place any condition on the value of the function at the limit point. A discontinuity or a jump refers to a jump discontinuity where the directional limits are not all equal.

5 For example, equilibrium (y1,y2) is characterized by r1(y1,y2)=u1 and r2(y1,y2)=u2. One can derive the best response function y2=ϕ2(y1,u2) from the second equation and then substitute it into the first equation. This yields r1(y1,ϕ2(y1,u2))=u1, where the unobservable u2 is not separated from (y1, y2).

6 For the aforementioned example, Echenique and Komunjer (Citation2009) began with r1(y1,y2)=0 and r2(y1,y2)=0, reduce it to r1(y1,ϕ2(y1))=0 by substitution, and then add a disturbance term u to yield r1(y1,ϕ2(y1))=u.

7 Tamer (Citation2003, p. 150) defines an incomplete econometric model as the one “where the relationship from (x, u) to y is a correspondence and not a function.”

8 See Assumption 1 of Berry and Haile (Citation2014), which leads to sjt=σj(pt,δt,xt(2)), where δjt=xjt(1)+ζjt,xjt(1) is one element of xjt and xjt(2) are the remaining elements. As in their article, xjt(2) is suppressed because we can conditional on an arbitrary value of xjt(2). Let δjt=xjt+ζjt.

9 See Assumption 2 of Berry and Haile (Citation2014), which leads to δjt=σj1(pt,st) for all j=1,,J and for any (pt,st).

10 See Berry and Haile (Citation2014, p. 1767–1770) for details.

11 By Eqs. (3) and (4), function r=(σ11,,σJ1,π11,,πJ1). The component σj1 comes from the market share equations sjt=σj(xjt+ζjt,pt) for j=1,2,,J, where pt=(p1t,,pJt). The functional form of σj is determined by individual utility (2) and the joint distribution of the idiosyncratic terms. Therefore, the smoothness of σj1 follows from smoothness of the demand function σj for product j, which is guaranteed by commonly used joint distributions of εjti,j=1,2,,J. πj1 comes from the condition that marginal revenue equals marginal cost: cj(st,wjt+ωjt)=ψj(st,pt) and thus wjt+ωjt=cj1(ψj(st,pt),st), where cj and ψj are marginal cost and marginal revenue functions, respectively. πj1 is a composite of ψj and cj1, thus its smoothness naturally follows from smoothness of the marginal revenue and marginal cost functions, see Berry and Haile (Citation2014, p. 1767–1770) for derivation of the structural equations.

12 Suppose there are v1v2 in Bm satisfying y=qm(v1)=qm(v2). Then we have r(y)=v1v2=r(y), which cannot hold.

13 We require it to be positive in order to guarantee that the jump occurs at the interior of the support.

14 For example, let yd=A¯11A¯12. If the probability of picking up equilibrium 1 is λ1(r(y))=13(yyd)+1 for yA12, then limyA12,yydλ1(r(y))=1=limyA11,yydλ1(r(y)) and it will prevent a jump of fY(y) at yd.

15 In (p. 1288) they write:“For a given x, different realizations of u can affect the support of Pxu, but not the probabilities assigned to different outcomes in the support.”

16 Since ϕ1(M(r(A12)))+ϕ3(M(r(A31)))1, the two components cannot both equal to 1.

17 For asymptotic validity of our test, the rates must satisfy γp+γh<1,3γp+γh>1, and γp+3γh>1.

Additional information

Funding

This work is supported by JSPS KAKANHI Grant numbers 17K13713 and 19K13666.
This article is part of the following collections:
Econometric Reviews Best Paper Award

Log in via your institution

Log in to Taylor & Francis Online

PDF download + Online access

  • 48 hours access to article PDF & online version
  • Article PDF can be downloaded
  • Article PDF can be printed
USD 61.00 Add to cart

Issue Purchase

  • 30 days online access to complete issue
  • Article PDFs can be downloaded
  • Article PDFs can be printed
USD 578.00 Add to cart

* Local tax will be added as applicable

Related Research

People also read lists articles that other readers of this article have read.

Recommended articles lists articles that we recommend and is powered by our AI driven recommendation engine.

Cited by lists all citing articles based on Crossref citations.
Articles with the Crossref icon will open in a new tab.