433
Views
1
CrossRef citations to date
0
Altmetric
Articles

Ramsey discounting calls for subtracting climate damages from economic growth rates

ORCID Icon & ORCID Icon
Pages 79-82 | Published online: 13 Feb 2018
 

ABSTRACT

The Ramsey equation ties the utility discount rate and the elasticity of marginal utility of consumption together with per capita consumption growth rates to calculate consumption discount rates. For many applications, per capita consumption growth rates can be approximated with per capita output growth rates. That approximation does not work for climate change, which drives an ever-increasing and increasingly uncertain wedge between output and consumption growth. NAS (2017), in a central recommendation and illustrative example, conflates the two. The correct, consumption-based discounting method generally decreases consumption discount rates and, thus, increases the resulting Social Cost of Carbon Dioxide (SC-CO2).

JEL CLASSIFICATION:

Acknowledgements

Without any implications, we thank Don Fullerton, Ken Gillingham, Bob Kopp, Kian Mintz-Woo, Billy Pizer, and Richard Zeckhauser for helpful comments. All remaining errors are our own.

Disclosure statement

No potential conflict of interest was reported by the authors.

Notes

1 This alone is an area where NAS (Citation2017) clears up prior confusion: The more commonly used term to describe the optimal social cost of the marginal tonne of CO2 emitted is ‘Social Cost of Carbon’ or ‘SCC’. That is inaccurate. For example, an SCC of $100 per tonne of carbon, C, equals $27 per tonne of carbon dioxide, CO2, as one tonne of C = tonnes of CO2.

2 Yet another important contribution: splitting the daunting process of calculating the SC-CO2 into individual modules. While often interrelated, these modules can, for the most part, be tackled independently before integrating them into a coherent whole.

3 Note that we do not go as far here as Heal (Citation2017), who argues that the Ramsey equation does not apply because of climate damages. It does. It just requires the use of the correct that subtracts climate damages from economic output, as we show here.

4 See, e.g. Gollier (Citation2012) for an overview. See Broome (Citation2012) and Kelleher (Citation2017) for ethical perspectives, Arrow et al. (Citation1996) for introducing the distinction between descriptivist and prescriptivist approaches to discounting into the climate debate, and references in footnote 6 for how uncertainties influence the resulting discount rates.

5 One important critique and extension, also referenced by NAS (Citation2017) in a footnote though not further elaborated on, notices that in Equation 2 conflates risk across states of nature and risk across time, in form of the elasticity of intertemporal substitution (EIS). Separating risk aversion and the EIS is a potentially important extension that, in fact, replaces the Ramsey equation altogether in determining appropriate discount rates (e.g. Epstein and Zin Citation1989; Epstein and Zin Citation1991; Weil Citation1990).

6 The difference is variably described as ‘marginal’ versus ‘nonmarginal’ (e.g. Dietz and Hepburn Citation2013; Foley, Rezai, and Taylor Citation2013) or as ‘exogenous’ versus ‘endogenous’ approaches to discounting (e.g. Dietz et al. Citation2006), with the first of each pair of terms applying to output-based growth rates and the second to consumption-based ones adjusted for climate damages. Note that general-equilibrium approaches such as Nordhaus (Citation1992, Citation2017)’s DICE model naturally use the latter. NAS (Citation2017), too, notes that outputs from integrated assessment models like DICE are in ‘consumption-equivalent’ units (167). Many others explore the role of uncertainty in determining the discount rate, which generally declines as a result. For some of the recent intellectual history, see Weitzman (Citation1998, Citation2001, Citation2010), Newell and Pizer (Citation2003) and Gollier and Weitzman (Citation2010). For digestible summaries of the main arguments, see Arrow et al. (Citation2013), Arrow et al. (Citation2014) and Groom et al. (Citation2005).

7 In fact, NAS (Citation2017) is clear that the reason for using the Office of Management and Budget’s 3 rather than 7% discount rate is that ‘the 3.0 percent rate is intended to reflect the rate at which society discounts future consumption’ (160, emphasis added), and it refers to ‘the rate of growth in consumption’ (176) in its reference to U.S. Government Interagency Working Group on Social Cost of Carbon (Citation2015) justifying a 2.5% discount rate.

8 On page 175, the NAS report argues that the growth rates are to emerge from the ‘socioeconomic’ module, whose task is to project growth rates in business-as-usual real GDP per capita over the coming decades (NAS Citation2017, 72–74).

9 Not to be overly precise, but since it will matter for comparison with , the exact rates thus calculated are 1.98, 3.04 and 4.00%, respectively.

10 See footnote 9 for comparison.

Log in via your institution

Log in to Taylor & Francis Online

PDF download + Online access

  • 48 hours access to article PDF & online version
  • Article PDF can be downloaded
  • Article PDF can be printed
USD 53.00 Add to cart

Issue Purchase

  • 30 days online access to complete issue
  • Article PDFs can be downloaded
  • Article PDFs can be printed
USD 205.00 Add to cart

* Local tax will be added as applicable

Related Research

People also read lists articles that other readers of this article have read.

Recommended articles lists articles that we recommend and is powered by our AI driven recommendation engine.

Cited by lists all citing articles based on Crossref citations.
Articles with the Crossref icon will open in a new tab.