942
Views
2
CrossRef citations to date
0
Altmetric
Articles

Comparison of the stabilising effects of government spending shocks in the Czech Republic, Hungary and Poland

ORCID Icon
Pages 2899-2923 | Received 23 Sep 2018, Accepted 26 Jul 2019, Published online: 28 Sep 2019

Figures & data

Table 1. Spending multipliers: baseline model with k = 1 lag.

Table 2. Spending multipliers: baseline model with k = 4 lags.

Table 3. Peak spending multipliers for Poland; specifications without the ‘crisis’ dummy variable.

Table A1. Unit root test for variables (data in log).

Table A2. Lag length criteria for the baseline model.

Table A3. Elements of A and B matrices for the baseline model.

Table A4. Elements of A and B matrices – model with direct taxes, k = 1 lag.

Table A5. Elements of A and B matrices – model with direct taxes, k = 4 lags.

Table A6. Elements of A and B matrices – model with indirect taxes, k = 1 lag.

Table A7. Elements of A and B matrices – model with indirect taxes, k = 4 lags.

Table A8. Elements of A and B matrices – the baseline model with 4 lags.

Table A9. Elements of A and B matrices – subsample since 2007.

Table A10. Peak multipliers (adjusted to be interpreted in the national currency) in robust system specifications.

Table A11. Elements of A and B matrices, the additional SVAR specification for Poland.

Figure A1. Inverse roots of AR Characteristic Polynomial for baseline model.

Figure A1. Inverse roots of AR Characteristic Polynomial for baseline model.

Figure A2. Impulse responses of Y to structural one s.d. shock in G ± 2 s.e., baseline model.

Figure A2. Impulse responses of Y to structural one s.d. shock in G ± 2 s.e., baseline model.

Figure A3. Impulse responses of Y to structural one s.d. shock in G ± 2 s.e., model with direct taxes, k = 1 lag.

Figure A3. Impulse responses of Y to structural one s.d. shock in G ± 2 s.e., model with direct taxes, k = 1 lag.

Figure A4. Impulse responses of Y to structural one s.d. shock in G ± 2 s.e., model with direct taxes, k = 4 lags.

Figure A4. Impulse responses of Y to structural one s.d. shock in G ± 2 s.e., model with direct taxes, k = 4 lags.

Figure A5. Impulse responses of Y to structural one s.d. shock in G ± 2 s.e., model with indirect taxes, k = 1 lag.

Figure A5. Impulse responses of Y to structural one s.d. shock in G ± 2 s.e., model with indirect taxes, k = 1 lag.

Figure A6. Impulse responses of Y to structural one s.d. shock in G ± 2 s.e., model with indirect taxes, k = 4 lags.

Figure A6. Impulse responses of Y to structural one s.d. shock in G ± 2 s.e., model with indirect taxes, k = 4 lags.

Figure A7. Impulse responses of Y to structural one s.d. shock in G ± 2 s.e., baseline SVAR with k = 4 lags.

Figure A7. Impulse responses of Y to structural one s.d. shock in G ± 2 s.e., baseline SVAR with k = 4 lags.

Figure A8. Impulse responses of Y to structural one s.d. shock in G ± 2 s.e., subsample since 2007.

Figure A8. Impulse responses of Y to structural one s.d. shock in G ± 2 s.e., subsample since 2007.

Figure A9. Impulse responses of Y to structural one s.d. shock in G ± 2 s.e. for Poland, SVAR specifications without the dummy variable for the crisis and post-crisis period.

Figure A9. Impulse responses of Y to structural one s.d. shock in G ± 2 s.e. for Poland, SVAR specifications without the dummy variable for the crisis and post-crisis period.