290
Views
0
CrossRef citations to date
0
Altmetric
Regular Article

A New Kuznetsian Dynamic: The Knowledge Economy and Income Inequality in the United States, 1917–2008

Pages 174-204 | Published online: 11 Nov 2016
 

Abstract

The rise of the knowledge economy resulted in higher levels of income inequality in the United States and forced many to question the Kuznets Inverted-U hypothesis. However, this study argues that the establishment of a knowledge economy does not negate the importance of employment shifts for income inequality. Instead, the expansion of knowledge employment alters the major sectors that are responsible for the overall distribution of income. To this end, this article presents the key argument that the current service–knowledge transition impacts income inequality trends, of today, in a way that is similar to the agricultural–industrial transition, of the past. According to the autoregressive conditional heteroskedasticity regressions, the agricultural–industrial transition returns stronger associations with income inequality in the United States before 1950. The agricultural–industrial transition's impact diminishes thereafter as the service–knowledge transition shares a more robust association with income inequality after 1980.

ACKNOWLEDGMENTS

The author thanks Rob Clark and Anthony Roberts for their helpful comments on previous iterations of this article. This article was presented at the 2013 annual meetings of the sociology of development conference in Salt Lake City, Utah.

NOTES

Notes

1 Top income shares do not directly measure the overall distribution of earnings. But it allows for a more temporally expansive view of inequality as the measurements required to construct a U.S. Gini coefficient are unavailable before the 1940s. Additionally, unreported comparisons of the 90-10 ratio to the Gini coefficient return a correlation of 0.96.

2 See CitationKalleberg (2011) for a description of this process.

3 The 1950s period is important as employment in agriculture and industry, as a percent of total employment, fell below 50 percent.

4 Others use the term “postindustrial” or “post-Fordist” economy (CitationHirschorn 1984; CitationBlock 1990).

5 There is an interesting, if not complementary, line of research which shows that knowledge workers are attracted/fostered by the availability of public amenities (e.g., CitationGlaeser 1998; CitationClark 2003; CitationShapiro 2006).

6 Interestingly, CitationFlorida's (2002) estimate of knowledge employment is strikingly similar to that of the expert-managerial class estimated by CitationWright (1997) and CitationBarley (1996).

7 There is a large literature on the role of skill-biased technological change as the primary cause of rising inequality (CitationDustmann et al. 2009; CitationAutor and Dorn 2010; CitationBlack and Spitz-Oener 2010; CitationMichaels et al. 2010). The evidence includes the similar timing of increasing wage inequality and the invention of personal computers (CitationKatz 2000), while others observe that educated and better paid workers are more likely to utilize computers in the workplace (CitationKrueger 1993). But others note that inequality rises years before the widespread availability of computers (e.g., CitationCard and DiNardo 2002).

8 This conversion is done by logging all variables and using the difference function in ARIMA.

9 The dependent variable in this study includes returns to capital investments. However, noncapital gains included estimates of the dependent variable were also tested but this did not substantially alter the findings. This analysis is available on request.

10 Many use southern imports as opposed to total imports. But an unreported analysis shows that this variable is not a significant predictor of United States income inequality.

11 Other time periods were tested but the current cutoffs return the most robust associations.

12 Preliminary diagnostics and correlation matrix is available on request.

13 Some scholars claim that inequality is less systematically determined today that in the past (e.g., CitationBurtless and Jencks 2003). This argument implies that model residuals may grow more dispersed over time resulting in time-contingent heteroskedastic errors. However, an unreported supplementary analysis, which is available on request, reveals that the residuals of the models specified in this investigation does not produce consistently more dispersed residuals over time.

14 There should be less concern that correlated independents are biasing the results since the indicators are log-differenced. Nevertheless, the exclusion of unionization substantially enhances the significance of international imports and, to a lesser extent, female labor participation.

15 For an earlier review of the literature against Kuznets, see CitationFields and Jakubson (1994).

16 This is important as Kuznets offers a vague explanation regarding the point at which inequality will start to decline during the transition from “traditional” to “modern” forms of employment.

Log in via your institution

Log in to Taylor & Francis Online

PDF download + Online access

  • 48 hours access to article PDF & online version
  • Article PDF can be downloaded
  • Article PDF can be printed
USD 53.00 Add to cart

Issue Purchase

  • 30 days online access to complete issue
  • Article PDFs can be downloaded
  • Article PDFs can be printed
USD 327.00 Add to cart

* Local tax will be added as applicable

Related Research

People also read lists articles that other readers of this article have read.

Recommended articles lists articles that we recommend and is powered by our AI driven recommendation engine.

Cited by lists all citing articles based on Crossref citations.
Articles with the Crossref icon will open in a new tab.