67
Views
0
CrossRef citations to date
0
Altmetric
Original Articles

Testing expected utility maximization under price and quantity risk with a heterogeneous panel

&
Pages 1105-1119 | Published online: 11 Apr 2011
 

Abstract

Refutable implications based on the curvature properties of the indirect utility function for the competitive firm operating under uncertainty are extended to the case of both price and quantity uncertainty. Using unit roots and cointegration tests for heterogeneous panels, a model of US agricultural production is developed based on the time-series properties of a panel of state-level data. Most refutable hypotheses under output price and output quantity risk are not rejected, but symmetry conditions implied by a twice-continuously-differentiable indirect utility function are rejected. The same test conclusions are obtained from a traditional model that presumes stationarity in all variables.

Acknowledgements

The authors are, respectively, a graduate research assistant and professor, School of Economic Sciences, Washington State University. The authors express appreciation to Eldon Ball and Wallace Huffman for access to the data used in this article and to Holly Wang, Douglas Young, Atanu Saha and an anonymous reviewer for constructive comments on earlier drafts of the manuscript.

Notes

1It joins work by Chakrabarti (Citation2003), Bandiera et al . (Citation2000), Sarantis and Stewart (Citation2001) and McCoskey and Kao (Citation1999).

2Examples are Abdulkadri et al . (Citation2006), Key et al . (Citation2006), Ozanne (Citation1998), Saha and Shumway (Citation1998), Saha et al . (Citation1994), Love and Buccola (Citation1991), Chavas and Holt (Citation1990) and Myers (Citation1989).

3With a single source of risk, this assumption defines the distribution properties on the first-order moment of risk. For example, under output price risk, let denote random output price with mean and random variable . The random component of wealth is defined by , where Y is output quantity. Then, assumption (2) is equivalent to which is a commonly maintained hypothesis in the economics literature. However, under the scenario of both output price and output quantity risk, assumption (2) imposes a strict condition on the nature of the market and on empirical properties of the data when testing hypotheses derived from expected utility maximization. We will relax this assumption and demonstrate its importance for testing under both price and quantity risk in a later section.

4The following notation is used throughout this article: hx denotes the partial derivative of h(·) with respect to x, hxy represents the Hessian matrix whose ij-th element is ∂2 h/∂xi yj where h(·) is a real-value function of vectors x and y. Transpose notation for vectors and matrices is not used.

5This specification provides the convenient, but not necessary, result that the expected values of the stochastic terms are zero.

6Because they implicitly treated assumption (2) as a necessary condition, Saha and Shumway (Citation1998) did not demonstrate that their propositions and corollary were applicable for testing the expected utility maximization hypothesis under all types of risk, market structure and aggregation level.

7In both cases, the null hypothesis is the same, i.e. that the variables are not cointegrated for each cross-sectional member. The alternative hypothesis is different for the two test categories. The alternative for the panel statistics category is that the stationary autoregressive parameters are homogeneous; the alternative for the group mean statistics allows them to be heterogeneous.

8The group-ρ statistic is slightly undersized and empirically the most conservative in small panels. The panel-v tends to have the best power relative to the others when the panel is fairly large. The other statistics lie between these two extremes and have little comparative advantage in terms of testing power, either in small or large panels. In our case the N dimension exceeds the T dimension, which may cause all the statistics to become overly conservative (Pedroni, Citation2004).

9The theory of expected utility maximization applies to the individual, in this case the individual firm. Although tests of utility maximization have not been reported for state-level data, Lim and Shumway (Citation1992) failed to reject the hypothesis that each of the states acted as though they were profit-maximizing firms. They used nonparametric testing procedures on annual data for the period 1956–1982, which overlaps with the first 23 years of our data period.

10Significant (5% level) groupwise heteroskadasticity was still found in the scaled data.

11This routine is available from the Estima website, http://www.estima.com.

12Although evidence was found that significant heteroskedasticity still remained across states, we were unable to transform the data to remove cross-sectional heteroskedasticity because we had more cross-sectional units than time periods.

13An additional dummy variable was included in each input demand equation in the time-series-based model for the production year 1983 to pick up the effects of the PIK program.

14See Lusk et al . (Citation2002) for an example of the frailties of measurement error in causing violation of dual relationships implied by economic theory.

15The importance of sufficient price variability in recovering dual relationships has long been known. See, for example, Quiggin and Bui-Lan (Citation1984).

16For example, Park and Antonovitz (Citation1992a, Citationb) found empirical support for the hypothesis of constant absolute risk aversion (CARA) for California feedlots. Ozanne (Citation1998) found that the presumed CARA parameter was significant for aggregate US agriculture. Abdulkadri et al . (Citation2003) found that the hypothesis of CARA was not rejected for Kansas irrigated corn farmers.

17For example, Dalal (Citation1994) criticized Park and Antonovitz (Citation1992b) conclusion supporting CARA and argued that their results contradicted rather than confirmed the existence of CARA. Chavas and Holt (Citation1990, Citation1996) rejected the null hypothesis of CARA and supported DARA for US aggregate corn and soybean producers. Abdulkadri et al . (Citation2003) rejected the hypothesis of CARA for Kansas dryland wheat and dairy farmers.

Log in via your institution

Log in to Taylor & Francis Online

PDF download + Online access

  • 48 hours access to article PDF & online version
  • Article PDF can be downloaded
  • Article PDF can be printed
USD 53.00 Add to cart

Issue Purchase

  • 30 days online access to complete issue
  • Article PDFs can be downloaded
  • Article PDFs can be printed
USD 387.00 Add to cart

* Local tax will be added as applicable

Related Research

People also read lists articles that other readers of this article have read.

Recommended articles lists articles that we recommend and is powered by our AI driven recommendation engine.

Cited by lists all citing articles based on Crossref citations.
Articles with the Crossref icon will open in a new tab.