1,393
Views
5
CrossRef citations to date
0
Altmetric
Research Article

Determinants of land value volatility in the U.S. Corn Belt

ORCID Icon & ORCID Icon

ABSTRACT

Understanding land value volatility and its reaction to exogenous shocks helps land owners, investors, and lenders assess risk. Land value volatility, the variance of the unpredictable component of land value growth rates, is modelled for each of the Corn Belt states in the U.S. using EGARCH. A pooled VAR system is then estimated to capture the interactions between land value determinants and land value volatility. The variables of the pooled VAR are split into negative and positive vectors to allow for asymmetric impacts. Impulse response functions are mapped. All states exhibit land value volatility clustering. Inflation, cash rent and population growth rates granger cause land value volatility. Land value volatility responses to negative shocks are greater than those to positive shocks. Lenders and investors should expect greater swings in land values after negative shocks to land value growth rates, but not an overreaction of land values from shocks to cash rent growth rates. Positive shocks to changes in interest rates increases land value volatility, but unexpected shocks to population growth rates do not have statistically significant impact on land value volatility.

JEL CLASSIFICATION:

I. Introduction

Land serves as an investment and a production tool. Farmland values are of importance to land owners, farmers, agricultural lenders and policy makers for their role in farm loans as a collateral and for their farm income generation (Nickerson et al. Citation2012; Cowley Citation2016). Therefore, land values lows and highs may indicate times of financial stress or strength in the farm sector (Cowley Citation2016). Understanding the factors that impact land value variance (i.e. land value volatility) and how it reacts to innovations (e.g. good or bad news) can help land owners and lenders prepare for changes in the land market. Previous studies have focused on land value volatility using the assumption of constant growth rates (Benirschka and Binkley Citation1994; Young, Binkley, and Florax Citation2016) or as percentage variations in land values (Just and Miranowski Citation1993). We propose to use and analyse the variance of the unpredicted component of land values.

Volatility forecasting is a common element in investment risk management analysis (Hossain and Latif Citation2009). In financial markets, volatility is measured by the standard deviation of stock returns (Zheng Citation2015). Wheaton et al. (Citation2001), though, argue that in the case of real estate markets, volatility should not be measured based on historical returns but based on the unpredictable component of housing prices. Since future housing prices can be predicted by historical price behaviour, the uncertain portion in housing price variation is the unpredictable component of house price growth rates (Zheng Citation2015). This approach is applicable to land values, as they can be predicted based on historical land values (see Just and Miranowski Citation1993), linking uncertainty in land value behaviour to the unpredictable portion. Analogous to the housing market (see Wheaton et al. Citation2001), we assume that uncertainty in the land value market has a predictable and an unpredictable component. We measure land value volatility as the variance of the unpredictable component of the land value growth rate. Although it may be common to analyse volatility, volatility clustering, and spillovers in financial and housing markets (Lee Citation2009), this is the first study to model land value volatility as the variance of the unexpected changes in land values. Our objective is to analyse land value volatility and its asymmetric responses to positive and negative shocks from land value determinants. We also test how land value volatility responds to good or bad news (i.e. we check for the presence of asymmetric effects). This article is composed of this introduction, followed by an analysis of current land value trends and past literature. Thereafter, the empirical method is discussed along with the data. This is followed by the results section and concluding remarks.

Overview of land value trends

The greater variation in land values in the Corn Belt in the U.S. has motivated us to study this region and to investigate how land value volatility is impacted by changes in land value determinants. Land values in the Corn Belt states experienced larger changes over time than average U.S. land values. There are two major peaks in land values during the period of 1953 to 2017, one before the farm crisis in the 1980 s and the second one from 2011 onwards (). The second peak in land values is 1.85 times larger than the first peak in real values. From 1987 to 2009, land values in the Corn Belt have been steadily increasing, with a sharp increase from 2009 onwards. Since mid-2015, though, farmland values have been decreasing and this is likely to continue (Sherrick, Schnitkey, and Kuethe Citation2015).

Figure 1. Land values in the Corn Belt in 2017 prices.

Figure 1. Land values in the Corn Belt in 2017 prices.

Trends in farmland values can also be analysed by studying land values to cash rent ratios (). From 1960s to early 2000s, land values to cash rent ratios have ranged from 13.64 to 20. Following a decrease in interest rates since the late 1990s, land values to cash rent ratios have increased, reflecting the steady increases in land values. Johnson (Citation2016) suggests that lower interest rates may be responsible for the increases seen in land values to cash rent ratios. Lower interest rates imply lower opportunity costs, making investors willing to pay a higher amount for each dollar in current earnings from farmland.

Figure 2. Land value to cash rent ratio and the 10-year constant maturity treasury rate.

Figure 2. Land value to cash rent ratio and the 10-year constant maturity treasury rate.

Previous research on land values

Volatility, studied extensively in finance, is normally applied to stocks, exchange rates and interest rates (Lee Citation2009). Nevertheless, applications to housing prices have become common (Lee Citation2009; Miller and Peng Citation2006; Hossain and Latif Citation2009). Housing, as an asset, holds similar traits to house owners, as land does to land owners. Namely it represents a large share of the total assets (land represents 80% of the total farm assets), and it has low liquidity and transaction costs. Positive shocks to the housing market may increase demand and consequently house price volatility. Housing supply, though, may not react as quickly to higher demand. The short-term inelastic supply may further affect housing price volatility (Zheng Citation2015). As the land market holds similar traits to the housing market, we expect land value volatility to display similarities to house price volatility (i.e. time varying volatility and clustering).

The fundamentals of farmland pricing are the discounted value of its economic rent (i.e. the return to farmland from the cultivation of the land including all variable factors of production) (Ricardo Citation1996; Moss and Katchova Citation2005). The relationship between land values and returns can be represented through the capitalization formula (i.e. Land Value = Returns/Discount Rate) (Brorsen, Doye, and Neal Citation2015). The observed land value is, generally, the lowest value the seller is willing to accept and the highest value the buyer is willing to pay (Robison, Lins, and VenKataraman Citation1985). Hence, the opportunity costs of the seller equals the returns from the land for the buyer (Featherstone and Baker Citation1987; Robison, Lins, and VenKataraman Citation1985). By re-organizing the capitalization formula we find that Land Value/Returns = 1/Discount Rate. Without market distorting factors, such as inflation, the ratio of Land Value/Returns would be constant (Robison, Lins, and VenKataraman Citation1985). However, we know that this is not the case (). Thus, expansions to the capitalization model have been suggested over time. Studies have found that land values are also determined by macroeconomic factors (e.g. inflation), government payments, and population growth among other factors (Just and Miranowski Citation1993; Borchers, Ifft, and Kuethe Citation2014; Devadoss and Manchu Citation2007). Therefore, we assume that shocks to factors beyond returns to land and interest rates, such as population growth and inflation, will also effect land value volatility.

Farmland markets have undergone boom and bust cycles over time (Henderson, Gloy, and Boehlje Citation2011) and are prone to bubbles (Featherstone and Baker Citation1987). Land values overreact to shocks to asset values, rents and real interest rates (Featherstone and Baker Citation1987). Land further from the market are sensitive to boom and bust periods (Benirschka and Binkley Citation1994). Similarly, land in regions heavily dependent on government payments is more sensitive to variations in inflation, returns on assets and capital costs (Moss Citation1997). Government payments, though, only minimally explain variations in land value minimally, while inflation and returns on alternative capital largely explain land price swings (Just and Miranowski Citation1993). We use past research to determine the fundamental and other variables that influence land values used in this study. Given the many factors that determine land values and swings in land prices, we investigate the role of these factors on land value volatility. Whether and how much land value volatility reacts to unexpected shocks to land value determinants provides valuable insight to investors, agricultural lenders and landowners.

II. Methodology and empirical analysis

We assume that agents in the land market can predict future land value growth rates based on rational expectations, with knowledge of available information and the optimal strategies of other agents (Hossain and Latif Citation2009). The general technique used for modelling rational expectations is the ARMA model (Hossain and Latif Citation2009; Miller and Peng Citation2006). That is, the expected land value growth rate is a function of past information and shocks. Therefore, the observed growth rate of land value in state i in year t, (lvi,t), is equal to the sum of expected land value growth rate conditional on the information set available (Ii1) and an unpredicted shock (εi,t) (Miller and Peng Citation2006):

(1) lvi,t=Elvi,t|Ii1+εi,t(1)

where the land value growth rate is lvi,t=logLi,tLi,t1, and Li,t is the land value in state i in year t.

We estimate the expected future land value growth rate for each Corn Belt state using an ARMA(p,q) model. The p and q order of lags for the ARMA model is established by analysing the AIC of various model specifications (see Table A-1). A dummy for the farm crisis period and a time dummy for the recent increase in land values (i.e. from 2005–2014) are added to the ARMA models. The residuals from the estimated ARMA model are equivalent to the unpredicted portion of the realized land value growth rates (lvi,t). From EquationEquation (1), the realized land value growth rate is a function of the expected land value growth rate (Elvi,t|Ii1) and of unpredictable shocks or innovations (εi,t).

We test each of the Corn Belt states’ land value growth rates for the presence of volatility clusters (i.e. if years of higher volatility are followed by high volatility and low volatility periods are followed by low volatility periods) (Hossain and Latif Citation2009; Enders Citation2015). Volatility cluster is checked by testing whether the residuals follow an ARCH(q) process using the Lagrange Multiplier test (ARCH-LM)Footnote1 (Engle and Ng Citation1993; Lee Citation2009):

(2) εi,t2=φi,0+φi,1εi,t12+φi,2εi,t22++φi,pεi,tq2(2)

where εi,t2 is the squared residuals for the land value growth rates of state i and q is the order of the ARCH process. The ARCH-LM test can then be estimated for each state using the sample size T, which in our case is 107 observations per state, and the R2 from EquationEquation (2):

(3) LMi=TiRi2(3)

Volatility estimation

The presence of cluster volatility provides evidence that estimating volatility with an ARCH/GARCH model is appropriate. We opt to model volatility with an exponential-generalized autoregressive conditional heteroscedasticity model (EGARCH). The EGARCH, an extension of the GARCH model, controls for volatility clustering as well as asymmetric effects in volatility (Lee Citation2009). It also allows for asymmetric effects and nonnegative constraints (Enders Citation2015). Asymmetric effects occur when there is a tendency for volatility to react more to negative ‘news’ (e.g. a decline in returns) than to positive ‘news’ (e.g. a rise in returns) (Enders Citation2015). The conditional mean and variance equations used in the EGARCH(1,1) estimation are (McAleer and Hafner Citation2014; Lamoureux and Lastrapes Citation1990):

Conditional mean equation

(4) lvi,t=Elvi,t|Ii1+εi,t,(εi,t|εi,t1,εi,t2,)N0,hi,t(4)

where lvi,t is the land value growth rate and εi,t the residuals for state i at time t. εi,t follows a normal distribution with mean 0 and a conditional variance hi,t. EquationEquation (4) is equivalent to the ARMA in EquationEquation (1). In the EGARCH model, variance is conditional on past shocks and past information. Hence, the variance is not constant (i.e. unconditionalFootnote2 ) throughout the years.Footnote3 The conditional variance equation proposed by Nelson (Citation1991) is (McAleer and Hafner Citation2014):

Conditional variance equation

(5) lnhi,t=ωi,0+αiηt1+γiηt1+βilnhi,t1,β<1(5)

where hi,t is the conditional variance for the land value growth rate in state i. hi,t varies over time. The stability condition is given by β<1. ωi,0 is the constant, and εi,t1 is the lag of the residual from the mean equation. If γi0 then we know that for state i, asymmetry exists (McAleer and Hafner Citation2014). Asymmetry effects means that land value volatility reacts differently to good and bad news (e.g. a decrease in returns). For a better interpretation of shock sizes and persistence, the EGARCH uses standardized shocks ηt1, which are calculated as ηt1=εi,t1hi,t10.5 (Enders Citation2015; Nelson Citation1991; McAleer and Hafner Citation2014).Footnote4 The EGARCH specification that is used to model land value volatility is chosen by analysing the AIC of different EGARCH models (see Table A-2). Land value volatility (vly) predicted from the EGARCH model (i.e. hˆi,t) is then used in a pooled vector autoregression (VAR).

Reduced form vector-autoregression model

The vector autoregressive (VAR) model, introduced by Sims (Citation1980), is commonly used for analysing dynamic systems due to its ease in estimation and its similarity to multivariate multiple linear regressions (Featherstone and Baker Citation1987; Tsay Citation2013). By allowing the lags of every variable in the system to impact other variables, the VAR minimizes spurious relationships due to restrictions made a priori of the dynamic interactions (Featherstone and Baker Citation1987; Sims Citation1980). In this study, we propose a slight modification to the usual vector autoregression (VAR) system found in the literature. Following Miller and Peng (Citation2006) we estimate a pooled VAR model composed of land value volatility (vlyi,t) along with other variables:

Pooled VAR

(6) Yi,tcpii,tvlyi,t=Didi+Dtdt+AYi,t1+αYi,t1+aYi,t1++BYi,t1βYi,t1bYi,t1+Rcpii,t1ρcpii,t1rcpii,t1+Gvlyi,t1γvlyi,t1gvlyi,t1+Ui,tei,tui,t(6)

where vlyi,t is the conditional variances predicted from the EGARCH model (see EquationEquation (5)), Yi,t is a vector of a change in risk-free interests (cmt), growth rates of cash rent (cr), land values (lv)Footnote5 and population (pop). Di is a vector of state dummies and Dt is a vector of time dummies of 10 year intervals.Footnote6 Time and states dummies are added to control for time-invariant state attributes, as well as, macro factors affecting the states (Miller and Peng Citation2006). The variables (pop, cmt, lv and cr) on the right hand side were split into positive and negative values (i.e. Yi,t+ and Yi,t). For example, Yi,t+ contains only positive values of (pop, cmt, lv and cr) and zero for negative values. Analogously, Yi,t contains only negative values of (pop, cmt, lv and cr) and zero for positive values. In the case of cpi and vly no negative values were observed so they are not split.Footnote7 The separation of positive and negative values was conducted in order to capture the asymmetric effects of the variables on land value volatility (Miller and Peng Citation2006). A, B, R, G are vectors of coefficients, while a,β,γ,ρ,a,b,r,g are scalars of coefficients. Ui,t is a vector and ei,t,ui,t are scalars of error terms orthogonal to the space spanned by the right hand side variables (Miller and Peng Citation2006).

Due to the size of our sample, estimating a VAR system for each of the states is not recommended, hence, we pool the VAR system (Miller and Peng Citation2006). Pooling allows us to control for fixed effects and for the lagged effects pertinent to each state (Miller and Peng Citation2006). We use state level data instead of national level since we believe that using disaggregated data is more appropriate to analyse land value volatility in the Corn Belt. Following Miller and Peng (Citation2006), we estimate the pooled VAR row by row using feasible GLS. First, the VAR system is estimated using OLS with fixed effects. Residuals from the OLS are then used to construct the weighted matrix to control for heteroscedasticity and serial correlation in the error terms (see Wooldridge Citation2009). Next, the weighted OLS is estimated. An optimal lag length of the VAR is chosen based on three selection criteria proposed by Andrews and Lu (Citation2001).Footnote8 We then test for granger causality between the variables using a test specific to panel data designed by Dumitrescu and Hurlin (Citation2012). The test allows us to verify the suitability of the VAR system. Lastly, we plot unit impulse response functions (IRFs) to analyse the land value volatility response to exogenous shocks in the other variables (following Hamilton Citation1994; Lütkepohl Citation2005). To estimate the IRFs we transform the VAR into a moving average, MA() process (Hamilton Citation1994):

(7) yt=μ+ψ0ϵt+ψ1ϵt1+ψ2ϵt2+(7)

where μ is a vector of intercepts, assumed to be zero, and ϵ is a vector of exogenous shocks or innovations. ψs is a matrix that can be interpreted as (Hamilton Citation1994, 318):

(8) yt+sϵt=ψs(8)

The element in the ith row and jth column of the matrix ψs identifies the response from a one unit increase in the jth variable’s innovation at the time tϵjt for the value of variable i at t + s (yi,t+s) (Hamilton Citation1994, 318). All other innovations are held constantFootnote9 (Hamilton Citation1994, 318). In simple terms, the impulse response gives the difference between forecasts of y with a one-time shock (yt) and forecasts of y without the shock (yt0) (e.g. the impulse response for one period is IRF0=ytyt0). It provides the marginal effects from a one-time shock.

Choice of variables

The proposed pooled VAR model is composed of land value volatility, land values and four other variables that are important in determining land values. The variables we use can be divided between fundamental and other variables that influence land values and land value volatility. The fundamental variables are those related to asset pricing theory and land value formation (Featherstone and Baker Citation1987; Robison, Lins, and VenKataraman Citation1985). The other variables comprise external factors that influence land values such as inflation and demand for land for conversion to non-agricultural purposes.

Fundamental variables

In the literature on land value determination there is a consensus that land value is a function of returns to the land and interest rates. The fundamental variables (returns and interest rates) determine the long-run equilibrium of land values (Featherstone and Baker Citation1987). Robison, Lins, and VenKataraman (Citation1985) argue that the rent received for the land (e.g. cash rent) can be a measure of returns from the land, and is readily available for investors seeking to buy land. Therefore, we use cash rents as a proxy for returns to the land. We use the 10-year treasury constant maturity rate as the interest rate. This interest rate is commonly used as a proxy for a risk-free interest rate for long-term investments (e.g. land acquisition), and is helpful in determining the capital’s opportunity cost (Gloy et al. Citation2011).

Other variables that impact land values and its volatility

Apart from the fundamental variables, there are factors present in the economy that impact land value and land value volatility. In this study, we limit these factors to inflation and urbanization pressures. Robison, Lins, and VenKataraman (Citation1985) argue that inflation can affect fundamental variables and land values. We control for inflation by using the consumer price index with 2017 as the base year. Competition for land causes an increase in its value (Kuethe, Ifft, and Morehart Citation2011). As the population increases, there is a rise in demand for land for conversion into non-agricultural purposes. We use population growth rate as a proxy for urbanization pressure.

III. Data

Data on land values for the Corn Belt states (Iowa, Illinois, Ohio, Indiana and Missouri) come from the National Agricultural Statistics Service of the United States Department of Agriculture. We use land value instead of actual farmland prices registered in transaction costs in order to reflect the value of all land, not only land that was sold (Raup Citation2003). Land value volatility estimates are produced using yearly data from 1912 to 2017. These are predicted from the EGARCH model (see EquationEquation 5).Footnote10 A larger sample is used since the GARCH modelling requires a larger dataset. Variables for the pooled VAR are available from 1960 to 2017. The shorter time-series considered in the pooled VAR is due to the time periods that data on cash rents are available.

Cash rents from 1960 to 2017 are from the USDA National Agricultural Statistics Service.Footnote11 Annual population data come from the United States Census Bureau, and are only available from 1990 to 2016. Population between 1981 and 1989 and between 1971 and 1979 are estimated using the weighted average of the shares of the state population over the total U.S. population from beginning and ending years.Footnote12 The 10-year treasury constant maturity rate is obtained from the Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis with an annual frequency.Footnote13 Information on annual consumer price index comes from the U.S. Bureau of Labour Statistics.Footnote14 All variables, except volatility and the treasury rates, were transformed into growth rates.Footnote15 The 10-year treasury constant maturity rate is calculated as the percentage change (i.e. the rate in the current year subtracted by the rate in the last year). Variables are transformed as to avoid the case where some variables are pre-whitenedFootnote16 and others not (Conway et al. Citation1984). The mean and standard deviation of the variables prior to the transformation are presented in .

Table 1. Mean and standard deviation of the variables.

IV. Results

In order to run the vector autoregression system we must first test for stationarity in the variables and in the VAR model. Additionally, we discuss the results from the ARCH tests for land value volatility clustering and asymmetric effects from the EGARCH models, before discussing the results from the VAR model, granger causality tests and impulse response graphs.

Stationarity

To verify whether or not the VAR is stationary, a panel unit root test is run using the Harris-Tzavalis unit-root test. Similarly, we test the stationarity of the land value series used in the GARCH modelling using the Augmented Dicky Fuller test and the Phillips-Perron unit test. The presence of a unit root is rejected in every case ().

Table 2. Panel unit root tests of Corn Belt land value series and of the VAR variables.

ARCH effects

ARCH LM tests confirm the existence of volatility clustering in all Corn Belt states (). P-values for the ARCH LM tests indicate that the hypothesis of homoscedasticity can be rejected at a 5% level of statistical significance. Given the presence of volatility clustering, modelling volatility with EGARCH is appropriate, whereas modelling volatility as a constant variance (i.e. as an unconditional variance) can lead to underestimating actual risk (Lee Citation2009).

Table 3. ARCH LM tests for the residuals from an ARCH model.

Asymmetric effects

After testing for the presence of ARCH effects, ARMA models are estimated for each state. The residuals from the ARMA models are then used to model volatility using EGARCH. The optimal model is chosen by estimating different EGARCH specifications and choosing the one with the lowest Akaike information criterion (AIC) (see Tables A-1 and A-2).Footnote17 Results from the EGARCH regression are also in the appendix.

Once the models for each state are specified we analyse the asymmetric effect from volatility in each series. Recall that asymmetric effects exist if γi0 in the EGARCH model (EquationEquation 5). Asymmetric effects are found for land value volatility in all states (). This means that large swings in land value are followed by large swings in land value while low land value volatility is followed by low land value volatility. The asymmetric coefficients are positive, meaning that bad news have larger impacts on volatility than good news. The presence of asymmetric effects highlights the importance of using an EGARCH instead of a GARCH model for land values series (Lee Citation2009).

Table 4. Asymmetric effects from the univariate EGARCH volatility models.

Pooled VAR

Results from the pooled VAR system composed of the variables: land value volatility (vly), cash rent growth rates (cr), land value growth rates (lv), population growth rates (pop), and change in interest rates (cmt) are presented in . The R2 of 0.50 for the volatility equation (6th column) indicates a reasonably good fit of the equation. The lagged land value volatility, negative change in interest rates, negative and positive growth rates in land values, and positive growth rates in population are statistically significant determinants of land value volatility. The coefficients of the pooled VAR system are complex to interpret independently (Featherstone and Baker Citation1987). In order to understand further the impacts of the variables in the VAR model on land value volatility, we test for granger causality between the variables.

Table 5. Results from the pooled vector auto-regression model.

Panel granger causality

In the case of vector autoregressive models, individual hypothesis t-tests on the coefficients may not be useful (Featherstone and Baker Citation1987). The reason is that the amount of lagged variables in the regressions make the presence of correlations among exogenous variables likely (Featherstone and Baker Citation1987). As an alternative, granger causality tests are performed. Dumitrescu and Hurlin (Citation2012) provide a test for granger causality for panel data models that performs well with small samples. This test is an adaptation of the granger causality test (Granger Citation1969) with a null hypothesis that there are no causal relationships in any of the cross-section variables.

Results show that land value volatility is significantly impacted by land value, cash rent, inflation and population growth rates (). This is similar to other authors’ (Featherstone and Baker Citation1987; Just and Miranowski Citation1993; Moss Citation1997) findings that returns to land, interest rates and inflation have statistically significant effects on land values. In our case, though, changes in interest rates impact land value volatility through land value growth rates. Past land value volatility affects future volatility, which may suggest a potential for bubbles in the land value market. Land value growth rates granger causes cash rent growth rates, but not the other way around. This result is in line with Schnitkey (Citation2016) reasoning that economic theory points to a unidirectional causality from land values to cash rent. In some cases, only negative (positive) growth rates granger cause another variable (e.g. population growth rate affecting land value volatility), highlighting the importance of splitting the variables in the pooled VAR.

Table 6. Results from the Dumitrescu and Hurlin Granger causality test.

Impulse response functions

In order to interpret the economic significance of the granger causality relations, impulse response functions were constructed. These map the responses of land value volatility, to a one-time shock to one of the error terms, over the years (EquationEquations 7 and Equation8). Given that some of the variables were split into negative and positive, the multiplication of the positive vector (Yi,t1+) by 1% is considered a positive shock. Likewise, the multiplication of the negative vector (Yi,t1) by −1% is a negative shock. We investigate the dynamic responses of land value volatility to positive and negative shocks to population, cash rents and land value growth rates, as well as changes in interest rates (). These shocks are considered transitory with zero representing a return to the equilibrium level. For the variables consumer price index and land value volatility only positive shocks are analysed since negative shocks would be simply mirror images.

Figure 3. Impulse response functions: The response of land value volatility to exogenous shocks.

Figure 3. Impulse response functions: The response of land value volatility to exogenous shocks.

The unpredicted component of land value growth rates (i.e. land value volatility) seems to respond similarly to shocks in the growth rates of the determinants of land value, the same way land value responds to changes in its determinants. In some cases, though, the responses are not statistically significant. Our results do not show statistically significant impacts of shocks to population grown rates on land value volatility, although Kuethe, Ifft, and Morehart (Citation2011) found linkages between increases in land values and population growth. Land value volatility responses to shocks to cash rent growth rates are also statistically insignificant, even though Featherstone and Baker (Citation1987) find an overreaction of land prices to rent.

The responses of land value volatility to positive and negative exogenous shocks are asymmetric. Negative shocks appear to have larger effects on land value volatility than positive ones. For instance, negative shocks to land value growth rates have greater impacts on land value volatility than positive shocks. In the first year, a negative shock causes an increase of 0.50% in land value volatility while a positive shock causes an increase on 0.10%. The reaction in land value volatility from shocks to land value growth rates is relatable to Featherstone and Baker (Citation1987). They find that increases in land prices cause further increases in land prices. The response of land value volatility to shocks aligned with the presence of asymmetric effects of land value volatility (see section 4.3) may indicate a market prone to bubbles.

Just and Miranowski (Citation1993) argue that variations in inflation and interest rates cause overreaction of land prices. Similarly, we find statistically significant responses of land value volatility to shocks to inflation and interest rates but not to shocks to rents. Responses of land value volatility to shocks to cash rent growth rates, though, are small and statistically insignificant. Shocks of 1% to inflation growth rates, though, increase land value volatility up to 0.70% and last over 8 years. A positive shock to changes in interest rates of 1% increases land value volatility by 0.60% in the second year. This result is best explained by the fact that investment in monetary assets are preferred when interest rates are high (Devadoss and Manchu Citation2007).

V. Conclusions

Our study follows theory applied to the housing market by modelling land value volatility as the variance of the unexpected changes in land values. Residuals from rational expectation models on land values for each of the Corn Belt states are used to model a land value volatility series for each state using exponential GARCH models. A pooled VAR system is then estimated to model time change volatility of land values and the interactions between land value determinants and land value volatility. Asymmetric impacts are allowed by splitting the determinants of land value into negative and positive vectors. Finally, coefficients of the pooled VAR are used to estimate impulse response functions. We report on the asymmetric effects of land value volatility and perform granger causality tests.

We confirm the presence of land value volatility clustering in all Corn Belt states. This means that land value volatility is consistent with other real estate markets such as the housing market and should not be modelled as an unconditional variance (i.e. a constant variance). The presence of asymmetric effects in Corn Belt states’ land values indicates a stronger reaction of land value volatility to bad news than to good news. This fact, associated with the response of land value volatility to shocks in land value growth rates, suggests a market prone to bubbles.

Our findings also show that land value volatility is granger caused by inflation, cash rent, land value and population growth rates. Impulse response functions show that the responses of land value volatility to innovations resemble the reactions of land values to changes in its determinants, found in previous studies. That is, the unpredicted component of land value growth rates (i.e. volatility) reacts similarly to shocks to the growth rates of land value determinants as land values react to changes in its determinants. Land value volatility responses to positive and negative shocks, though, are asymmetric with responses to negative shocks being larger than those to positive shocks.

The results aid lenders and land owners in their risk assessment. Findings indicate that these agents should expect greater swings in land values after negative shocks to land value growth rates. Though this response will be smaller than the shock itself. Unexpected positive shocks to changes in interest rates cause increases in land value volatility in the second year, as monetary assets are preferred over farmland. Investors should not expect an overreaction of land values due to unexpected shocks to cash rents, as these responses are statistically insignificant. Future research could expand this analysis to incorporate the transmission of commodity price volatility to land value and cash rent volatilities in order to investigate how these may further affect the farm income.

Disclosure statement

No potential conflict of interest was reported by the authors.

Notes

1 The ARCH-LM test was conducted using the MTS package in R (Tsay Citation2016).

2 The unconditional variance can be treated as a constant and is estimated as the long-run forecast of the variance (Asteriou and Hall Citation2016).

3 The assumption of homoscedasticity or constant variance was rejected through the ARCH-LM tests.

4 The fact that the standardized shocks (ηt1) are a function of variables (i.e. hi,t10.5and εi,t1) that are dependent on the parameters in the mean and variance equations makes the quasi-maximum likelihood estimation and the invertibility of the EGARCH challenging (McAleer and Hafner Citation2014). McAleer and Hafner (Citation2014) use a random coefficient complex nonlinear moving average process to estimate the conditional variance as hi,t=Eεt2|It1.

5 lv are the land value growth rates used in the ARMA models. Recall that the residuals from the ARMA models are then used to model land value volatility.

6 The last dummy accounts for 7 years instead of 10 due to the length of the time series.

7 There was only one negative value for CPI in 2009 of −0.0015, which was excluded as an outlier.

8 The selection criteria were performed using the pvarsoc program by Abrigo and Love (Citation2016). The pooled vector autoregression model (VAR) with one lag was preferred, as it was the case where all criteria displayed the lowest values (Abrigo and Love Citation2016).

9 We preferred to analyse the response to a unit shocks because the standard deviations of the variables were very small and we need to be able to analyse the effects from the shocks isolated. We acknowledge that this assumes that shocks from other variables remain constant and that we may be underestimating the impact on land value volatility. Nevertheless, we found similar movements from shocks using the orthogonalized impulse-response functions, which makes our results and conclusions more robust.

10 Results from the EGARCH regressions can be found in the appendix (Table A-3).

11 Recent data on cash rents is downloaded from NASS QuickStats. Data from 1960 to 1994 is accessible at (USDA, Economic Research Service, NRE Division Citation2018).

12 For example, if in 1980, Iowa had a population share of 1.3% of the total population in the U.S. and in 1970 that share was 1.4% then: Estimated population in 1981 = U.S. population in 1981 *(1.3%*0.1) + (1.4%*0.9). Estimated population in 1989 = U.S. population in 1989 *(1.3%*0.9) + (1.4%*0.1). Data is available at

https://www.census.gov/programs-surveys/popest/data/data-sets.html.

13 The Federal Reserve Bank dataset is available at https://fred.stlouisfed.org.

14 Information on the consumer price index is available at https://www.bls.gov/cpi/home.htm.

15 Each variable (i.e. land values, cash rent, consumer price index and population density) is transformed into logged first differences (li,t = log(Li,t/Li,t-1)), interest rates are as percentage changes (Hossain and Latif Citation2009).

16 Pre-whitening is the transformation of a time series variable to make it have the statistical properties of white noise.

17 Differently from GARCH models, there is no consensus that the EGARCH (1,1) provides the best and most convenient fit (Lee Citation2009).

References

Appendix 1.

Table A1. AIC statistics for each ARMA model specification.

Appendix 2.

Table A2. EGARCH Model specification selection.

Appendix 3.

Table A3. Results of the EGARCH models for each state.