1,458
Views
2
CrossRef citations to date
0
Altmetric
Research Article

Induced innovation: evidence from China’s secondary industry

, ORCID Icon, & ORCID Icon

ABSTRACT

We investigate the effect of rising labour costs on induced technological change in China’s secondary industry. Building on insights developed in a rich literature, we propose a model linking changes in labour productivity to changes in labour costs and the predetermined availability of physical capital. Importantly, we derive testable hypotheses to distinguish induced innovation from standard substitution of capital for labour under fixed technology. Our empirical results support the hypothesis that rising wages have induced labour-saving innovation in China, at least in the decade of the 1990s, but less so or not at all after the middle of the next decade.

JEL CLASSIFICATION:

I. Introduction

We contribute to the discussion of China’s achievements in industrial innovation and to the ‘race’ between China and the U.S. to lead the world in advancing industrial technology (e.g. Santacreu and Zhu Citation2018 in St. Louis Fed On the Economy Blog). Focusing on China’s secondary industry, we ask whether rising labour costs have stimulated labour saving technological innovation, raising output per unit of employment beyond what would normally occur through factor substitution under fixed technology. We add to studies that document evidence of China’s achievements in innovation as reflected in research and development (R&D) and successful patent applications (e.g. Hu and Jefferson Citation2009; Wei, Xie, and Zhang Citation2017). We find that rising wages lead to successful innovation and accelerated productivity growth in China, building on Atkinson and Stiglitz (Citation1969) and Acemoglu (Citation2015).

That hypothesis that rising input prices are an important force underlying technological innovation has been addressed in the economics literature at least since J. R. Hicks’ Theory of Wages (Hicks Citation1932). We follow the more recent work of Acemoglu (Citation2010, Citation2015) and Acemoglu and Autor (Citation2011), proposing a model of endogenous technology adoption in response to changing wages. From this base we derive production-function-based regressions to test hypotheses that labour productivity growth has exceeded the amount attributable to standard factor substitution under fixed production technology. While a number of papers show that rising wages have led to more innovations and rising multifactor productivity in China, we add to this literature by identifying the degree to which wage-induced innovation in China is labour-saving and thus responsive to forces tending to reduce its global competitiveness.

Much current literature relating rising labour costs to productivity growth in China utilizes data on local minimum wage changes, examining how firm-level total factor productivity growth (Mayneris, Poncet, and Zhang Citation2018 who also address the impact of minimum-wage enforcement; Hau, Huang, and Wang Citation2020), and patent applications (Chu et al. CitationForthcoming). However, these studies do not attempt to show the degree to which observed productivity growth exceeds that which would have occurred under observed wage growth when production functions are not altered through innovation.

Another contribution we offer to the existing literature on China is based on knowledge that cross-section and over-time variation in legal minimum wages may contain a possibly confounding endogenous component (Freeman Citation2010). We address this endogeneity concern by using (i) provincial wages instrumented with the 10-year lagged size of the provincial primary-industry labour force and (ii) firm-level wages with one-year lagged wages averaged over other counties within the same industry and the same province as observed firms.

We first construct a simple theoretical model to illustrate the difference between standard substitution between labour and capital and the alteration of the production process caused by rising labour costs under induced innovation. We then employ an indirect approach yielding implications that we test against the existence of induced innovation from theory-guided regression models.

We find evidence confirming the presence of wage-induced innovation that is particularly strong in the last decade of the 20th century and that more pronounced among the largest firms. We recognize that our modelling and empirical testing of the wage-induced innovation hypothesis is sensitive to assumptions regarding the elasticity of substitution between capital and labour. We perform simulation exercises to evaluate the robustness of our conclusions and to evaluate our estimation results assuming that labour and capital are either gross complements or substitutes. The results of these simulations provide further evidence that we have identified the presence of factor-price-induced technological innovation and its time trend.

The next section introduces our data sources and explains some of the basic trends observed in summary statistics. Section 3 presents our theoretical model and estimation results; Section 4 discusses the sensitivity of our hypothesis tests to alternative assumptions on the elasticity of substitution, and Section 5 concludes.

II. Data

present the summary statistics of our basic variables. summarizes our principal source of data, the well-known Annual Survey of Industrial Enterprises (ASIE) data base,Footnote1 which we supplement with data from official provincial employment and output statistics (). The ASIE data are predominantly secondary industry and enable us to match output, employment, wage, and capital-stock data at the individual firm level. They also allow us to account for differences in the propensity to innovate between larger and smaller firms, the importance of which is emphasized by An (Citation2017). Estimation results derived from the ASIE data use samples subjected to a two-tail 7% trim (14% total) of extreme values based on total wage payments divided by value added.Footnote2 To complement the firm-level analysis, we also utilize province-level data (). The provincial output, wage, employment, R&D, and FDI data come from the NBS annual provincial statistical yearbooks. Provincial secondary-industry real capital data as used in Wu (Citation2016) have kindly been provided by the author, Yanrui Wu. We address potential wage endogeneity by instrumenting with the 10-year lagged size of the provincial primary-industry labour force.

Table 1. Summary statistics: 7% trimmed annual survey of industrial enterprises data (used in the regression models)

Table 2. Summary statistics: provincial data

show the growth of real wages between 1983 and 2012 for the provincial data, and between 1997 and 2007 for the ASIE data, respectively. Both the provincial and ASIE data indicate that real wage growth increased abruptly in the late-1990s, declining towards the middle of the next decade, rebounding somewhat around 2005, and remained substantially higher than in the preceding ten years through at least 2012Footnote3. illustrate the annual growth of labour productivity. Both the provincial and ASIE data suggest a decline in the rate of growth in years following the turn of the millennium. The figures show that labour productivity and real wage growth both accelerated in the late-1990s, a result consistent with induced innovation. In the next section we develop a theoretical model and derive testable hypotheses that will allow for a more rigorous examination of the induced innovation hypothesis.

Figure 1. Provincial data: average real wage growth

Source: Authors’ calculations from China Statistical Yearbooks
Note: Data are provincial averages of wage growth in secondary industry.
Figure 1. Provincial data: average real wage growth

Figure 2. Annual survey of industrial enterprises: real median wage growth

Source: Author calculations from ASIE data. Series show annual proportionate growth of median firm real wages.
Figure 2. Annual survey of industrial enterprises: real median wage growth

Figure 3. Provincial data: secondary industry labour productivity growth

Source: Authors’ calculations from China Statistical Yearbook
Figure 3. Provincial data: secondary industry labour productivity growth

Figure 4. Annual survey of industrial enterprises: median labour productivity growth

Source: Authors’ calculations from ASIE data.
Figure 4. Annual survey of industrial enterprises: median labour productivity growth

III. Theoretical model and empirical results

Our theoretical model is an adaptation of Acemoglu’s (Citation2010) theoretical framework. Our base model of wage-induced innovation assumes a unitary elasticity of substitution. In Section 4 we relax this rather strict assumption and consider substitution elasticities less than or greater than unity and discuss sensitivity of our basic findings to this more generalized view.

Unitary substitution elasticity benchmark

Following Acemoglu (Citation2010) we specify the production function of the final good producer as follows:

(1) Y=αα(1α)1(Kθ(AL)1θ)αq(θ)1α(1)

where A denotes exogenous labour augmenting technology and αα(1α)1is a convenient normalization used in Acemoglu (Citation2010). The variable qθ denotes the quantity of an intermediate good embodying technology θ. K and L denote capital and labour, respectively. The objective function of the final good producer is:

(2) maxK,L,q(θ)αα(1α)1Kθ(AL)1θαq(θ)1αWLRKχq(θ),(2)

where W, R and χ denote wage, rental rate of capital and the price of the intermediate good, respectively. Technology θ is created and owned by a profit-maximizing monopolist from which the final good producer purchases technology. This setup allows for induced innovation to operate through an endogenous choice of θ in the final good producer’s maximization problem. As in Acemoglu (Citation2010), we assume K is supplied inelastically at a fixed levelKˉWis exogenously given, which allows us to examine how rising wage rates affect the advancement of induced technological changes.Footnote4 A positive wage shock not only leads to a standard substitution between capital and labour but may also induce the final good producer to choose a different production process to reduce the impact of rising wages.

As shown in the Online appendix, we define wage-induced innovation as follows:

(3) θW>0,(3)

where θ denotes the optimal choice of technology.Footnote5 As explained in Wei, Xie, and Zhang (Citation2017), rising wages are an important driver to stimulate China’s growth in innovation. A common empirical approach to examining the price-induced innovation hypothesis focuses on testing the existence of (lagged) price variables in a production or cost function (e.g. Peeters and Surry Citation2000; Caputo and Paris Citation2005). Our paper takes a different approach by examining the relationship between labour productivity growth and real wage growth.

Labour productivity growth and real wage growth

In the Online appendix, we derive the relationship between labour productivity and the real wage as follows:

(4) YL=1α(1θ)W.(4)

Under fixed technology, θ is constant, implying that labour productivity and the real wage grow at the same rate – a general property of a Cobb-Douglas production function.Footnote6 However, under induced technological change, θ increases in response to rising wages, implying that labour productivity grows faster than the real wage. The Online appendix provides a theoretical example of modelling induced technological change.

Define ϕt=1α(1θt). Dividing both sides of (4) by W, and taking logs, we characterize the behaviour of over time as:

(4a) lnYitLit1Wit=ϕt+ηl(i)+εit(4a)

where i denotes province i and ηl(i) captures provincial fixed effects when the provincial data are used; i denotes firm i and ηl(i) captures county fixed effects when we use the ASIE data; ϕt denotes year fixed effects, and 1eϕtϕ0=1θt1θ0.

Based on Equationequation (4a), under induced technological change, rising wage implies that θt is greater than θ0: the ratio 1θt1θ0 should be less than 1.Footnote7 We estimate Equationequation (4a) using the ASIE data and report regression results based on the subsample of the Large enterprises in , panel A and results for the provincial data covering the years 1978–2011 in panel B. Both sets of results indicate accelerating induced technological change in the late 1990s. After that, both series indicate a weakening of induced technology change, but more so among the set of firms represented in the provincial data.

Figure 5. Estimates of EquationEquation (4a) based on (1-θt)/(1-θ0) and 95% confidence intervals

Notes: (1) Panel A focuses on the subsample of the Large enterprises; (2) Panel B focuses on provincial data.
Figure 5. Estimates of EquationEquation (4a)(4a) lnYitLit1Wit=ϕt+ηl(i)+εit(4a) based on (1-θt)/(1-θ0) and 95% confidence intervals

Controlling for omitted variables and possible endogeneity

The simple relationship between productivity and wage growth represented in Equationequation (4a) may yield a biased view of technical change due to omission of variables correlated with both the real wage and the availability of physical capital. To deal with possible omitted variable issues, we take logs of (4) and, adding the year and location identifier (Bit), we obtain the following approximationsFootnote8:

(5) lnYLit=Bit+βlnWit+δlnKˉit+εit.(5)

Under wage-induced technical change, we expect β > 1. Thus, we test for wage-induced technical change under the following null hypothesis.

Null Hypothesis: β = 1 (in the absence of wage-induced technical change).

Alternative Specification. In an alternative implementation of the induced innovation framework that can aid in testing the robustness of our estimation results, we approach the relationship between labour productivity and the price of labour by substituting the optimal demand for labour into (4) and then taking logs and adding location and year identifiers, to obtainFootnote9

(6) lnYLit=Bit+θlnKˉLit.(6)

To examine whether the technology parameter is a function of the real wage we hold constant the influence of the availability of physical capital (allowing for possible capital-induced innovation) and specify:

θ=γ0+γ1f(W)+γ2f(Kˉ),wheref(X)=lnX.

Under wage-induced technical change, we expect γ1>0. Substituting the preceding specification into (6) we obtain the empirical formulation,Footnote10 Footnote11:

(7) lnYLit=Bit+γ0lnKˉLit+γ1ln(Wit)lnKˉLit+γ2ln(Kˉit)lnKˉLit+εit(7)

Our null hypothesis, indicating the absence of technical change is:

γ1=0
.

Empirical results: Tests with ASIE data

The use of microdata allows us to account for the fact that innovation is more likely among Large firms as suggested in much of the literature on innovation in China (An Citation2017). Channels that have been proposed in the literature to explain why larger firms tend to invest more in innovation include (i) larger scale that allows larger firms to spread fixed costs of innovation investment over more output (e.g. Schumpeter Citation1942; Forslid, Okubo, and Ulltveit-Moe Citation2018); (ii) a broader technological base or a greater ability to absorb riskier innovation investments by pooling risk over a broader portfolio of products (e.g. Nelson Citation1959). Knott and Vieregger (Citation2020) show that both R&D investment and R&D productivity increase with firm size.

In the ASIE samples, while it seems reasonable to assume that local wage rates are not influenced by individual firm employment decisions, we conduct robustness checks, estimating Equationequations (5) and (Equation7) incorporating an instrumental variable (IV) for the local wage as described below. We proceed on the assumption that enterprises’ stock of physical capital are predetermined as discussed above.Footnote12 We include county- and year-fixed effects (FE), as well as region-specific time trends as additional controls (Bit in equations 5 and 7).Footnote13 We hope inclusion of year FE alleviates concern that our results are driven by drastic SOE reforms in the late 1990s as well as their time-varying impacts across regions. The standard errors are clustered at the county level.

In the IV estimation, the instrumental variable for the firm’s wage is the one-year lagged wage averaged over other counties within the same industry and the same province as the observed firm. Industry categories are (1) Mining; (2) Manufacturing; (3) Production and Distribution of Electricity; and Gas and Water. The identifying assumption of the instrumental variable is that once county-level and year fixed effects are accounted for, the neighbouring counties’ historical economic shocks are not correlated with own county’s contemporaneous economic shocks.

The OLS and IV estimation results for hypotheses on β and γ1 are reported graphically in .Footnote14 We see in panel A of that the OLS estimated value of β for the two subsamples that exclude the smaller firms generally exceeds 1.0 through the period 1996–2001. This is consistent with our wage-induced innovation hypothesis. However, the estimated value of declines abruptly and remains well below 1.0 between 2001 and 2003, not rising above 1.0 through 2007. Thus, the null of no wage-induced technical change assuming unitary elasticity of substitution is strongly rejected for these two subsamples over the period 1996–2001. The estimated value of for the full sample that includes the smaller-size firms in the ASIE data is consistently less than 1.0 from 1998 through 2007, and its time path follows a roughly similar course to that of the larger-firm subsamples, falling steadily through 2003, rebounding somewhat, but ending in 2007 significantly below its value in 1998. These results indicate that wage induced innovation is weak or absent among smaller-size firms.

Figure 6. Estimates of β and γ1 with Kˉ in Equations (5) and (7)

Notes: (1) The instrumental variable for the firm’s wage is the one-year lagged average wage over other counties within the same industry and the same province as the observed firm; (2) Dashed lines indicate the 95% confidence intervals.
Figure 6. Estimates of β and γ1 with Kˉ in Equations (5) and (7)

The 2SLS estimate of Equationequation (5) reported in panel B of , with the lagged IV for the industry/county wage as described above, is robust in failing to detect the existence of wage-induced technical change when based on the sample including the smaller-size firms. However, the IV estimated value of for the subsample that includes only large firms significantly exceeds 1.0 through the period 1996–2006, five years beyond evidence consistent with induced innovation revealed in the OLS estimation results for large firms. When the estimation sample is enlarged to include medium firms, the IV estimation results are consistent with the marked decline in the estimated value of β in 2001, and not rising above 1.0 through 2007.

As shown in panel A of , the OLS estimated value of γ1 is above zero through the sample period. After 1998, the time paths of γ1 are closely parallel for all subsamples of the ASIE data, dropping substantially through 2003 until levelling off through 2007 at about three-fourths their value in 1998. Moreover, the time paths for γ1 are roughly similar to those for equation 5’s β shown in panel A, particularly for the Large and Medium and Large firm subsamples. The estimated time paths of the wage coefficients based on both Equationequations (5) and (Equation7) indicate a substantial fall-off in the degree of wage innovation over time, with the decline beginning in 2001 in the Equationequation (5) results and earlier, in 1998, in the Equationequation (7) results.

The 2SLS estimates of Equationequation (7) reported in panel B of , using the same IV as for estimation of Equationequation (5) are qualitatively robust to the OLS estimation results in being greater than zero throughout the time period covered in the data. Moreover, there is a very interesting parallel with the estimation results for Equationequation (5) – OLS and IV estimation results – in indication of a rather pronounced break, with increasingly declining trend following the year 2001. The 2SLS estimation of Equationequation (7) reinforces not only the evidence of falling induced innovation after the year 2001, but also its tendency to disappear in the late sample period.

The inclusion of a measure of physical capital in Equationequations (5) and (Equation7) serves to control for omitted variable bias. Estimates of the coefficients β and γ1 are not only very robust to exclusion of the capital-stock variable shown in , but we find consistent robustness to 2SLS estimation using an IV for the firm’s wage as described above. Estimates are also robust to the use of a contemporary rather than lagged IV for wage. Details are available from authors on request.

Figure 7. Estimates of β and γ1 without Kˉ in equations (5) and (7)

Notes: (1) The instrumental variable for the firm’s wage is the one-year lagged average wage over other counties within the same industry and the same province as the observed firm; (2) Dashed lines indicate the 95% confidence intervals.
Figure 7. Estimates of β and γ1 without Kˉ in equations (5) and (7)

Empirical results: Tests with provincial data

The provincial data allow us to test the induced innovation hypothesis over the years 1991–2011 compared to 1996–2007 covered by the ASIE data. To control for possible omitted variable bias, we estimate Equationequation (5) with year and provincial fixed effects as well as region-specific time trends (Bit in Equationequations 5 and Equation7). These additional controls capture exogenous shocks to TFP, for example, the differing pace of institutional reforms across different regions in China. Estimation results are reported in .

Table 3. Estimation results of EquationEquation 5: provincial secondary industry data

To control for the potential problem of endogeneity in the estimation of the wage coefficient with provincial aggregate data, we employ the two-stage least squares (2SLS) method, where the instrumental variable (IV) for provincial real wage is the 10-year lagged size of the provincial primary-industry labour force. Following Lewis, W. Arthur (Citation1954), we assume that China had a large ‘surplus population’ in rural areas before market-oriented reforms that supported worker mobility.Footnote15

The point estimates of approximately 1.6 for the coefficients of the one-year lagged log wage are highly significant in both Models (1) and (2) of , but the Kleibergen and Paap (Citation2006) rk Wald F statistics for weak identification is only moderately strong.Footnote16 Moreover, the p-value for the test that the estimated coefficient of log real wage is greater than 1.0 is 0.32 in Model (1) and 0.33 in Model (2). The lower bound of the 95% Anderson-Rubin confidence set is below one. Thus, we cannot with a high degree of confidence reject the null hypothesis that the coefficient of log real wage equals 1.0, indicating the absence of wage-induced technical change. The weaker evidence regarding wage-induced innovation may reflect the fact that provincial data include firms of all sizes.

In contrast to a broad literatureFootnote17 linking FDI and R&D to innovation, in the presence of the log-wage variable we find no support for a positive link of R&D and/or foreign ownership participation to technology growth (see Model (2) of ).

Estimation results for Equationequation (7) based on provincial aggregates over the period 1991–2011 are reported in . As in estimation of Equationequation (5) using the provincial aggregate data, we use 2SLS, where the IV for the provincial real wage is the 10-year lagged size of the provincial primary-industry labour force. The estimate of γ1 is significantly greater than zero, and its lower bound of the 95% Anderson-Rubin confidence set is above zero regardless of whether the capital-stock variable is included. Thus, this estimation result supports the hypothesis of wage-induced technical change.

Table 4. Estimation results of EquationEquation 7: provincial secondary industry data

The regression results based on both micro (firm-level) and macro (province-level) data indicate that the evidence of wage-induced innovation becomes weaker if we focus on the hypothesis test of instead of γ1 (which is consistently positive and significant). This is mainly related to the threshold values (depending on the elasticity of substitution between capital and labour) used in our hypothesis tests.

IV. Relaxing the assumption of unitary elasticity of substitution

The unitary elasticity of substitution assumption provides us with a clear analytical benchmark to test wage-induced innovation. To evaluate the sensitivity of our hypothesis tests to the existence of non-unitary substitution elasticity we turn to the CES production function. To help visualize the ambiguity in the impact of induced innovation under the alternative specifications of the substitution elasticity and alternative levels of induced innovation, we perform a simple Monte Carlo simulation experiment.

Theoretical model

We first analyse the firm’s problem under fixed (exogenous) technology, as defined below:

(8) maxKtLtθKtρ+1θAtLtρ1/ρWtRtKt,(8)

where the parameter At denotes labour augmenting technology and the elasticity of substitution between capital and labour is 11ρ. From the first-order conditions, we solve for the profit-maximizing inputs of L and K and obtain the following result:

(9) Lt=θ1ρKtAtWt(1θ)Atρ1ρ(1θ)1ρ(9)

From (9) and the CES production function, we derive the output-labour ratio:

(10) YtLt=Wt(1θ)At11ρAt(10)

Our null hypotheses (absence of induced innovation) on the relationship between labour productivity and wage growth under fixed technology depend critically on the elasticity of substitution. The parameter β is our estimate of the partial derivative of ln(Yt/Lt) with respect to ln(Wt), and the relationship of our obtained estimate of β to the elasticity of substitution is:

(11) βˆ=ln(Yt/Lt)ln(Wt)=11ρ(11)

Next, we examine the values of γ1 implied by the CES production function. Under fixed technology, the capital share parameter, θ, is assumed to be invariant to wage increases.Footnote18 Given the firm’s production function, we can re-write the output-labour ratio:

(12) YtLt=θ(Kt/Lt)ρ+(1θ)Atρ(1/ρ)(12)

We focus on the partial derivative of ln(Yt/Lt) with respect to ln(Kt/Lt) and how it is related to changes in the real wage as reflected in our parameter of interest, γ1. We define the partial of ln(Yt/Lt) with respect to ln(Kt/Lt) as ξt and derive it from Equationequation (12) as follows:

(13) ξt=ln(Yt/Lt)ln(Kt/Lt)=1Ht(13)

where Ht=1+1θθ(AtLtKt)ρ. We relate γ1 to the partial derivative of ξt with respect to ln(Wt), specified as:

(14) ξtln(Wt)=ρ1ρ1Ht2Gt2(1θ)12ρ1ρ(WtAt)ρ1ρ(14)

where Gt=Wt(1θ)Atρ1ρ(1θ). If we estimate regression models (5) and (7), and assuming that the data are consistent with CES production functions under fixed technology, the predictions of the coefficient estimates based on Equationequations (11) and (Equation14) are:

  1. under unitary elasticity of substitution: β = 1 and γ1=0,

  2. for elasticity of substitution < 1: β < 1 and γ1<0,

  3. for elasticity of substitution > 1: β > 1 and γ1>0.

No single prediction from above is fully consistent with our empirical findings presented in the previous section. Focusing on the ASIE results, we find that β is greater than 1 in the late 1990s but drops below one in the 2000s. We also find that γ1 is positive with a rising trend in the late 1990s and remains positive but with a declining trend afterwards. If we were to assume that the elasticity of substitution declined from significantly greater than unity to significantly less than unity after 2000 we could ‘explain’ the behaviour of β but not the parallel behaviour of γ1 which remains positive after 2000 instead of becoming negative as would be the case under scenario (ii) above. The assumption with fixed technology is not compatible with our empirical findings regardless of the assumed elasticity of substitution in our CES framework.

If there exists wage induced innovation, our estimate of β with respect to ln(Wt) will reflect an additional wage impact beyond what is predicted under fixed technology:

(15) βˆ=ln(Yt/Lt)ln(Wt)=11ρ+11ρ11θθln(Wt)>11ρ(15)

Without specifying a full model, the functional form of θWt is unknown and it is difficult to pin down the threshold value of βˆ (even for a given value of ρ) to be used in the hypothesis test. However, Equationequation (15) indicates that increases with induced innovation compared to the case with fixed technology.

To derive the implications of wage-induced innovation for γ1, we modify Equationequation (14) to allow for the possibility of a nonmonotonic relationship between wage-induced innovation and the parameter γ1 as follows:

(16) ξtln(Wt)=Wt(1θ)Atρ1ρHt2Gt2θln(Wt)ρ1ρ1Ht2Gt2(WtAt)ρ1ρ(1θ)ρ1ρθln(Wt)+ρ1ρ1Ht2Gt2(1θ)12ρ1ρ(WtAt)ρ1ρ(16)

In contrast to the implication in Equationequation (15) that wage-induced innovation raises β monotonically, an uncertainty about the relationship arises from the two additional components on the right-hand-side of Equationequation (16), the first of which is always positive, leading to a higher value of γ1 with increasing wage-induced innovation, while the sign of the second component depends on the value of ρ. The sign is negative if the substitution elasticity is greater than unity but positive if the substitution elasticity is less than unity.

Under a general CES production function, the regression analysis will become much more complicated, because Equationequations (5) and (Equation7) are correctly specified only when the elasticity of substitution is equal to unity. Model misspecifications could also affect the coefficient estimates beyond Equationequations (15) and (Equation16).

Monte carlo simulation

The data-generating process is described in . We assume there are 50 regions in each pseudo data set. In each region, wage and the supply of capital stock are exogenously determined, generated from a uniform distribution between 1 and 2. The parameter At is considered to represent regular technological progress, widely available to all regions. We normalize At to be one.Footnote19 θ is set to be 0.5 + xWt, where we use x to control the degree of wage-induced innovation.Footnote20 Setting x to zero turns off wage-induced innovation. In each data set, we consider three elasticity scenarios: (i) elasticity < 1 (ρ takes a random draw from a uniform distribution between −0.8 and −0.2); (ii) elasticity = 1 (ρ = 0); and (iii) elasticity > 1(ρ takes a random draw from a uniform distribution between 0.2 and 0.8). For each elasticity scenario, we generate 1000 pseudo data sets.

Table 5. Monte carlo simulation – parameter values

Simulation results are summarized in . The upper panel of presents the boxplots of β estimates, while the lower panel presents the boxplots of γ1 estimates. provides a summary of the predicted signs of β and γ1 for substitution elasticities less than, equal to, and greater than 1.0 under fixed technology (x = 0) and wage-induced technology (x > 0). We note the following in our empirical results:

  1. The combined estimates of β and γ1 reported in before 2002 are consistent with induced technology if the substitution elasticity is equal to or less than 1.0 and with fixed technology if the substitution elasticity exceeds 1.0. (We note that the confidence interval for γ1 is broad enough not to preclude a roughly constant time path for γ1 > 0 prior to 2002.)

  2. Following the year 2001, the behaviour of β is still consistent with induced technology for the elasticity of substitution that is less than 1.0. Although the γ1 estimates remain positive after 2001, they tend to decline, particularly after 2005, suggestive of a decline in the degree of wage-induced technology.

Table 6. Predictions of β and γ1

Figure 8. Monte carlo simulation results

Note: In each boxplot, the median is indicated by the central mark; the 25th and 75th percentiles are indicated by the bottom and top edges of the box, respectively; the outliers are marked by the ‘+’ symbol.
Figure 8. Monte carlo simulation results

It is also instructive to compare the changes in our estimated β and γ1 (see ) with the theoretical results presented in this section. After 2001, our estimate of β falls below one (for small or medium firms), while our estimate of γ1 declines but remains positive. The joint behaviour of β and γ1 is not consistent with the assumption of fixed technology. Under fixed technology, the decline in β after 2001 could be explained by a decline in the substitution elasticity from a value greater than one to a value less than one (which we find implausible). However, this would also imply that γ1 should be negative at the end of our sample period. In fact, our estimated γ1 remains positive. Evaluation of our empirical results in comparison with the above scenarios leads us to rule out the possibility that fixed technology prevailed during our entire sample period.

The upshot of this simulation exercise is that our empirical results are fully consistent with gradually declining wage-induced innovation when the elasticity of substitution is less than unity. Previous studies of the elasticity of substitution between labour and capital in China provide evidence supporting our induced innovation hypothesis. For example, Mallick (Citation2012) finds that the elasticity of substitution between capital and labour in China is significantly less than unity. Acemoglu and Restrepo (Citation2019) choose an industry-level elasticity of substitution of 0.8, citing Oberfield and Ravel (Citation2014) estimates for United States industry. In other words, our hypothesis tests based on the assumption of unitary elasticity of substitution use conservative threshold values to test wage-induced innovation, which may lead to under-rejection of the null hypothesis. However, given the declining trends in both β and γ1 estimates, it is still reasonable to conclude that wage-induced technology change had a stronger influence on productivity growth in China in the late 1990s than in the 2000s.

V. Summary and conclusion

Implementing a model developed in Acemoglu (Citation2010) to test hypotheses relating the rate of labour-saving productivity growth to real wage growth and the availability of physical capital in China’s secondary industry, we find evidence supporting wage-induced (labour-saving) innovation among the largest firms beginning in the mid-1990s but not after 2002 (encompassing China’s entry into the WTO) through 2013, where our data end.Footnote21 To this extent, technical change is not exogenous, as in Molero-Simarro (Citation2017), Ge and Yang (Citation2014), Bai and Qian (Citation2010) and many others.

It will be important for future research to investigate whether adjustments to the increased competitive environment in the years following WTO entry redirected attention towards general efficiency considerations at least temporarily.

We find the absence of stronger evidence supporting wage-induced innovation following China’s WTO accession surprising on its face, and also in light of evidence that productivity (TFP) growth was boosted by WTO accession (Brandt, Van Biesebroeck, and Zhang Citation2012; Brandt et al. Citation2017). However, An (Citation2017) notes that ‘Compared with 2002, the percentage of first world innovation in product and process declined sharply [in 2014] indicating that the level of “Created in China” was literally dropping.’

We test sensitivity of our null hypotheses to an assumed elasticity of substitution between labour and capital in a CES framework, finding labour productivity growth could exceed real wage growth under fixed technology if the elasticity exceeds unity. However, the elasticity of substitution exceeding unity is not consistent with published estimates for China (Bai and Qian Citation2010; Mallick Citation2012). Importantly, the assumption of fixed technology is not consistent with the changes in our estimated coefficients over time, strengthening our evidence of wage-induced innovation.

The evidence of substantially reduced wage-induced innovation in the approximately five years following China’s accession to WTO is quite robust to estimation with different subsamples and to alternative specifications of regression models. However, our inferences could be biased if our assumption of unitary elasticity of substitution is false. If the elasticity of substitution between capital and labour is less than unity, a decline in the rate of labour productivity growth below the rate of wage growth could still be consistent with induced innovation. Such an increase in the probability of a Type II error would further strengthen empirical support of wage-induced technology change. Additionally, the empirical patterns we find both in regression analysis and simulated patterns based on a more flexible CES framework support wage-induced innovation influencing productivity growth in China, at least in the decade of the 1990s, but less so or not at all after the middle of the next decade.

The industrial explosion that turned China into the ‘workshop of the world’ (Gao Citation2012) has contributed to dramatic wage increases. As manufacturers start to look elsewhere in order to maintain international competitiveness, other nations hope investors will be attracted to their low-cost labour, producing a similar employment boom. Such hopes might not be realized if China’s rising wages have induced substantial labour-saving innovation whereby unit costs are even lower under the new technology than those in lower-wage labour markets, implying that the employment impact of expanding output is continually damped by rising productivity (Zhong Citation2015).

Acknowledgements

Comments from the Editor and an anonymous reviewer are gratefully acknowledged. Prof. Xiaojun Wang gratefully acknowledges financial support from the National Natural Science Foundation of China (grant # 71673079).

Disclosure of potential conflicts of interest

No potential conflict of interest was reported by the author(s).

Notes

1 This is by far the most comprehensive annual survey of industrial firms conducted by the National Bureau of Statistics of China (NBS). It includes all state-owned enterprises and non-state-owned enterprises with sales over 5 million yuan. The only data base that has a larger sample size is the Economic Census, but that is only conducted once in several years. In 2004 when an Economic Census was conducted, this sample account for about 90% of total sales. This data base is widely used in the literature, including Song, Storesletten, and Zilibotti (Citation2011), Hsieh and Klenow (Citation2009), and Brandt, Van Biesebroeck, and Zhang (Citation2012), to name just a few. They are primarily located in secondary industry and results are quite robust to the exclusion of all enterprises not located in this industrial category. Changes in sample definitions and variables measured limit our ability to use the full-time range of available ASIE surveys.

2 We have also examined alternative rates for the two-tail trim: 1%, 2%, 5%, 10% and 15%. Our estimation results are quite robust to the trimming of implausibly extreme values.

3 The impact of accelerating wage growth in China has led to an immense literature that we cannot fully cite here. We note the insights in Yang, Chen, and Monarch (Citation2010) and those in the collection of papers on whether China has passed the Lewis Turning Point in China Economic Review (Arthur Citation2010).

4 The theoretical framework can be easily modified to examine the impact of labour scarcity on induced innovation by assuming labour is supplied inelastically at a fixed level Lˉ, as examined in Acemoglu (Citation2010).

5 As explained in the Online appendix, to ensure the existence of wage-induced innovation, the wage level should be less than some threshold value that increases with A. We believe this is a realistic assumption in the sample period targeted in our study because of a relatively abundant supply of rural workers. The resulting technology level, θ, should be greater than 0.5. This is consistent with China’s income share data: for the industry sector (that is relevant to our provincial and ASIE data), the labour income share was always less than 0.5 1978–2004 (Bai and Qian Citation2010 ).

6 Exogenous technical changes (A), such as exogenous industrial upgrading, will impact labour productivity and wage rates equally, so their growth rates will remain the same.

7 It is not appropriate to use Equationequation (4a) to identify θ0, so we use 1θt/1θ0 to examine how θt changes over time.

8 The optimal choice of technology can be affected by level of capital stock (this can be demonstrated using our theoretical model), so we include capital stock and Bit as additional control variables to capture non-wage-induced innovation.

9 Kˉ is assumed predetermined as an accumulation of prior investments as in Ge and Yang (Citation2014) and thus is not endogenous with current W. If there is no wage-induced technical change, then a change in W will impact Y/L only through reducing the amount of labour per unit of Kˉ along the isoquants of an exogenously given production function.

10 Our key theoretical results shown in Equationequations 5 and Equation7 are conditioned on capital stock. However, the functional form of the conditioning is unknown because the cost function to produce technology θ can be specified in many different ways. We use a simple log linear function of capital stock in the main text, but we also conducted extensive robustness checks using fractional polynomials and splines. Specifically, we estimated the following specifications:

lnYLit=Bit+βtlnWit+m(KˉitorlnKˉit)+εit(5) and

lnYLit=Bit+αtlnKˉLit+γtlnWitlnKˉLit+m(KˉitorlnKˉit)lnKˉLit+εit(7),

where m(.) is either a fractional polynomial function or a spline function. This allows us to control for a wide variety of trends in capital stock, which is not an essential part of our analysis. Estimates of primary parameters, i.e. α, β, and γ, are very close to those in the baseline specifications. Estimation results are also robust to inclusion of county-specific fixed effects.

11 Again, when the ASIE data are used, we allow γ0, γ1 and γ2to vary by years.

12 Rising labour cost is closely related to the dynamics of rural-urban migration (Golley and Meng Citation2011; Knight, Deng, and Li Citation2011; Wang et al. Citation2011; Zhang, Yang, and Wang Citation2011). An individual firm has very limited power to influence rural-urban migration decisions. In the regression models, we include county fixed effects and regional time trends to control for local common factors that could affect both local wage rates and labour productivity.

13 The time trend is defined as (current year – 1978), and the regions are defined as ‘coastal,’ ‘northeast,’ ‘west,’ and ‘far west.’ The provinces included in each region are specified in the notes to table 3.

14 Estimation results in tabular form are available on request. In particular, we pay special attention to biases and size distortions caused by potentially weak instruments, and we adopt the latest econometric tools, robust to heterogeneity, serial correlation, and clustering. Dealing with weak instruments along with heteroskedasticity and serial correlation when multiple endogenous regressors and instruments are involved is still an open econometric question. We used a Stata package, weakiv (Finlay, Magnusson, and Schaffer Citation2013), to conduct the Anderson-Rubin test: the null hypothesis is rejected at the 1% level in all regression models. The Anderson-Rubin test is a joint test of the structural parameters (all the coefficients of endogenous regressors are equal to one in Equationequation 5, or zero in equation 7) and the exogeneity of the instruments.

15 Estimation results are robust to alternative specifications of the time period for the IV. Since our IV is lagged ten years behind our potentially endogenous independent variable, this approach also limits the years for which we are able to estimate the regression model. We are aware of the pitfalls involved when using lagged values in instrumental variable estimation as noted widely in the literature (e.g. Reed Citation2015). Nevertheless, we believe these results are of interest as a test of the hypothesis of wage-induced innovation in China, and they add robustness to our results based on individual firms’ data.

16 In the case with one endogenous regressor and one instrument, the Kleibergen-Paap rk Wald F statistic is equivalent to the Olea, Luis, and Pflueger (Citation2013) effective F statistic.

17 Much of this literature is summarized in An (Citation2017).

18 If the elasticity of substitution differs from one, the capital share parameter is not equal to the capital income share in general.

19 At could take a different value in a different time period. The qualitative conclusion of our simulation results is unchanged under different values of At.

20 This is a simple shortcut to introduce wage-induced innovation without specifying a full structure of the model to endogenize the choice of technology. We have also explored alternative specifications (θ = 0.5 + x(ln(Wt)+ln(Kt)) and θ = 0.5 + xln(Wt)), and the qualitative conclusion remains unchanged.

21 We note that our evidence of the timing of induced innovation is roughly consistent with Li et al. (Citation2012)’s citation of Ceglowski and Golub (Citation2007), that the ratio of Chinese wages to labour productivity declined substantially from the 1980s through the middle of the next decade.

References

Technical Appendix

Setup:

  • A representative firm produces the final good using two factors of production, labour and capital. The price of the final good is normalized to one.

  • Technologies are created and supplied by a profit-maximizing monopolist.

  • In Acemoglu’s (Citation2010) M economy, the supplies of the productive factors are assumed to be given. We adopt a similar setup, except that the wage (W) instead of the labour supply is given. The goal is to examine how rising wages affect the advancement of induced technological changes. The supply of K is fixed at Kˉ in the short run.

Final-Good Producer

The objective function of the final-good producer:

maxK,L,qθαα1α1KθAL1θαqθ1αWLRKχqθ

θ: technology

qθ: quantity of an intermediate good embodying technology θ

χ: price of the intermediate good

A: labour augmenting technology

αα1α1: a convenient normalization used in Acemoglu (Citation2010); α0,1.

FOCs:

L:W=α1α1α11θKθAL1θα1KθA1θLθqθ1α
K:R=α1α1α1θKθAL1θα1Kθ1AL1θqθ1α
qθ:αα1α11αKθAL1θαqθα=χ
qθ=α1χ1/αKθAL1θ
=α1α1α11θKθAL1θα1
W=α1α1α11θKθAL1θα1KθA1θLθqθ1θ
=1α11θKθA1θLθχα1/α
L=KA1θθ1θ1α1W1θχα1αθ

At the equilibrium, K=Kˉ. Then L=KˉA1θθ1θ1α1W1θχα1αθ, and qθ=α1Kˉ1θ1αAW1θθχα1αθαθ

The Profit-Maximizing Monopolist

Assumptions:

  1. A technology θ is created at a cost Cθ.

θ=11+eϕ
ϕ=ln1θ1

Assume Cθ=ln1θ12.

(2) Once the technology θ is created, the unit production cost is assumed to be 1α1α+αθ units of the final good. Since the price of the final good is normalized to 1, the unit production cost of the intermediate good is 1α1α+αθ.

maxχ,θχ1α1α+αθα1Kˉ1θ1αAW1θθχα1αθαθCθ
χ:χα1αθαθ+χ1α1α+αθα1αθαθχα1αθαθ1=0
χ=1

Given Kˉ, The problem of the monopolist can be simplified as follows:

maxθθ1α+αθKˉ1θ1αAW1θθln1θ12

FOC: 11α+αθKˉ1θ1αAW1θ/θαθ1α+αθ1θln1θ1αAW=2ln1θ11θ2θ

For the existence of θ, we require 1αWA to be greater than 1:

limθ0θ1α+αθKˉ1θ1αAW1θθ=0<limθ0ln1θ12
limθ1θ1α+αθKˉ1θ1αAW1θ/θ=Kˉ<limθ1ln1θ12

It is easy to show that the LHS of the FOC is positive given 1αA>1 and its RHS is positive only when θ> 0.5, so θ must be between 0.5 and 1.

The objective function of the monopolist has strictly increasing differences in (W, θ) if and only if 2θ1α+αθKˉ1θ1αAW1θ/θWθ>0.

2θ1α+αθKˉ1θ1αAW1θθWθ>0 requires that W<1θ1αAeαθ21α+αθ+θ1θ. It is easy to show that 1θ1αAeαθ21α+αθ+θ1θ is strictly increasing in θ. Then, we define Wmax as 10.51αAeα×0.521α+α×0.5+0.510.5, which should be larger than A1α. Please note that W<Wmax is only a sufficient condition to ensure the objective function of the monopolist has strictly increasing differences in (W, θ).

Given that (a) the objective function is continuously differentiable in θ, (b) A1α<W<Wmax (which ensures that the existence of the solution and the objective function of the monopolist has strictly increasing differences in (W, θ)), and (c) the solution is strictly between 0.5 and 1, Topkis’s theorem implies that θW>0. In other words, an increase in W can encourage technological advancement, which we define as a wage-induced technical change.

Output (Y) Per Worker

YL=αα1α1KˉθAL1θαα1KˉθAL1θ1αL
=α11α1KˉLθA1θ
=α11α1W1α1θ
=Wα1θ

If θ is fixed, output per worker increases with W. An wage-induced technical change (W↑⇒θ) will further increase the output per worker.

Summary of the Model

  1. Given Kˉ, θ increases with W: an increase in W will encourage technological advancement, which we define as a wage-induced technical change.

  2. Under fixed technology, the output per worker will increase with W (holding Kˉ fixed). Wage-induced technical change will increase output per worker more than what would be expected on the basis of a pure substitution of capital for labour under fixed technology.