470
Views
0
CrossRef citations to date
0
Altmetric
Research Article

The effect of environment, social and governance on demand and supply of debt

ORCID Icon, ORCID Icon, ORCID Icon &

ABSTRACT

This paper investigates how Environment, Social and Governance (ESG) performance affects the zero-leverage phenomenon. Using a sample of European-listed firms for the 2002–2020 period and bivariate probit models with partial observability, we find that a greater ESG performance decreases the firm’s propensity to have zero leverage. The negative effect of ESG performance on zero leverage is determined by creditors-related reasons and not by firms’ own decisions, since it only impacts significantly the supply of debt. Creditors seem to be willing to grant debt at more favourable conditions to firms with greater ESG performance. Using propensity score methods, we estimate that a greater ESG performance decreases a firm’s zero-leverage propensity by approximately 3.9% points.

JEL CLASSIFICATION:

I. Introduction

All over the world, countries and firms are facing some important challenges to their existence. Environmental challenges, society development, easy access to information and higher educational levels have forced governments and firms to adjust their activities and goals to reduce climate change threatens and to value human capital. Adopting a sustainable development becomes an essential principle at both the macro and micro-economic levels. The challenging goals imposed by the European Grean Deal to European countries to achieve carbon neutrality (European Comission Citation2019) are leading to the emergence of new private investment funds and public social funds. For instance, the InvestEU Programme running until 2027 brings back the European Fund for Strategic Investments along with other financial instruments, triggering at least €650 billion for investment with a priority on sustainable development.

The new challenges raised to firms have affected firm’s sustainability, social responsibility and governance mechanisms. To adjust their practices, firms may also need to adjust their capital sources, but the literature has remained relatively silent on this issue. Some (partial) exceptions are Sharfman and Fernando (Citation2008), which shows that lower capital costs are observed when there is an improved environmental risk management, with firms transiting from carbon-intensive activities to more sustainable economies typically gaining easier access to capital markets and increasing debt ratios; Nguyen and Phan (Citation2020), which concludes that heavy carbon emitting firms, by facing higher carbon costs that increase their risk of suffering from financial distress, are forced to decrease their debt values; Fernández-Cuesta et al. (Citation2019), which finds that firms’ commitment to the reduction in carbon emissions contributes to reducing information asymmetry between creditors and borrowers, allowing those firms to have better access to long-term debt to finance their relevant environmental investments; and Tascón et al. (Citation2020), which shows that environmental transaction costs slow down the speed of adjustment to target debt levels for carbon emitters. All these studies are limited in scope, being specific for carbon emitting firms and not fully covering the new economic, societal and environmental challenges faced by firms.

The last decades have been marked by a firm’s deleveraging trend, becoming usual to find debt-free firms. Some studies show that there is a growing number of firms that do not hold any amount of (short- and long-term) debt, the so-called ‘zero-leverage phenomenon’ (Strebulaev and Yang Citation2013). Previous literature shows that we are dealing with a global and persistent phenomenon that is influenced by country and institutional specificities and is observed in both large/listed firms and small/private firms (Bessler et al. Citation2013; Devos et al. Citation2012; Ghoul et al. Citation2018; Morais, Serrasqueiro, and Ramalho Citation2021; Ramalho, Rita, and Silva Citation2018; Saona, Vallelado, and Martín Citation2020) and may contribute to raising firm’s value (Chipeta, Aftab, and Machokoto Citation2021; Hamelin, Lefebvre, and Weill Citation2022). Zero leverage is commonly identified as a consequence of financing constraints or the firm’s desire to build up financial flexibility. In the former case, zero leverage results from impositions of creditors who do not wish to grant credit to firms, while in the latter firms deliberately opt for zero-debt policies to build up financial slack and preserve borrowing capacity (Dang Citation2013; Huang, Li, and Gao Citation2017; Morais, Serrasqueiro, and Ramalho Citation2020).

In this paper, we focus on the potential effects of firms’ sustainability, social responsibility and governance practices over their probability of adopting a zero-debt policy. As a proxy for those practices, we use the Environment, Social and Governance (ESG) combined score available at the DataStream database, with a higher score reflecting a better performance in the mentioned practices. Because firm leverage results not only from the demand for debt, but also requires the supply of debt, we investigate the effects of the ESG index on those two quantities. This is in marked contrast with the classical literature on zero leverage, which typically relies on an empirical model (standard logit or probit specifications) that only allows to estimate the overall effect of an explanatory variable on the probability of firms having debt or not. Here, because, as discussed above, zero leverage may be the result of a firm’s own decision or a creditor refusal to grant credit to the firm, we use the bivariate probit model with partial observability (Poirier Citation1980), which allows to separately estimate the effect of any explanatory variable on both the demand and supply of debt. In addition, we use propensity score analysis to estimate the overall effect of the ESG score on the firm’s probability of having zero leverage. In all estimations we use an unbalanced panel of European listed firms for the 2002–2020 period.

The remainder of the paper is organized as follows. Section II formulates some research hypotheses. Section III describes the data and the methodology applied in the empirical analysis. Section IV presents and discusses the main results of the paper. Section V concludes.

II. ESG and capital structure: research hypotheses

Firms’ ESG scores represent a measure for the influence that economic growth, environmental protection, social efficiency and governance elements exert into a firm operation. Several studies focus on a particular element of the ESG score and explore their potential effects on firms. Exploring the environmental element of the ESG score, Huynh and Xia (Citation2020) show that bond returns of firms more sensitive to news about climate change obtain lower returns. In a recent study, Duan et al. (Citation2023) found a positive relationship between lower carbon intensity and bond returns. On the other hand, Bolton and Kacperczyk (Citation2021), exploring whether carbon emissions affect US stock returns, found that carbon emissions positively affect stock returns.

The effects of ESG performance on firm’s activities and attractiveness have recently started to be investigated. Studies have been dedicated to the potential effects of ESG scores on firms’ performance and despite mixed empirical results, most of the studies report a positive effect of ESG performance on firm’s financial performance (Busch and Friede Citation2018; Friede, Busch, and Bassen Citation2015; Ray and Goel Citation2023).

The research on the relationship between ESG scores and firm’s debt is limited. For example, Gao et al. (Citation2022) provide evidence that a positive media ESG spotlight reduces firms’ cost of debt by increasing firm’s reputation. This effect is particularly important for firms with poor governance mechanisms. Brogi et al. (Citation2022) found that high ESG scores are associated with a reduction in firm credit risk and Zhang (Citation2022) shows that some firms, recognizing the importance of ESG performance, ‘greenwash’ their activities making misleading ESG disclosures to be more attractive for external investors. However, to the best of our knowledge, there are no studies investigating the impact of ESG scores on firm’s capital structure. Next, we formulate two hypotheses regarding the impact of ESG scores on the probability of a firm adopting a zero-leverage policy, considering both demand and supply factors.

At the demand level, firm’s ESG performance may have two distinct effects on firms’ capital structure. On the one hand, firms with superior performance may have fewer incentives to engage in harmful environmental projects, such as those that are fossil-fuel based, since such investments may be penalized or declared unsuitable by local governmental entities, investors and/or creditors. In this sense, a better ESG performance is expected to increase the propensity for zero-leverage policies. On the other hand, promoting sustainability, creating wealth and qualified jobs and complying with the environmental and human goals requires considerable investments to allow firms to adjust their activities and technologies (Sharfman and Fernando Citation2008). Consequently, a greater firm’s ESG performance may instead decrease the likelihood of firms having zero leverage. Overall, since most firms are still in a transition phase, we expect this second effect to be superior to the first one in most cases. Therefore, in this paper we test the following hypothesis:

H1:

A higher firms’ ESG performance decreases the propensity for zero leverage by firms’ own decisions.

From a supply-side perspective, we expect a greater willingness of creditors to grant debt to firms with greater levels of sustainability and social responsibility and with better governance mechanisms, since these factors may be a signal of a better-governed firm with good prospects. In fact, there is some evidence that firms with higher ESG scores tend to present a better financial performance than firms with lower ESG scores (e.g., Friede, Busch, and Bassen Citation2015; Ray and Goel Citation2023). Moreover, ESG performance have been identified as a mechanism that reduces information asymmetry (Kim and Park Citation2023). Therefore, banks have been motivated to incorporate environmental issues into their lending decisions (Herbohn, Gao, and Clarkson Citation2019; Jung, Herbohn, and Clarkson Citation2018; Weber, Scholz, and Michalik Citation2010) and to offer favourable financing conditions to better carbon performers and firms with superior social responsibility (Herbohn, Gao, and Clarkson Citation2019; Jung, Herbohn, and Clarkson Citation2018; Weber, Scholz, and Michalik Citation2010). Therefore, the following hypothesis is formulated:

H2:

A higher firm’s ESG performance decreases the propensity for zero leverage due to an increased willingness of creditors to grant debt.

Hence, both due to debt demand and supply factors, we expect that firms with higher ESG scores are less prone to have zero debt.

III. Data, methodology, and variables

The sample

Firm’s accounting, financial and market data were obtained from the DataStream database. Data were collected for listed firms from 14 Western European countries (Austria, Belgium, Denmark, Finland, France, Germany, Greece, Ireland, Italy, Netherlands, Portugal, Spain, Sweden and the UK) over the period ranging from 2002 to 2020. The European context is particularly suitable to investigate the potential effect of ESG performance on the zero-leverage phenomenon since all selected countries are implementing the most recent European Green Deal (European Comission Citation2019).

The firm’s ESG scores were obtained from the new Eikon Refinitiv ESG rating system, which comprises some of the most common ESG indicators used in European studies (Erhart Citation2022; Gigante and Manglaviti Citation2022). Relative to others, this rating has the advantage of being normalized by industry and based on percentile-ranked scores. For example, a score of 0.7 means that a firm performs better than 70% of other firms in the same industry. The Refinitiv ESG rating system has also the advantage of being available in DataStream for firms of the selected countries since 2002.

Using the FTSE/Dow Jones Industry Classification Benchmark (ICB), we excluded from the sample utility and financial firms and also firms without an industry code. We also removed from the sample firm/year observations with missing information for any variable used in the econometric models and observations with obvious errors (e.g. negative sales). Finally, we allowed firms’ entry and exit from the sample to avoid the possible survivorship bias that could arise from considering only successful firms. Our final sample is represented by an unbalanced panel data with 7,095 firm-year observations, corresponding to 1,299 firms.

The bivariate probit model with partial observability

To examine the potential effect of firm’s ESG performance on zero leverage, most empirical studies on the zero-leverage phenomenon use standard probit specifications, which account for the binary nature of the dependent variable ( = 1 if the firm has debt and 0 otherwise). This model assumes that all firms’ requests for debt are successful, which is not true since creditors may not be willing to grant them the requested debt. Conversely, creditors could be willing to grant debt to firms that do not request it. Hence, a problem of partial observability arises since we can only observe the joint outcome of the firm and creditors’ decisions about debt. Therefore, to examine if the potential effect of ESG performance on zero leverage is due to a firm’s own decision or is an imposition of creditors, or both, we use bivariate probit models with partial observability in the sense of Poirier (Citation1980).

We assume that firm’s demand for (short- and long-term) debt is represented by a dichotomous variable y1, which is equal to 1 if the firm wants to resort to debt and is 0 otherwise, while creditors’ supply of debt is defined by the dichotomous variable y2, which takes on the value 1 if the creditor is willing to grant debt and is 0 otherwise. Each dichotomous variable is determined by one latent variable, y1 or y2, being 1 when the associated variable is positive. The latent variables are governed according to:

(1) y1=β1x1+ε1(1)
(2) y2=β2x2+ε2(2)

where x1 (for the demand function) and x2 (for the supply function) are vectors of explanatory variables, β1 and β2 represent the respective coefficients, and ε1 and ε2 are error terms assumed to follow a bivariate normal distribution Φ2ε1,ε2, with Eε1=Eε2=0, Varε1=Varε2=1 and Covε1,ε2=ρ.

We can identify four possible decisions on leverage (‘firms want to resort to debt’, y1 = 1, and ‘creditors want to grant debt’, y2 = 1; ‘firms want to resort to debt’, y1 = 1, but ‘creditors do not want to grant debt’, y2 = 0; ‘firms do not want to resort to debt’, y1 = 0, but ‘creditors would grant debt’, y2 = 1; and ‘firms do not want to resort to debt’, y1 = 0, and ‘creditors would not grant debt’, y2 = 0), with the last three ending up indistinguishable as all we can observe is that firms are debt-free. Therefore, unlike typical zero-leverage empirical studies, we need to directly model the probability of a firm being levered, not of being debt-free. summarizes the partial observability problem surrounding decisions about debt.

Figure 1. Partial observability problem.

Source: Morais et al. (Citation2020).
Figure 1. Partial observability problem.

In this context, the probability that a firm decides to resort to debt and that the debt is actually granted by the creditor is given by:

(3) Proby=1=Proby1>0,y2>0=Prob[ε1>β1x1,ε2>β2x2]=Φ2β1x1,β2x2,ρ(3)

Reciprocally, the probability that the firm holds no debt results from:

(4) Proby=0=1Proby1=1(4)

As noted by Poirier (Citation1980), in spite of not observing y1 and y2, estimation of the coefficients of the demand and supply functions remains feasible. The model’s likelihood function is:

(5) L=y=1Φ2β1x1,β2x2,ρy=01Φ2β1x1,β2x2,ρ(5)

with the demand and supply equations being jointly estimated by maximum likelihood. A requirement for the model to be identified is that at least one of the variables contained in x1 does not appear in x2, or vice versa (x1 x2).

The explanatory variables

Our main explanatory variable is based on the ESG-combined score, which provides a comprehensive scoring of a firm’s Environment, Social and Governance performance discounted by negative media stories (ESG controversies). The score ranges between 0 (poor ESG performance) and 1 (excellent ESG performance). We consider two alternative sets of models. In one set, we use directly ESG combined score as explanatory variable. In the second, we use a dummy variable that distinguishes between firms with higher ESG performance from firms with lower ESG performance. In particular, the ESG dummy variable assumes the value 1 for firms with values in the third tercile of the variable ESG combined score and the value 0 for firms with values in the first tercile. Terciles are computed separately for each year. Firms in the second tercile were dropped from the analysis in order to avoid misclassification of what is considered a higher or lower ESG score.

The estimated econometric models also include a set of standard firm-specific control variables commonly found in the literature to be important for explaining firm’s capital structure decisions, such as Cash holdings, Growth opportunities, Profitability, Dividend payout, Non-debt tax shields, Tangibility and Size. In addition, to control for the influence of the different non-leverage regulatory environments that characterize the countries included in our sample, the models also include the Investment grade dummy variable, which is commonly evaluated regardless of country. Some country-specific control variables are also included in the models. We use the GDP growth rate to control for macroeconomic shocks that may be specific to each country and year. Furthermore, considering that Europe has been deeply affected by the 2008 financial crisis, which affected public and private access to external sources of financing (Laeven and Valencia Citation2018), we use a dummy variable, Crisis, to indicate if a country was in a financial crisis in a given year. In particular, following the classification of Laeven and Valencia (Citation2018), we consider that the 2008 global financial crisis affected countries in different ways, lasting longer in the European countries that suffered a sovereign debt crisis after the original financial crisis. Finally, industry and year dummies are also included in the models.

To meet with the model assumptions, there are variables that we consider as relevant only for the demand for debt (Cash holdings, Non-debt tax shields) or for the supply of debt (Size, Investment grade), since the finance literature presents mostly demand- or supply-related theoretical arguments to justify their effects on debt.Footnote1 Thus, because cash represents the firm’s most liquid asset and creditors rely mainly on more stable assets to make their credit decisions, cash holdings are usually considered as a measure mostly influencing the demand for debt (e.g. Dang Citation2013; Morais, Serrasqueiro, and Ramalho Citation2020). Also, Non-debt tax shields, while relatively irrelevant for creditors’ decisions, may contribute to explain firm’s decisions about debt given that firms with high levels of depreciations and amortizations display lower propensity to take advantage of debt tax shields given the potential substitution between the two sources of tax shields (Morais, Serrasqueiro, and Ramalho Citation2020). On the other hand, firm size and the investment-grade classification are traditional and accepted measures used by creditors to evaluate the firm’s ability to comply with future obligations and therefore are in general viewed as influencing mainly the supply of debt (Dang Citation2013).

The remaining variables (ESG-combined score or the ESG dummy, Growth opportunities, Profitability, Dividend payout, Tangibility and GDP growth rate and Crisis) may be indistinguishable used as possible factors influencing both demand and supply of debt. provides a formal definition of the variables considered in the econometric models and presents descriptive statistics for them. Almost 95% of firm-year observations are classified as levered firms, which means that only 5% of firm-year observations are classified as zero-leverage firms.

Table 1. Definition of the variables.

Table 2. Descriptive statistics.

To examine the overall impact of ESG performance on zero leverage we also used PS methods (Rosenbaum and Rubin Citation1983), which have the advantage of accounting for sample selection effects and promote a direct comparison of the propensity to have zero leverage between firms with greater ESG performance and lower ESG performance. We use the ESG dummy variable as the treatment variable. Hence, firms with ESG dummy equal to 1 are the ‘treatment group’ and firms with ESG dummy equal to 0 are the ‘control group’. We use a logit model, with Leverage as dependent variable, to estimate the PS conditional on all the independent variables considered in the bivariate probit models. Next, using nearest-neighbour matching, we match each firm with greater ESG performance with the lower ESG performance firms that display the closest predicted propensity scores, and vice-versa. Finally, we estimate the differences between the predicted performances for each match and compute the effect of ESG performance on zero leverage by averaging those differences for the whole sample.

IV. Results

Main models

presents the results of the effects of ESG performance on zero leverage. Model (1) is a standard probit model with random effects, while Model (2) is a bivariate probit model with partial observability, analysing separately the determinants that affect firm’s decision to resort to debt and creditors’ decision to grant debt to the firm, which allows testing hypotheses H1 and H2, respectively. Both models use the variable ESG combined score as explanatory variable. Models (3) and (4) are similar to models (1) and (2), respectively, but use ESG dummy as explanatory variable. For all estimated equations, for each independent variable we report in the first row the estimated coefficient and in the second row (in parentheses) the result of an heteroskedasticity-robust Wald test for its individual statistical significance.

Table 3. Regression results.

The Wald tests for the individual and joint statistical significance of the independent variables confirm the ability of both models to explain the respective dependent variables. The estimated ρ in the bivariate probit models with partial observability is statistically significant, confirming that EquationEquations (1) and (Equation2) are interrelated and suggesting that using the bivariate probit model would allow efficiency gains over separate probit estimation of demand and supply equations if that was possible.

Models (1) and (3), on the one hand, and models (2) and (4), on the other hand, present quite similar results in terms of the sign and significance of the coefficients. Therefore, next we present and discuss only the results of models (3) and (4). The former model shows that firm’s ESG performance influence its capital structure. In particular, the ESG dummy variable has a positive and significant coefficient, implying that firms with greater ESG performance are more likely to use debt and thus less prone to have zero leverage. This result may be justified by the argument that to obtain and keep a superior ESG performance, firms need to adjust their activities and technologies, create qualified jobs and improve work conditions, which may imply important investments and hence require more external financing (Sharfman and Fernando Citation2008). It may be also the case that firms with better ESG performance are able to raise debt in more favourable conditions and hence are more prone to use debt. Looking only at the results of Model (3), we are unable to conclude if both explanations are valid or not.

Model (4) shows that the variable ESG dummy is significant only in the supply equation. Therefore, the overall negative effect of ESG performance on zero leverage, found in Model (3), is not motivated by firms’ decision or need to resort to more debt, but due to a greater creditor’s willingness to grant debt to firms. Thus, our results suggest that ESG performance favours access to debt financing. In fact, the emergence of new programmes destined to fund innovation and social entrepreneurship projects at a cost below the usual market conditions seems to be particularly aimed at firms with better ESG performance (Nguyen and Phan Citation2020). These results allow to reject hypothesis H1 and to confirm hypothesis H2.

Model (4) also shows that some of the other variables influencing zero leverage also affect in distinct ways the demand and supply of debt, namely Profitability, Dividend payout, Tangibility and Crisis. Profitability decreases the firm’s propensity to resort to debt but increases the creditor’s willingness to grant debt to them. The demand effect is supported by the financial flexibility theory, which states that firms use their internal sources of liquidity to build up financial slack and preserve debt capacity to be able to invest in the future (Dang Citation2013; Huang, Li, and Gao Citation2017). The supply effect results from the natural greater willingness of creditors to lend to more profitable firms. On the other hand, Dividend payout seems to not significantly affect firm’s debt (univariate probit models), but this happens because it has a positive effect on firms’ decision, or need, to resort to debt, but a negative effect on the decision of creditors to fund firms that pay higher dividends. A possible explanation for the latter effect is that dividend payers are more prone to decapitalize their firms and leave them less able to comply with their debt service, reducing thus the creditor propensity to grant debt to them (Morais, Serrasqueiro, and Ramalho Citation2020). Asset tangibility decreases the propensity for firms resorting to debt, but, on the other hand, increases the propensity for creditors granting debt to them. The supply effect was expected, since firms with greater asset tangibility (more collateral) are less exposed to information asymmetries and consequently less credit constrained (Benmelech and Bergman Citation2009). In contrast, the demand effect is somewhat surprising, since firms with higher levels of tangibility have lower costs of financial distress and bankruptcy given that, in case of bankruptcy, these assets retain their value (Myers Citation1977). Finally, the 2008 financial crisis did not affect debt demand, but increased the propensity towards zero leverage, because creditors were less available to grant credit to firms (Santos Citation2011).

For the remaining variables, their effects on the propensity for firms having debt are the most commonly found in previous literature. The negative effect of Cash holdings on debt demand conforms with the financial flexibility theory. The positive effects of Size and Investment grade on debt supply conforms with the financial constraints’ perspective, which states that larger firms with an investment-grade rating have higher reputation in the debt market, suffering lower information asymmetries (Devos et al. Citation2012; Huang, Li, and Gao Citation2017). The negative effects of GDP growth rate on both debt demand and supply reflects, respectively, the greater availability of internal sources of financing due to the improved economic conditions and the idea that in periods of economic growth the costs of adverse selection are lower, increasing investor’s preference for financing through equity (Choe, Masulis, and Nanda Citation1993).

Robustness tests

As explained before, to identify the two equations (demand and supply) of the bivariate probit model with partial observability it is necessary that the demand and supply equations do not contain exactly the same set of variables. Although we have justified theoretically our variable selection for each equation, other arguments can lead to different exclusion restrictions. Therefore, to test the robustness of the results produced by models (2) and (4) of , now we consider alternative specifications where some of the variables that previously appeared in only one equation are now added also to the other Equation. In particular, assuming that cash holdings may be also used by outsiders to predict firm’s bankruptcy (Ohlson Citation1980), we add the Cash holdings variable to the supply Equation (Model 4a); and, considering that firm size may also explain its demand for debt, since a greater level of assets means investment that perhaps had to be financed by debt, we add the Size variable to the demand equation (Model 4b). To save space, in we only present the results of the specifications that use Model (4) of as baseline.

Table 4. Alternative variables for the demand and supply equations of the bivariate probit model.

As shows, these modifications do not change our main findings. In particular, the sign and statistical significance of the ESG dummy variable do not change across models. Moreover, the variables added to the other equation (Cash holdings to the supply equation and Size to the demand equation) keep a greater relevance in the equation where we considered them initially.

Propensity score analysis

presents the results of the propensity score matching analysis. In the first row of we report the predicted effect of ESG performance on zero leverage. In the other rows, we present diagnostic criteria for the propensity score analysis performed. In particular, for both the original and matched sample, we present descriptive statistics and Rubin’s (Citation2001) diagnostic criteria for the balance of the distribution of the covariate values for the greater and lower ESG performance group of firms. A perfect matching would imply a standardized mean difference of zero across groups and a variance ratio of one. Although not being perfect, the level of balance between the groups improves substantially in the matched sample in all cases and Rubin’s (Citation2001) measures suggest that the matched samples are sufficiently balanced.

Table 5. Propensity score matching estimates.

confirms that firms with greater ESG performance have a lower propensity to have zero leverage. In particular, it is predicted that ESG performance decreases a firm’s zero-leverage propensity by approximately 3.9pp.

V. Conclusion

This paper examines the effect of firm’s ESG performance on the zero-leverage phenomenon, with a particular focus on how ESG performance influences firm’s decision to resort to debt and creditor’s decision to grant debt. In this analysis, we used bivariate probit models with partial observability in the sense of Poirier (Citation1980). Our results suggest that the higher the ESG performance the lower the propensity for firms having zero leverage. However, ESG performance does not seem to significantly influence firm’s decision to raise or not debt. Indeed, it affects only debt supply, since creditors are found to be willing to grant debt in more favourable conditions to firms with greater levels of ESG performance. Overall, according to our PS analysis, firms with greater ESG performance have a propensity to become debt-free that is 3.9pp smaller than that of firms with lower performance.

The observed increase in debt among firms with superior ESG performance may indicate a positive response to financing initiatives that promote sustainable practices. Those firms may benefit from easier access to financing and lower capital costs, resulting in increased profit margins. This can stimulate significant investments in sustainable initiatives, allowing firms to implement more robust environmental and social practices, contributing to long-term sustainability. In short, adopting ESG practices not only mitigates legal and reputational risks associated with environmental and social issues but can also result in tangible financial benefits. However, it is also important to consider potential negative repercussions for firms that meet ESG criteria. Indeed, the easy access to financing can lead to increased indebtedness, which may result in unsustainable debt levels for some companies, thereby increasing financial vulnerability during economic turbulence. It is essential to underscore the need for the efficient deployment of the financing they receive to avoid debt accumulation and suboptimal investments. Creditors can also play a pivotal role by requiring well-defined investment plans prior to disbursement, coupled with ongoing monitoring and evaluation mechanisms, thus ensuring that resources are used effectively. By actively avoiding inefficient financial allocation, stakeholders can foster a conducive environment for sustained economic and sustainable development fostering ESG-oriented firms with an increased capacity to raise the finance needed to develop their business.

Our results are also important for the traditional and extensive literature on capital structure, since they show that classical firm-specific characteristics may not be sufficient to fully explain firm’s capital structure. New theoretical approaches that incorporate the new challenges faced by societies and firms need to be developed to better explain firms’ financial choices.

Acknowledgements

Flávio Morais gratefully acknowledges financial support from Fundacão para a Ciência e a Tecnologia within the projects: NECE UIDB/04630/2020; CEFAGE-UBI UIDB/04007/2020.

Joaquim Ferreira gratefully acknowledge financial support from Fundacão para a Ciência e a Tecnologia within the projects: NECE UIDB/04630/2020.

Luís Marques gratefully acknowledge financial support from Fundacão para a Ciência e a Tecnologia within the projects: NECE UIDB/04630/2020.

Joaquim Ramalho is pleased to acknowledge financial support support from Fundação para a Ciência e a Tecnologia, grant UIDB/00315/2020 (DOI: 10.54499/UIDB/00315/2020).

Disclosure statement

No potential conflict of interest was reported by the author(s).

Additional information

Funding

This work was supported by the Fundação para a Ciência e a Tecnologia [UIDB/00315/2020]; NECE - Research Center in Business Sciences, University of Beira Interior [UIDB/04630/2020].

Notes

1 To avoid some subjectiveness on the variables included in a single equation, in a sensitivity analysis on the robustness tests section we consider alternative specifications where some of the variables that previously appeared in only one equation are added to the other equation.

References

  • Abadie, A., and G. W. Imbens. 2016. “Matching on the Estimated Propensity Score.” Econometrica 84 (2): 781–807. https://doi.org/10.3982/ECTA11293.
  • Benmelech, E., and N. K. Bergman. 2009. “Collateral Pricing.” Journal of Financial Economics 91 (3): 339–360. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jfineco.2008.03.003.
  • Bessler, W., W. Drobetz, R. Haller, and I. Meier. 2013. “The International Zero-Leverage Phenomenon.” Journal of Corporate Finance 23 (1): 196–221. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jcorpfin.2013.08.004.
  • Bolton, P., and M. Kacperczyk. 2021. “Do Investors Care About Carbon Risk?” Journal of Financial Economics 142 (2): 517–549. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jfineco.2021.05.008.
  • Brogi, M., V. Lagasio, and P. Porretta. 2022. “Be Good to Be Wise: Environmental, Social, and Governance Awareness As a Potential Credit Risk Mitigation Factor.” Journal of International Financial Management & Accounting 33 (3): 1–26. https://doi.org/10.1111/jifm.12156.
  • Busch, T., and G. Friede. 2018. “The Robustness of the Corporate Social and Financial Performance Relation: A Second-Order Meta-Analysis.” Corporate Social Responsibility and Environmental Management 25 (4): 583–608. https://doi.org/10.1002/csr.1480.
  • Chipeta, C., N. Aftab, and M. Machokoto. 2021. “The Implications of Financial Conservatism for African Firms.” Finance Research Letters 42:1–9. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.frl.2021.101926.
  • Choe, H., R. W. Masulis, and V. Nanda. 1993. “Common Stock Offerings Across the Business Cycle: Theory and Evidence.” Journal of Empirical Finance 1 (1): 3–31. https://doi.org/10.1016/0927-5398(93)90003-A.
  • Dang, V. A. 2013. “An Empirical Analysis of Zero-Leverage Firms: New Evidence from the UK.” International Review of Financial Analysis 30 (1): 189–202. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.irfa.2013.08.007.
  • Devos, E., U. Dhillon, M. Jagannathan, and S. Krishnamurthy. 2012. “Why Are Firms Unlevered?” Journal of Corporate Finance 18 (3): 664–682. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jcorpfin.2012.03.003.
  • Duan, T., F. Li, and Q. Wen. 2023. “Is Carbon Risk Priced in the Cross Section of Corporate Bond Returns?” The Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis, forthcoming. 1–35. https://doi.org/10.1017/S0022109023000832.
  • Erhart, S. 2022. “Take it with a Pinch of Salt—ESG Rating of Stocks and Stock Indices.” International Review of Financial Analysis 83:102308. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.irfa.2022.102308.
  • European Comission. 2019. “The European Green Deal. European Union Law.” Accessed January 2, 2023. https://eur-lex.europa.eu/legal-content/EN/TXT/?qid=1576150542719&uri=COM%3A2019%3A640%3AFIN.
  • Fernández-Cuesta, C., P. Castro, M. T. Tascón, and J. Castaño. 2019. “The Effect of Environmental Performance on Financial Debt. European Evidence.” Journal of Cleaner Production 207:379–390. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jclepro.2018.09.239.
  • Friede, G., T. Busch, and A. Bassen. 2015. “ESG and Financial Performance: Aggregated Evidence from More Than 2000 Empirical Studies.” Journal of Sustainable Finance & Investment 5 (4): 210–233. https://doi.org/10.1080/20430795.2015.1118917.
  • Gao, H., J. He, and Y. Li. 2022. “Media Spotlight, Corporate Sustainability and the Cost of Debt.” Applied Economics 54 (34): 3989–4005. https://doi.org/10.1080/00036846.2021.2020710.
  • Ghoul, S., O. El Guedhami, C. Kwok, and X. Zheng. 2018. “Zero-Leverage Puzzle: An International Comparison.” Review of Finance 22 (3): 1063–1120.
  • Gigante, G., and D. Manglaviti. 2022. “The ESG Effect on the Cost of Debt Financing: A Sharp RD Analysis.” International Review of Financial Analysis 84:102382. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.irfa.2022.102382.
  • Hamelin, A., V. Lefebvre, and L. Weill. 2022. “No debt no performance? CEO gender matters.” Economics Letters 219:110838. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.econlet.2022.110838.
  • Herbohn, K., R. Gao, and P. Clarkson. 2019. “Evidence on Whether Banks Consider Carbon Risk in Their Lending Decisions.” Journal of Business Ethics 158 (1): 155–175. https://doi.org/10.1007/s10551-017-3711-3.
  • Huang, Z., W. Li, and W. Gao. 2017. “Why Do Firms Choose Zero-Leverage Policy? Evidence from China.” Applied Economics 49 (28): 2736–2748. https://doi.org/10.1080/00036846.2016.1245845.
  • Huynh, T., and Y. Xia. 2020. “Climate Change News Risk and Corporate Bond Returns.” Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis 56 (6): 1985–2009 1–49. https://doi.org/10.1017/S0022109020000757.
  • Jung, J., K. Herbohn, and P. Clarkson. 2018. “Carbon Risk, Carbon Risk Awareness and the Cost of Debt Financing.” Journal of Business Ethics (2016) 150 (4): 1151–1171. https://doi.org/10.1007/s10551-016-3207-6.
  • Kim, J., and C. Park. 2023. “Can ESG Performance Mitigate Information Asymmetry? Moderating Effect of Assurance Services.” Applied Economics 55 (26): 2993–3007. https://doi.org/10.1080/00036846.2022.2107991.
  • Laeven, L., and F. Valencia. 2018. “Systemic Banking Crises Revisited.” IMF Working Paper, 2018(206), 1–47.
  • Morais, F., Z. Serrasqueiro, and J. J. S. Ramalho. 2020. “The Zero-Leverage Phenomenon: A Bivariate Probit with Partial Observability Approach.” Research in International Business and Finance 53:1–16. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.ribaf.2020.101201.
  • Morais, F., Z. Serrasqueiro, and J. J. S. Ramalho. 2021. “The Zero-Leverage Phenomenon in European Listed Firms: A Financing Decision or an Imposition of the Financial Market?” BRQ Business Research Quarterly 1–23. https://doi.org/10.1177/23409444211024653.
  • Myers, S. C. 1977. “Determinants of Corporate Borrowing.” Journal of Financial Economics 5 (2): 147–175.
  • Nguyen, J. H., and H. V. Phan. 2020. “Carbon Risk and Corporate Capital Structure.” Journal of Corporate Finance 64:101713. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jcorpfin.2020.101713.
  • Ohlson, J. A. 1980. “Financial Ratios and the Probabilistic Prediction of Bankruptcy.” Journal of Accounting Research 18 (1): 109–131. https://doi.org/10.2307/2490395.
  • Poirier, D. J. 1980. “Partial observability in bivariate probit models.” Journal of Econometrics 12 (2): 209–217. https://doi.org/10.1016/0304-4076(80)90007-X.
  • Ramalho, J. J. S., R. M. Rita, and J. V. Silva. 2018. “The Impact of Family Ownership on Capital Structure of Firms: Exploring the Role of Zero-Leverage, Size, Location and the Global Financial Crisis.” International Small Business Journal 36 (5): 574–604. https://doi.org/10.1177/0266242617753050.
  • Ray, R., and S. Goel. 2023. “Impact of ESG Score on Financial Performance of Indian Firms: Static and Dynamic Panel Regression Analyses.” Applied Economics 55 (15): 1742–1755. https://doi.org/10.1080/00036846.2022.2101611.
  • Rosenbaum, P. R., and D. B. Rubin. 1983. “The Central Role of the Propensity Score in Observational Studies for Causal Effects.” Biometrika 70 (1): 41–55. https://doi.org/10.1093/biomet/70.1.41.
  • Rubin, D. B. 2001. “Using Propensity Scores to Help Design Observational Studies: Application to the Tobacco Litigation.” Health Services and Outcomes Research Methodology 2 (3/4): 169–188. https://doi.org/10.1023/A:1020363010465.
  • Santos, J. 2011. “Bank Corporate Loan Pricing Following the Subprime Crisis.” The Review of Financial Studies 24 (6): 1916–1943. https://doi.org/10.1093/rfs/hhq115.
  • Saona, P., E. Vallelado, and P. Martín. 2020. “Debt, or Not Debt, That Is the Question: A Shakespearean Question to a Corporate Decision.” Journal of Business Research 115:378–392. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jbusres.2019.09.061.
  • Sharfman, M. P., and C. S. Fernando. 2008. “Environmental Risk Management and the Cost of Capital.” Strategic Management Journal 29 (6): 569–592. https://doi.org/10.1002/smj.678.
  • Strebulaev, I. A., and B. Yang. 2013. “The Mystery of Zero-Leverage Firms.” Journal of Financial Economics 109 (1): 1–23. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jfineco.2013.02.001.
  • Tascón, M. T., P. Castro, C. Fernández-Cuesta, and J. Castaño. 2020. “Environmental Transaction Costs and Speed of Adjustment to Target Debt in European Carbon Emitters.” Journal of Cleaner Production 256:1–10. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jclepro.2020.120483.
  • Weber, O., R. Scholz, and G. Michalik. 2010. “Incorporating Sustainability Criteria into Credit Risk Management.” Business Strategy and the Environment 19 (1): 39–50. https://doi.org/10.1002/bse.636.
  • Zhang, D. 2022. “Are Firms Motivated to Greenwash by Financial Constraints? Evidence from Global firms’ Data.” Journal of International Financial Management & Accounting 1–21. https://doi.org/10.1111/jifm.12153.