727
Views
17
CrossRef citations to date
0
Altmetric
Original Articles

SURVEY OF RECENT DEVELOPMENTS

&
Pages 7-32 | Published online: 16 Jul 2008

Abstract

Summary Macroeconomic performance continued its steady improvement during 2007, with quite strong growth, moderate inflation, a reasonably stable exchange rate, and a strongly performing stock market. A promising sign has been rapid investment growth, although the global economic slow‐down predicted for 2008 is likely to reduce Indonesia's exports, and therefore its growth rate. Moreover, rapid increases in food and energy prices on world markets seem likely to require some tightening of monetary policy to keep inflation in check.

The 2008 budget finalised in November assumed a world oil price of $60 per barrel, even though the actual price was already closer to $90. By February it reached $100, and the government announced its intention to revise the budget further in light of this and of the likely impact of the coming global slow‐down. While the impact of higher oil prices on the budget deficit can readily be accommodated, the subsidy cost of holding domestic energy prices constant will be enormous. Under‐spending on infrastructure continues to be a problem‐partly because so much revenue is being pre‐empted for subsidies, but also because funding allocations are not being fully spent, and because coordination between different government jurisdictions is lacking.

January 2008 saw the passing of former president Soeharto, whose 32 years in power dramatically reshaped the Indonesian economy. Despite the well‐known human rights abuses and high level of corruption under his regime, the government observed a seven‐day period of mourning, and there was a genuine display of grief on the part of many ordinary Indonesians.

There have been worrying developments in relation to two institutions established as part of Indonesia's post‐Soeharto democratisation, and in relation to the parliament (DPR) itself. The Business Competition Supervisory Commission's decisions on the mobile phone industry appear likely to do further damage to foreign investors' perceptions of Indonesia, and to be harmful to consumers' interests. The DPR's appointment of five new members of the Anti‐Corruption Commission (KPK) followed a closed‐door selection process, the outcome of which suggested that the commission faces capture and subversion by other public sector institutions seeking to block anti‐corruption efforts. Finally, a case brought by the KPK against officials of the central bank, including the current governor, has provided strong evidence of the apparently widespread practice of government agencies bribing DPR members.

SUMMARY

Macroeconomic performance continued its steady improvement during 2007, with quite strong growth, moderate inflation, a reasonably stable exchange rate, and a strongly performing stock market. A promising sign has been rapid investment growth, although the global economic slow-down predicted for 2008 is likely to reduce Indonesia's exports, and therefore its growth rate. Moreover, rapid increases in food and energy prices on world markets seem likely to require some tightening of monetary policy to keep inflation in check.

The 2008 budget finalised in November assumed a world oil price of $60 per barrel, even though the actual price was already closer to $90. By February it reached $100, and the government announced its intention to revise the budget further in light of this and of the likely impact of the coming global slow-down. While the impact of higher oil prices on the budget deficit can readily be accommodated, the subsidy cost of holding domestic energy prices constant will be enormous. Under-spending on infrastructure continues to be a problem–partly because so much revenue is being pre-empted for subsidies, but also because funding allocations are not being fully spent, and because coordination between different government jurisdictions is lacking.

January 2008 saw the passing of former president Soeharto, whose 32 years in power dramatically reshaped the Indonesian economy. Despite the well-known human rights abuses and high level of corruption under his regime, the government observed a seven-day period of mourning, and there was a genuine display of grief on the part of many ordinary Indonesians.

There have been worrying developments in relation to two institutions established as part of Indonesia's post-Soeharto democratisation, and in relation to the parliament (DPR) itself. The Business Competition Supervisory Commission's decisions on the mobile phone industry appear likely to do further damage to foreign investors’ perceptions of Indonesia, and to be harmful to consumers’ interests. The DPR's appointment of five new members of the Anti-Corruption Commission (KPK) followed a closed-door selection process, the outcome of which suggested that the commission faces capture and subversion by other public sector institutions seeking to block anti-corruption efforts. Finally, a case brought by the KPK against officials of the central bank, including the current governor, has provided strong evidence of the apparently widespread practice of government agencies bribing DPR members.

MAJOR EVENTS

On the international front, Indonesia successfully hosted the enormous UN Framework Convention on Climate Change meeting in Bali during December. The event involved over 10,000 delegates and observers from 180 countries, and put Indonesia on the world centre stage for two weeks. There was some irony in the fact that Indonesia is the world's third-largest contributor to the production of greenhouse gases owing to the vast scale of forest-clearing activity. A new international mechanism to encourage slowing deforestation was discussed, but at the core of the negotiations was the question of what commitments developing countries would make to limit greenhouse gas emissions in future, and the continued unwillingness of the USA to commit to emissions targets. With high drama in the effort to obtain consensus, the conference managed at the last minute to produce a ‘Bali Roadmap’ that set timetables and parameters for vital negotiations about the follow-up to the Kyoto Protocol, which expires in 2012. For Indonesia this was a success in terms of foreign policy. Both environment minister Rachmat Witoelar, as president of the conference, and Indonesia's President Suslio Bambang Yudhoyono, who involved himself in the efforts to break the final deadlock, can claim some credit.

Of far greater impact on the general populace, former President Soeharto passed away on 27 January 2008. Under his leadership from 1966 until 1998 Indonesia achieved sustained high rates of economic growth and a considerable reduction in poverty, and was transformed from the ‘prime economic under-performer’ in Southeast Asia into a ‘newly industrialising economy’ (Thee 2001). His New Order regime will also be remembered, however, for political repression, for widespread human rights abuses (especially in East Timor, Aceh and Papua) and for the extensive system of corruption over which he presided, all of which resulted in his being forced to resign when the economic crisis of the late 1990s robbed the regime of performance legitimacy. The final notable item in his long list of strong actions against those who dared openly to criticise him was to secure in August 2007 a Supreme Court reversal of earlier court decisions in favour of Time magazine, which Soeharto had sued for defamation. The Supreme Court ordered Time to pay $106 million in damages; a petition for a review of the ruling was lodged in February. Despite the many black marks against the former president's name, the government declared a seven-day period of national mourning, and many observers were struck by the genuine display of grief on the part of ordinary Indonesians at his passing.

MACROECONOMIC DEVELOPMENTS

Macroeconomic performance in 2007 was sound. Output (GDP) growth continued its steady upward trend through the third quarter, falling back a littie in the fourth, and exactly achieving the 6.3% expansion assumed in the budget for 2007. Open unemployment has continued its gradual downward trend, from 10.5% in February 2006 to 9.1 % in August 2007. Consumer prices rose by 6.6% in the calendar year, almost exactly the same rate as assumed in the budget, and only a little above the mid-point of the central bank's target range (6±1%). The exchange rate against the US dollar has been reasonably stable, with a 4.4% depreciation through 2007. The main stock market index showed a healthy return of more than 50% to investors over the year, notwithstanding a short-lived setback early in the second half: the Indonesian stock market was the third-best performer in the region (Trimegah Research Citation2008). All categories of bank lending have been growing rapidly.

This solid performance was achieved despite recent turbulence in international financial markets in the second half of the year. In July 2007 the ‘sub-prime lending’ crisis in the US found many financial institutions heavily exposed to high-risk borrowers in the home mortgage market. This resulted in upward adjustments of interest rates in many countries, and it is widely expected that world economic growth will slow appreciably in 2008 as a consequence. The sudden upheaval in global financial markets has been accompanied by rapid increases in oil and food prices. These major external developments, and the way they are likely to be handled by policy makers, call into question the likelihood that the Indonesian economy will perform as well in 2008 as it did in 2007.

Economic growth

Year-on-year GDP growth continued to accelerate through the third quarter (Q3) of 2007, reaching 6.5%–a rate exceeded in only one quarter (Q4 2004) in the postcrisis period–before declining slightly to 6.3% in the fourth quarter. Non-oil and gas GDP continued to grow at a somewhat higher rate of around 7.0% for the last three quarters of 2007 (). Household consumption absorbs almost two-thirds of GDP and, while still growing a little more slowly than the economy as a whole (at 5.6%), has continued to accelerate over the past six quarters, suggesting that individuals are increasingly confident about future prospects. Likewise, the growth of investment spending, while much more volatile, accelerated significantly during the last half of 2007, suggesting that this confidence extends to the business sector. The capacity for future growth depends, of course, on investment.

TABLE 1. Components of GDP growth (2000 prices; % p.a. year on year)

The pattern of investment spending has been changing somewhat recently. Although building construction growth accelerated noticeably in the second half of 2007, to reach 9.9% in Q4, the acceleration of non-construction investment was even more dramatic, with the growth rate moving from only 1.5% in December 2006 to over 19% a year later. This outcome was dominated by investment in machinery and equipment, which recorded extremely rapid growth in the last three quarters of 2007. A possible explanation for this is that businesses have tired of waiting for the government to reform the labour market laws, and have decided instead to substitute capital for labour in the production process. Investment in transport turned around dramatically in the second half of 2007, from highly negative to quite strongly positive.

Both exports and imports have been growing a little more rapidly than the economy as a whole, but import growth almost doubled in the December quarter, causing net exports to contract after growing strongly during the first three quarters. solid global demand and consequent price increases in the international market resulted in record high export values in 2007. Total merchandise exports in 2007 amounted to $114 billion, 13.1% higher than for the same period in 2006, with an even larger increase of 15.5% recorded for non-oil and gas items, to $92 billion (CEIC Asia Database).Footnote1 Meanwhile, imports of raw materials have also been increasing at a rapid pace, as has the much smaller category of capital goods imports; consumer goods imports have also been buoyant, reflecting accelerating growth in consumption overall ().

FIGURE 1.  Imports by Major Category (& million)

Source: CEIC Asia Database.

FIGURE 1.  Imports by Major Category (& million) Source: CEIC Asia Database.

On the production side of the national income accounts, growth of the nontradables sector remains consistently more rapid than that of the tradables sector, with the differential between them widening significantly in the fourth quarter of 2007 (). Most of the sub-sectors within non-tradables have continued to experience robust growth, with communications the stand-out performer. Performance of the transport sub-sector was quite poor in 2007, however, consistent with a declining level of investment in the first half; this, in turn, may have reflected insufficient spending by governments on transport infrastructure (roads, ports, airports, railways and so on). Nevertheless, the growth rate in transport recovered to 5.6% by the end of the year, after a surprisingly large adjustment in the most recently issued national accounts data to the September quarter growth rate of investment in transport: this was revised to −1.1% from the previously reported −7.5%.Footnote2 Within the tradables sector, growth has been generally sluggish, with the exception of the September quarter growth in the rather volatile agriculture, livestock, forestry and fisheries sub-sector. Manufacturing growth rates declined steadily for the entire period shown in , to just 3.8% in the December quarter of 2007; it will be interesting to see whether the recent rapid expansion of investment in machinery and equipment can arrest this decline.

Despite this generally rosy economic growth picture, there is no room for complacency. The expected global economic slow-down is likely to hurt Indonesia's growth performance through its negative impact on exports. In response to the sub-prime mortgage crisis, 2008 growth forecasts for countries and regions that are the main destinations for Indonesia's non-oil and gas exports have been slashed; for example, the most recently available IMF World Economic Outlook Update Qanuary 2008: IMF Citation2008) projects significant reductions in output growth in 2008 in the US, the euro area, Japan and elsewhere ().

TABLE 2. Indonesian Export Destinations: Export Shares and GDP Growth Rates

Aside from the external threats of a global economic slow-down and persistent uncertainty in financial markets, Indonesia's performance will continue to be affected by problems of its own making–specifically, inadequate infrastructure and rigidity in the labour market (Manning and Roesad Citation2006). The weakness of investment spending in the transport sector (until recently) and the sluggish growth of this sector have already been noted. Neglect of the infrastructure needed to control flooding, particularly in important commercial and industrial centres such as Jakarta, was very clearly demonstrated when the capital was cut off from the main national airport, Cengkareng, after heavy rains at the end of January.

Fiscal policy

The budget for 2008 was enacted in early November 2007 (). There were a number of relatively minor changes from the draft version submitted to the parliament in August, such that planned revenues increased by Rp 20 trillion and planned expenditures by Rp 18 trillion; the revised deficit is only negligibly smaller, at 1.7% of projected GDP The main adjustments on the revenue side are a surprisingly large (proportionate) rise in international trade taxes, together with increases in oil and gas revenues and in dividends from state enterprises. On the expenditure side, there are large but unfortunately non-transparent rises in ‘Other subsidies’ and in ‘Other expenditure’, together with a range of increased transfers to regional governments, not least of which is an almost four-fold jump in ‘Adjustment funds’.

TABLE 3. Budgets for 2007 and 2008 (Rp trillion)

Of much greater importance than these changes is the absence of any change at all in one of the most important numbers in the entire document: the assumed world oil price, which remained at $60 per barrel. This figure is a little lower than the actual average price in 2006 of $64.30 per barrel, significantly less than the 2007 average of $71.10, and roughly a third less than the level of $87.60 at the end of that year. World oil prices were on a rapidly increasing trend in 2007, from $57 in Q1 to almost $88 in Q4 and, although they levelled off in January at $90.70, they exceeded $100 per barrel during part of February.Footnote3 There is little reason to believe they will average $60 per barrel for the whole of 2008. The government, particularly the Ministry of Finance (MOF), risks being perceived as divorced from reahty by making this assumption.

Yet this is clearly not the case. Indeed, the MOF has undertaken its own analysis of the impact on the budget of oil prices remaining near recent levels, and government ministers have discussed this analysis in public forums (e.g. Pangestu 2008). If the average oil price turns out to be, say, $100 per barrel in 2008, oil revenues (including income tax from oil and gas producers) are expected to increase by $13.7 billion, while expenditures on domestic fuel and electricity subsidies and additional transfers to regional governments are together expected to rise by $19.7 billion. The impact would be to increase the deficit by about $6 billion–almost doubling it, to about 3.0% of GDP. This increase would be large, but by no means catastrophic.

The MOF has put forward a list of nine anticipative policy measures in an attempt to assure observers of the government's preparedness to cope with the impact of significantly higher oil prices. Unfortunately the two documents outlining these measures (Abimanyu and Megantara 2007; Pangestu 2008) give few details, and appear to differ somewhat from each other. The discussion that follows is therefore necessarily based to some extent on guesswork. The list includes both revenue-increasing and expenditure-reducing measures, and it is claimed that together they would almost exactly offset the impact of oil price increases on the budget deficit, thus leaving it at 1.7–1.8% of GDP even if the oil price should rise to $100 per barrel. This claim seems somewhat lacking in conviction, how-ever, because some of the items on the list are deficit-financing rather than deficit-reducing measures.

Deficit-reducing measures

Improving the efficiency (and thus the profitability) of Pertamina (the national oil company) and PLN (the national electricity company), allowing an increase in dividends from the former (which accounts for about half the dividend income from all state-owned enterprises) and a decrease in subsidies to the latter

It goes without saying that this is a desirable objective, but if it is feasible, this begs the question of why the government would not move along these lines even if there were no change in the oil price. Note also that, hidden in the brief discussion of this item in Abimanyu and Megantara (2007) is the suggestion that Pertamina's efficiency could be improved by reducing the subsidy to consumption of fuels. Of course it is profitability rather than efficiency that would be increased in this way, but the interesting point is that these government officials appear here to be trying to put the reduction of fuel subsidies back on the agenda for public discussion–albeit with a high degree of circumspection.

Increasing/‘optimising’ tax revenue and dividends from the state-owned enterprises (SOEs)

It is not clear how tax revenue from SOEs could be increased, since this depends on their profits, which depend on their business success, rather than being a matter for government discretion. And although it would be possible to require them to pay higher dividends to their owner, this would simply shift the problem elsewhere within the government sector–depriving the SOEs of cash resources that they might otherwise have used for investment.Footnote4

Prioritisation of government expenditures; and

Use of unrealised expenditure in the budget

The government beheves there is a potential for significant cuts to some items in its budgeted expenditures, but does not reveal what these might include; explicitly excluded, however, is any interruption to spending on poverty and infrastructure. In addition, there appears to be an expectation of continued spending shortfalls because of administrative bottlenecks of one kind or another, which obviously would reduce the reahsed deficit.

Modification of energy policy with regard to production and subsidisation of oil and gas and power

Expanded crude oil production would increase government revenue, but the budget already assumes an increased output of 1.034 million barrels per day (notwithstanding the fact that production has fallen short of budget assumptions for the last three years), so it is difficult to imagine any additional deficit reduction potential here. On the consumption side, Abimanyu and Megantara (Citation2007) state that the success of the program to switch households away from (subsidised) kerosene to natural gas is vital to cutting subsidies, but there is no indication of how this switch might be accelerated. Similarly, mention is made of bringing about a switch in the fuel mix used in electricity generation, but it is not clear how this would help to reduce the cost of producing electricity: presumably, producers are already using the least costly fuels available to them.

BOX 1 Missing the Big Picture: Oil Prices and Energy Subsidies

To focus on the implications for the deficit of potentially higher oil prices is almost completely to ignore a key feature of the 2008 budget: the damage that is being done by holding domestic fuel and electricity prices constant regardless of huge increases in world energy prices. Indonesia's oil and gas reserves are assets in the ground that have the potential to be transformed into valuable assets of lasting benefit to current and future generations–such as schools, hospitals, other infrastructure and human capital.a Instead, in the absence of policy adjustments, they are to continue to be plundered to finance current consumption–with considerably larger benefits to the more wealthy members of the community, whose direct and indirect consumption of energy is greater than that of the poor It is difficult to judge why the parliament would accept–or, indeed, favour–the patently unrealistic oil price assumption in the budget. Clearly it has an important role to play in negotiating the details of the budget with the government of the day, but items that involve assumptions about the state of the world in the fiscal year in question should not be matters for bargaining, since they do not involve questions of government policy. Requiring, or allowing, the government to assume an oil price of $60 will not make it so in reality; requiring it to make a more realistic assumption would force it to bring into the open the implication of its current policy of holding domestic energy prices constant. If the average oil price in 2008 is indeed close to $100 per barrel, the total cost of the implied subsidy is likely to be in the order of $26 billion (table 4). For its part, the government's commitment to the ideals of democracy, one of which is a high level of transparency about its deployment of funds belonging to society, can hardly be said to be strong if it is prepared to sign off on a budget that deliberately under-estimates by perhaps $18 billion the cost of its policy of holding domestic energy prices constant.

aAccording to tlie Ministry of Finance (2007), combined spending by the ministries of education and health accounts for 8.0% of tire 2008 draft budget – less than the greatly under-estimated 8.9% figure for energy subsidies based on the assumption of an oU price of $60 per barrel. (This sectoral breakdown Is not available for the agreed 2008 budget.)

Deficit-financing measures

Issue more government bonds to the general pubhc; and

Issue bonds to regional governments in oil-producing areas

Both measures appear feasible. The rationale for the second measure is that regional governments in oil-producing areas receive a windfall share of any increase in the central government's oil and gas revenues, which may leave them with excess liquidity. If most or all of the additional transfers to local governments in oil-producing areas could be borrowed back by the central government, this would suffice to cover a significant proportion of the estimated increase in the deficit caused by an oil price increase to, say, $100 per barrel (see table 4 in box 1).

BOX 1 (continued) Missing the Big Picture: Oil Prices and Energy Subsidies

TABLE 4 Estimated Impact of $100 per Barrel Oil on the Budget

aRupiah values are converted to dollar values at the exchange rate of Rp 9,100/$ assumed in the budget.

bThe additions to the approved budget are from a presentation by the Minister for Trade (Pangestu Citation2008), based on an analysis by the Ministry of Finance, for an assumed oil price of $100/barrel.

cThe additional value of energy subsidies is estimated as the addition to oil and gas expenditures and transfers less estimated additional oil and gas transfers to regional governments.

dThe additional oil and gas transfers to regional governments are assumed to be proportional to the increase in the central government's oil and gas revenue (78.1%).

Ross H. McLeod

Miscellaneous measures

Use of contingency funds in the budget

The purpose of having a contingency fund is to provide a cushion against unexpected and unfavourable future events. An average oil price much higher than $60 per barrel in 2008 can hardly be described as unexpected; in any case, using these funds would simply mean removing that cushion.
  • Counter-cyclical fiscal policy measures

Counter-cyclical fiscal policy is running a deficit in order to increase aggregate demand and thus stimulate economic activity (or running a surplus in order to dampen it). Indeed, deficits in the various budgets and revised budgets in recent years have been increasing, precisely with this in mind.Footnote5 Here, the ministry is arguing in favour of stimulating aggregate demand by offering income tax ‘facilities’ to encourage both investment and the listing of firms on the stock exchange, as well as a number of customs duty incentives. Such measures obviously tend to increase rather than decrease the deficit, so it is hard to understand why they have been discussed in the context of the need to deal with an expected blow-out in the deficit.

In summary, the oil price is likely to be much higher than assumed, and this will significantly increase the budget deficit in the absence of adjustments to other expenditure and revenue items. None of the anticipative policy measures proposed seems likely to be able to achieve much in this regard, but the existence of ‘fat’ in the budget and the inability of the government to spend as much as it budgets for makes the problem less serious. In any case, it would not be difficult to borrow by issuing additional government bonds to finance a larger deficit. For a discussion of the likely impact of higher oil prices on the magnitude of subsidies to energy consumption, see box 1.

In mid-February the government indicated that it would soon propose a further revision to its 2008 budget in order to reflect the impact on the growth rate of the probable slow-down in the world economy, and the likelihood of a much higher oil price. The growth assumption was likely to be brought down to 6.4%, and the oil price assumption increased to $83 per barrel (Nurhayati and Suharmoko Citation2008). At the same time, the assumed inflation rate would be increased to 6.5%. Whether a change in the oil price assumption will be accompanied by any change in energy subsidy policies remains unclear. Reducing fuel and electricity subsidies is a complex issue, of course, and fraught with political risk to the incumbent government. But we would argue that governments should always focus on the efficiency of budget spending allocations in promoting superior economic outcomes, rather than responding to populist or other pressures. It is important to avoid any negative relationship between government spending and economic growth, as was evident in the pre-crisis period (Ramayandi Citation2003). Improved efficiency in allocating budget spending to infrastructure and other capital goods, in particular, has to remain the core focus of the budget process.

Under-spending on infrastructure

That there was a significant reduction in spending on infrastructure in the aftermath of the 1990s crisis is readily explained by the fact that the government had injected a huge volume of its own bonds as new equity into the many banks that had failed. Interest payments on these bonds immediately began to consume a large proportion of available revenues, which in any case were depressed as a consequence of the deep recession that followed the crisis. More recently, however, the government has turned its back on the opportunity presented by significant increases in the world oil price to remedy this short-term forced neglect of infrastructure; it has chosen instead to bend to populist pressure to keep domestic fuel and electricity prices low through heavy subsidisation. But even infrastructure spending for which funding is available in the budget has been hampered by administrative shortcomings, especially at local government level. And in other infrastructure projects where the government has tried to encourage private sector participation, this has been held back by similar administrative and other institutional failings, and by the apparent inabihty of the bureaucracy to formulate arrangements that would provide potential investors with an attractive rate of return relative to the risks involved.

Infrastructure inadequacies constitute an important part of the poor investment climate overall, and impose a constraint on economic development (Lindblad and Thee Citation2007: 25; Narjoko and Jotzo Citation2007:159). Less than two-thirds of Indonesians have access to electricity, and blackouts are frequent (JP, 11/2/2008). More than 100 million people lack access to safe drinking water, and contaminated water is the major cause of illness (USAID Citation2006). In 2004 only 58% of Indonesia's 340,000 kilometres of roads were paved, and only around half were in good condition. Traffic congestion continues to hamper the efficient operation of large cities like Jakarta, Bandung, Medan and Surabaya, and satellite towns like Bogor, Bekasi and Tangerang (World Bank Citation2008). City-wide flooding in Jakarta in early February claimed three lives and forced thousands to leave their homes (Antara News, 2/2/2008). The impact of torrential rain and high tides was compounded by rampant over-development and deforestation in the hinterland south of the city, and by rivers and drainage canals being clogged with garbage.

Current infrastructure deficiencies can be attributed to three general factors: inadequate budget allocations to infrastructure; under-spending of these allocations; and a lack of coordination between jurisdictions. In relation to the first factor, recent overall budget allocations for infrastructure spending, at around 3 % of GDP, have been far lower than the pre-crisis levels of approximately 5% (World Bank Citation2004:11). If existing infrastructure assets are to be adequately maintained and their capacity increased, the financing needs are substantial. For example, according to World Bank (Citation2004) estimates, annual investments of $2–3 billion are needed to meet even modest growth in electricity demand through to 2010; the roads sector could easily absorb $700–750 million more per year for maintenance, betterment and expansion; and $600 million per year is considered a conservative estimate of the spending needed to meet the United Nations Millennium Development Goals in relation to drinking water and sanitation. Raising Indonesia's relatively low tele-communications density by one percentage point costs about $300 milhon.Footnote6

When the present government first came to office it had great hopes for overcoming its lack of revenue to devote to new investment in infrastructure by encouraging the involvement of the private sector through public-private partnerships (PPPs) (McLeod 2005: 144–6). However, the implementation of this strategy has been disappointingly slow. One of the reasons for this has been the administrative and political difficulties involved in land acquisition. McLeod (Citation2005:146–7) described a new regulation that had been introduced precisely to facilitate the resumption of private land for purposes such as the construction of public infrastructure. As is so often the case, however, the enactment of the new measure has not been sufficient, on its own, to overcome the problem in question. Thus, for example, the opening of the Cikunir toll road (part of the Jakarta Outer Ring Road) in September 2007 had been delayed for two years owing to land disputes with locals (Wongso 2008), despite the fact that the regulation clearly allows the government to resume land for such purposes upon payment of fair compensation to its previous owners. More generally, problems with land acquisition are seriously jeopardising the construction of major toll roads. By November 2007, only 250 of the 12,000 hectares needed to construct the 40 toll roads currently planned had been acquired, and land acquisition had yet to be completed for a single toll road some three years after the 2005 infrastructure summit (Wongso 2008).

Aside from the problem of delay, the evident ability of owners to hold out for a higher level of compensation for resumption of their land creates an important risk for potential private sector investors. The government has responded by guaranteeing to cap the land acquisition cost to be borne by private investors at 110% of the estimated cost (Wongso Citation2008); that is, the government guarantees to pay the difference between the actual cost and 110% of the estimated cost.

The second factor contributing to infrastructure deficiencies is limited capacity at sub-national level to spend all the funds allocated to infrastructure. Since 2001, responsibihty for the provision of infrastructure and public goods has been devolved in large part from the central government to local governments, but the latter still lack the technical capabilities to use the funds transferred to them for planning and implementing infrastructure projects. To some extent, they also have yet to embrace their new responsibilities as service providers. A consequence of this is that a significant proportion of funds received from the central government that could be used for infrastructure development have simply been deposited with the banking system, often to be invested by the banks in Bank Indonesia Certificates (SBls), where they earn quite an attractive return. During the three years to November 2007, sub-national governments’ bank deposits grew rapidly, from Rp 59 trillion to Rp 141 trillion (CEIC Asia Database); the latter amount is equivalent to over half of the total budgeted transfers from the central government to sub-national governments in 2007 (). It is clear that the collective capacity or desire of sub-national governments to spend is significantly lower than the funds available to them.

A third problem with certain types of infrastructure arises from the need for coordination between levels of government, and between different governments at the same level. For example, national highways are the responsibility of the central government, but they cross through provinces and districts, thus requiring coordination between these three levels of government. Even more difficult is the case of infrastructure related to water–irrigation, flood control, and drinking water supply –all of which are very likely to involve the flow of water across administrative borders. Despite the obvious need for it, examples of intergovernment cooperation in relation to infrastructure projects of this kind are few, and there seems to be a lack of commitment to promoting such cooperation and coordination. Much more thought will need to be given to creating appropriate incentives for cooperation than has hitherto been the case. For example, cities such as Jakarta and Bandung rely on adjacent jurisdictions for their water supplies, and are heavily affected by flooding after rain falls in adjacent jurisdictions, but the latter have little or no incentive to supply water or to control rainfall runoff to the big cities downstream from them.

Financial markets and monetary policy

The stock market and the foreign exchange market

After a short-lived setback in August related to the emergence of the sub-prime crisis in the US, the Indonesia Stock Exchange performed very well for the remainder of 2007 (figure 7).Footnote7 The Jakarta Composite Index (JCI) rose by 43% from its low point in mid-August through to the end of the year, indicating considerable confidence in the Indonesian economy, particularly on the part of foreign investors: indeed, monthly net share purchases by foreigners were positive throughout the year. However, the Indonesian capital market appears still to be vulnerable to continuing volatility in the world financial market as a result of the sub-prime crisis. The index suddenly fell by some 19% in the middle of January 2008, although a large part of this loss was quickly recovered. In such circumstances, it is very much open to doubt whether the IDX can continue to perform as well as it did in 2007. Of course, Indonesia is not alone in this respect.

The rupiah exchange rate was relatively stable during the several months through January 2008 (). While this tends to be interpreted positively, many other currencies have been appreciating against the US dollar during the second half of 2007. The weakness of the dollar is a reflection of both the subprime crisis and the dramatic loosening of US monetary policy in response to it. compares exchange rate trends among five ASEAN economies (Indonesia, Singapore, Malaysia, Thailand and the Philippines), and shows that the rupiah, alone among the currencies of this group, failed to appreciate against the US dollar during the second half.

FIGURE 2.  Jakarta Composite Index (JCI) and Exchange Rate

Source: Indonesia Stock Exchange (IDX); Pacific Exchange Rate Service.

FIGURE 2.  Jakarta Composite Index (JCI) and Exchange Rate Source: Indonesia Stock Exchange (IDX); Pacific Exchange Rate Service.

FIGURE 3.  Dollar Exchange Rate Indicesa (June 2007 = 100)aIDR = Indonesian rupiah; MYR = Malaysian ringgit; PHP = Philippines peso; SGD = Singapore dollar; THB = Thai baht.

Source: CEIC Asia Database.

FIGURE 3.  Dollar Exchange Rate Indicesa (June 2007 = 100)aIDR = Indonesian rupiah; MYR = Malaysian ringgit; PHP = Philippines peso; SGD = Singapore dollar; THB = Thai baht. Source: CEIC Asia Database.

At first glance, this anomalous behaviour of the rupiah exchange rate seems to suggest that the central bank (Bank Indonesia, BI) has been intervening heavily in the market by purchasing dollars in order to keep the rupiah from appreciating like these other currencies–an argument that is bolstered by the observation that BI's foreign reserves jumped by about $6 billion in the second half of 2007, to $57 billion. According to market participants and BI officials, however, BI did not engage in large-scale purchases during this period; indeed, BI argues that it has been consistently committed to allowing the rupiah to float by avoiding such market intervention.

The explanation for the paradox of rapid increases in reserves in the absence of open market purchases of foreign exchange appears to be that there is a large inflow of oil export dollars to the government's deposit account at BI. These dollars are immediately converted to rupiah in the government's account, presumably at the current market exchange rate. By contrast with the case in which BI acquires dollars by purchasing them on the open market, there is no impact on the supply of base money, since base money does not include government deposits at the central bank. This means that there is no need for sterilisation–that is, no need for BI to issue SBIs to offset the monetary impact–which explains why the volume of SBIs outstanding remained virtually unchanged during this period.

One implication of these off-market purchases of foreign exchange from the government is that they send false signals to market participants. If instead the government were to sell its foreign exchange earnings on the market and deposit the rupiah proceeds in its account with BI, either this additional large supply of dollars would tend to cause the rupiah to appreciate, or BI would need to intervene to purchase this additional supply if it wanted to prevent such appreciation. In other words, the exchange rate observed in the market is artificially high as a consequence of the hidden sale of foreign exchange by the government to the central bank.

Inflation and monetary policy

At 6.6%, consumer price index (CPI) inflation for 2007 fell within BI's target range of 6±1%, although the 5.8% rate achieved mid-year was not able to be sustained (). The trend was upward during the second half, and the year-on-year rate recorded in January 2008 reached 7.4%. This modest resurgence suggests that BI may have been too eager to ease monetary policy (that is, to reduce interest rates) during 2007. Further reductions were put on hold in January, which was unsurprising given the central bank's decision to lower its inflation target range to 5±1% in 2008.

FIGURE 4.  Inflation and the Monetary Policy Interest Rate (% p.a.)

Source: CEIC Asia Database.

FIGURE 4.  Inflation and the Monetary Policy Interest Rate (% p.a.) Source: CEIC Asia Database.

When the CPI is disaggregated into its various components it can be seen that food prices have been growing much faster than the index as a whole, while administered prices under the control of the government have been growing much more slowly (). Price movements within the food component of the CPI are by no means uniform, however (). Prepared food prices have been growing at about the same rate as the CPl itself, while, at the other extreme, inflation of the fats and oils sub-component accelerated steadily and rapidly to reach almost 40% p.a. by the end of 2007. The beans and nuts sub-component also accelerated, albeit much less steeply (except in January 2008). Inflation of cereals prices, by contrast, moved in the other direction, falling from about 30% at the end of 2006 to just 9% a year later, presumably as a result of the easing of import restrictions on rice. The recent rapid increases in the price of pahn oil and soybeans are not specific to Indonesia, but appear to be related to global developments in the markets for these commodities resulting from the growing emphasis on the production of bio-fuels. The impact of policies pushing in this direction on world food prices, and the consequences for poverty world-wide, have surely been greatly under-estimated by those who have advocated the policies.

FIGURE 5.  Food Price Inflation: Selected Components (% p.a.)

Source: CEIC Asia Database.

FIGURE 5.  Food Price Inflation: Selected Components (% p.a.) Source: CEIC Asia Database.

These external developments affecting food prices, as well as the rising trend of oil prices, may make it difficult for Bl to keep inflation within its new, lower target range in 2008 without having to resort to some tightening of monetary policy. The government's announcement that it is intending to reduce the interest rate assumed in the 2008 budget is therefore rather surprising. The explanation may be a fear that any reversal of the downward trend in interest rates may slow the currently rapid and accelerating growth of bank lending for working capital, investment and consumption purposes (and, to a lesser extent, for financing small business activity) ().

FIGURE 6.  Bank Lending Growth (% p.a.)

Source: CEIC Asia Database.

FIGURE 6.  Bank Lending Growth (% p.a.) Source: CEIC Asia Database.

The potential threat to inflation described above is primarily from external price movements,Footnote8 and with this thought in mind it is pertinent to ask what purpose is served by BI's strategy of continuing to increase its already large foreign reserves, thus preventing the rupiah from appreciating. Selling off some of these reserves would tend to reduce the domestic price of tradables–including food imports–with a beneficial impact on consumers. It would also reduce the rupiah cost of foreign debt service for both the private sector and the government. It would be necessary to sterilise the contractionary monetary impact of such sales, which could be achieved, for example, by reducing the amount of SBIs outstanding; this would have the further beneficial effect of lowering interest rates generally In short, abandoning the policy of building up international reserves rather than allowing the rupiah to appreciate would help lower the pressure from imported inflation, at the same time providing scope for some reduction in domestic interest rates.Footnote9

Monetary policy operations

At the annual bankers’ meeting on 18 January 2008, the governor of BI foreshadowed refinements to the way in which the central bank conducts its inflation targeting monetary policy (Abdullah 2008). Such refinements were necessary, he argued, because under the current arrangements inter-bank money market interest rates were too volatile, and the short-term yield curve too steep. These ‘distortions’ were alleged to reduce the effectiveness of monetary policy, and simultaneously to prevent the financial markets from playing a bigger role in the economy. In the future, Bl would be attempting to stabilise inter-bank rates and generate a ‘more reasonable’ short-term yield curve by engaging in fine-tuning operations, based on sale and repurchase transactions (‘repos’) in SBIs and government bonds, and on foreign exchange swap transactions. We expect the change in operational policy to enhance the central bank's capability to send more precise policy signals to the market, hence refining the formation of market expectations.

GOVERNANCE ISSUES

Far-reaching governance problems, particularly in terms of regulatory quality and the control of corruption, constitute a long-term obstacle to Indonesia's economic progress. Here we discuss three national-level examples that have attracted attention in recent months: an important finding of anti-competitive behaviour by the Business Competition Supervisory Commission; changes to the membership of the Anti-Corruption Commission; and allegations of misuse of central bank funds, including for the purpose of bribing members of the parliament (DPR).

The Business Competition Supervisory Commission

In November 2007 the Business Competition Supervisory Commission (KPPU) brought down a much anticipated and highly controversial decision in relation to competition in the mobile (cell) phone market (KPPU Citation2007). This sector's extremely rapid growth in the last few years reflects the strong and rising demand for mobile phone services and the correspondingly high level of current and prospective profits. There were two main aspects to the commission's investigation of alleged violations of Law 5/1999 (on Prohibition of Monopolistic Practices and Unhealthy Competition), the first relating to prohibited activities, and the second to share ownership of companies operating in this market. The commission found that the dominant company in the market, PT Telkomsel, had abused its position of dominance by engaging in the ‘monopolistic practice’ of setting its tariffs too high, and that Temasek Holdings, the investment arm of the Singapore government, had violated the law by controlling a market share in excess of 50%. PT Telkomsel was fined Rp 25 billion (somewhat less than $3 million), and was required to reduce its current tariffs by at least 15%. Temasek was required to divest its entire shareholding in either Telkomsel or PT Indosat, the second-biggest company in the market, within two years from the time the decision was upheld by the courts (assuming the decision was indeed upheld). Furchases of the shares thus divested were required to be limited to parcels of no more than 5% of the total shares divested, and the buyers of such parcels were not to have any association with Temasek or with each other. Temasek and eight related companies were each fined Rp 25 billion–an aggregate amount of about $25 million.

The decision forcing Telkomsel to reduce its tariffs may be of little economic consequence, since tariffs have been declining in any case, and the company can probably re-package its products to some extent in order to reduce the impact on its profits. But the decision reflects little understanding of the important role of prices and profits in the economy. It is precisely the existence of super-normal (as distinct from ‘excessive’) profits that rapidly draws resources into the production of goods and services for which there is an unsatisfied demand. The currently high profitability of the mobile phone industry is the consequence of its providing a service that is very attractive to the Indonesian public.Footnote10 One impact of a forced reduction in Telkomsel's tariffs will be to reduce the amount of profit avail-able for reinvestment. A second impact, ironically, will be to weaken the abflity of small firms to compete by offering their services to customers at a substantial discount. In both cases the effect will be to slow the expansion of industry output, for which there is still a large unmet demand. There are at least five competitors for Telkomsel in the market, but the commission appears to have ignored the fact that there is no obstacle to these competitors offering more attractive tariffs. The strongest protection against high prices is precisely the abflity of other firms to undercut them, notwithstanding the good intentions behind Law 5/1999. Telkomsel is certainly much larger than these other firms, but it still accounts for only about 56% of total mobile phone subscribers. Evidence to support the assertion that it has a ‘dominant’ position appears weak.

By contrast, the decision in relation to Temasek appears, quite simply, to be inconsistent with the law. Article 27a of the law, which Temasek was found to have breached, reads as follows (translation by the authors):

Business entities are prohibited from owning a majority shareholding [emphasis added] in multiple enterprises that are of the same kind, and that carry out business activities in the same market … if such ownership results in:

a. a business entity or a group of business entities controlling a market share of more than 50% for a specific good or service.

Temasek has indirect shareholdings (through eight related subsidiary companies) in Indosat and Telkomsel, two enterprises of the same kind that operate in the same market, and that jointly account for about 90% of that market. However, Temasek and its subsidiaries do not have a majority shareholding: as the commission itself points out, Temasek is the indirect owner of about 41 % of Indosat and 35% of Telkomsel. The commission appears to have confused a greater than 50% market share with a greater than 50% shareholding.Footnote11

Even if Temasek were in breach of article 27a, the penalties determined by the commission appear to be beyond the scope of those provided for in the law, which are set out in articles 47 and 48. Neither article suggests that shareholders can be forced by the commission to divest themselves of shares. Moreover, in requiring that individual purchasers of the divested shares not acquire more than 5% of divested shares in the company concerned, the commission is (perhaps unwittingly) imposing its own view as to the desirable ownership structure of that company: specifically, that there should be at least 20 new shareholders in place of the relevant Temasek subsidiaries. This view has no basis whatsoever in the law, which is concerned only with shareholdings of over 50% (and then only if such majority shareholdings lead to the owner controlling a market share of more than 50%).

Nor does this view support the interests of consumers. If the Temasek stake in Telkomsel were to be divested, for example, the firm would then be 65 % owned by the state-owned PT Telkom (currently the only other shareholder), with at least 20 other shareholders owning no more than 1.75% each. Telkom would become the controlling shareholder, and presumably Telkomsel's performance would soon become similar to the dismal performance of its parent–which, over a period of many decades, has managed to extend its fixed telephone fine network to only about 9 million subscribers in a country with a population of over 220 million.Footnote12 One of the main explanations for the explosive growth of the mobile phone companies is precisely the failure of Telkom to satisfy the needs of consumers.

These observations lend support to the remarks of one critical Jakarta observer, who refers to ‘the many questionable or even absurd rulings of the [commission]’, asserting that ‘many of the KPPU's previous decisions in high-profile cases … have been overturned by appellate courts’ (Lingga Citation2007). Temasek is indeed appealing the decision through the courts. Despite the fact that it would appear to have very strong grounds for appeal, past experience (with the Manulife and Newmont Mining cases, for example: (JP, 20/1/2002; Reuters News Citation2007) suggests that the outcome is by no means clear. One problem is that no court is specifically assigned to handle anti-competition cases, suggesting a likely serious lack of the expertise needed to deal with such a complex case as this. Another problem is the well-known existence of systemic corruption in the courts and the legal bureaucracy.

The KPPU's decision in the Temasek case has been heavily criticised by those who see it as damaging the investment climate – specifically in relation to foreign investors–but has been strongly supported by those who portray it as a victory in the battle against foreign ownership of strategic assets. Indeed, the case was originally initiated by the Federation of State-Owned Enterprise Employees Unions in the form of a complaint against Temasek, alleging that it over-charged its mobile phone customers and that it held a monopoly in the mobile phone business in Indonesia (Straits Times, 14/2/2008).Footnote13 The anti-foreign investor thrust is obvious from the fact that the complaint was levelled not against the provider itself but against its (indirect) foreign shareholder. The chairman of the KPPU, M. Iqbal, was reported to have received an award from a group of nationahst politicians, headed by former People's Consultative Assembly chair and presidential candidate Amien Rais, which had also advocated that the government buy back the shares of Indosat (Osman Citation2007). On the other hand, a group representing some 100 Indonesian lawyers asserted that the commission's case was seriously flawed, and would ultimately damage the interests of the Indonesian people (JP, 3/12/2007).

Vice President Jusuf Kalla, who earlier argued that the government should buy back the stake it had previously held in Indosat from Temasek's subsidiary, Singapore Technologies Telemedia (JP, 22/11/2007), has sought to deflect criticism of the commission's decision by asserting that foreign investors had to comply with Indonesian law; the president has reiterated this view. This, of course, is quite beside the point. What matters is whether the commission has properly interpreted the law–or whether, on the other hand, it has allowed itself to become the instrument of business entities (hiding under the cloak of economic nationalism) that perceive an opportunity to gain a foothold or increase their presence in the industry by virtue of Temasek's being forced out of one of the two biggest firms. It is a matter for concern that the national leadership has shown so little interest in the possibility that the commission's decision is indeed harmful, not only to consumers but also to the investment climate, and that it has tarnished the commission's own reputation–and, by association, the credibility of government regulatory bodies in general.

Much that has happened in Indonesia in the post-Soeharto era has been driven by the view that the development of new institutions was one of the keys to successful democratisation. The KPPU is one such new institution. The present case exemplifies the fact that most, if not all, public sector institutions, while intended to further the interests of the general public, may in fact do precisely the opposite, either because they lack the necessary skills and expertise or because they can be captured by vested interests.

Membership changes at the Anti-Corruption Commission

In December 2007, anti-corruption reformers and governance analysts were dismayed at the process by which five members were appointed to the Corruption Eradication Commission (KPK) for the 2007–11 period. Surprisingly for an agency whose primary function is to enhance the level of trust in all of the public sector institutions, the selection by the DPR's legal and domestic political affairs commission involved two closed-door voting sessions at the conclusion of a three-day ‘fit-and-proper’ test of the candidates for these positions. During the first round, five of the 10 candidates proposed by the president (on the advice of a government-backed selection team) were chosen for appointment to the KPK. In the second round, the new chairman was chosen from this group: Antasari Azhar, the incumbent director for prosecution in the office of the Junior Attorney General for General Crime. After the DPR had confirmed these choices, they were forwarded to the president for ratification.Footnote14

The law on the KPK (Law 30/2002) requires that the names of candidates submitted to the DPR be announced to the public in order to obtain feedback as to their suitability (article 30(6)). But shortly before the decision was to be made, the deputy chairman of the DPR commission is reported as saying that it had ‘decided to ignore the [many letters from various mass organisations and state institutions] in giving scores to the candidates’ (JP, 29/11/2007). Moreover, after the decision was announced, the DPR commission chairman revealed that most of its members had declined to score candidates openly (JP, 5/12/2007). In view of such attitudes it is hardly surprising that the eventual selections –and, in particular, the choice of Antasari as chairman–met with widespread criticism and expressions of concern that the KPK was unlikely to have any significant impact on corruption in the near future.

Indonesia Corruption Watch (ICW) coordinator Teten Masduki accused the DPR commission of bias in favour of political parties when selecting the successful candidates, calling for disclosure of the scores given to each, and arguing that ‘qualified and dedicated professionals [would] no longer [be] interested in joining the commission in the future’ (JP, 5/12/2007). Denny Indrayana, an expert in public administration from Gadjah Mada University, argued that the appointments signalled the start of the de-legitimisation of KPK, which would make the public lose hope for successful anti-corruption reforms (JP, 6/12/2007).Footnote15 Adnan Buyung Nasution, a member of the president's advisory council, deplored the outcome of the selection process, arguing that it was ‘not impossible that this was backed by, or involved a deal with, corruptors’; while the head of Transparency International Indonesia's management board, Todung Mulya Lubis, echoed this disappointment and voiced his suspicion that the selection process was full of political compromises (Tempo Interactive, 7/12/2007). For their part, some members of the DPR also admitted they were aware of widespread discontent about Antasari's appomtment (JP, 6/12/2007; Antara News, 4/12/2007).

It is too soon to be sure of the impact of these appointments on the president's anti-corruption drive, but this episode clearly illustrates the difficulty of trying to eradicate systemic corruption, as distinct from dealing with isolated cases. The attempt to create a new, non-corrupt institution to clean up all the corrupt surrounding public sector institutions is bound to be met with attempts by the latter to capture and subvert the new body. In turn, this raises the fundamental question of whether anti-corruption efforts should focus primarily on trying to prove and punish past transgressions, or whether they should be more concerned with modifying the behaviour of individuals within the public sector in the future – perhaps by putting much greater emphasis on proper evaluation of their performance as the main basis for promotion.

The Anti-Corruption Commission, Bank Indonesia and the parliament

Indonesia's democratic reform has involved scaling back the power of the executive branch, freeing up the political parties and boosting the legislature (MacIntyre Citation2003:138). Strengthening the role of the DPR would, it was hoped, result in sustained scrutiny of the executive and the bureaucracy. However, the outcome so far has been somewhat disappointing. KPK is currently investigating allegations of corruption involving the misuse of BI funds, encompassing sizable transfers to members of the DPR; this provides an opportunity to probe the DPR's contribution to good governance, while also serving as an important test case for the KPK's new membership.

This case first came to light in August 2007, when ICW filed a report with KPK alleging illegal transfers amounting to Rp 4.5 billion ($0.5 million) to the DPR's commission on finance, banking and state enterprises (Commission IX) in connection with several bills being deliberated in the DPR. In November, however, it was revealed that the Supreme Audit Agency (BPK) had written to KPK in November 2006, claiming that its audit of BI's annual report for 2004 had found evidence of illegal disbursements from BI on a far greater scale – around Rp 100 billion ($11 million) (JP, 23/11/2007). The decision to make these funds available (through BI's training institute, the Indonesian Banking Development Foundation) had been taken at a meeting of BI's governors in June 2003.Footnote16 About two-thirds of the total was used in connection with the legal defence of former high officials of BI involved in financial scandals, and the remainder was channelled to Commission IX.

At the time, the DPR was deliberating a bill to modify the law on Bank Indonesia. One of the modifications concerned the estabhshment of a finance sector supervisory agency that would take over from the central bank the responsibility for the supervision of banks–a potentially lucrative activity for those who exercise this responsibihty. McLeod (Citation1999:149) drew attention to the fact that BI had ‘had great success in opposing the threatened loss of [this] significant part of its operations’. The 1999 law on Bank Indonesia had put this change off until the end of 2002; the 2004 revision of that law postponed it further, until the end of 2010.

In January 2008, three top central bank officials were declared ‘suspects’ in the case: the governor, CitationBurhanuddin Abdullah, the legal affairs director, Oey Hoey Tiong, and the former head of the communications bureau. Rush Simanjuntak. This immediately raised questions about fairness, since only Burhanuddin–and none of the other members of the board of governors present at the meeting that had approved disbursement of the funds–was declared a suspect. In turn, this aroused suspicions about the politics behind the case, because Burhanuddin's term in office was soon to expire, and he was considered likely to seek re-appointment.Footnote17 By mid-February, Oey and Rush had been placed in detention after several hours of interrogation at KPK; Burhanuddin was also questioned the following week, but not detained (JP, 22/2/2008). Nine DPR members and seven former members are also implicated in the case, but at the time of writing only two had been questioned by KPK.

The case has drawn attention to the fact that it is common practice for government departments and agencies to make payments to DPR members to secure the passage of new legislation. Former BI deputy governor Aulia Pohan acknowledged that Bl funds had indeed gone to members of Commission IX (JP, 31/1/2008). The practice was also acknowledged by the deputy chairman of the DPR Ethics Council, who referred to the practice as ‘official lobbying’ (JP, 19/11/2007); as if to excuse the practice, DPR Speaker Agung Laksono noted that at the time the transfers were alleged to have occurred ‘the House's budget was very small while the government had a huge budget’ (JP, 4/8/2007). Seen in this light, the strengthened power of the legislature relative to the executive has yet to generate the good governance dividend originally hoped for.

Notes

1In this journal, ‘$’ refers to the US dollar The exchange rate at the end of January 2008 was Rp 9,291/$.

2GDP data can be significantly adjusted over time: the growth rate for investment in machinery and equipment was also revised upward by 2.8 percentage points in the September quarter.

3These data are world crude oil spot prices from World Bank, ‘Prospects for Development’ (Commodity Price Data), <http://web.worldbank.org/>.

4Changes in taxes and dividends paid by Pertamina as a result of higher oil prices are presumably already taken into account in the ministry's analysis of the budgetary impact of the oil price.

5Having said that, this strategy has been somewhat counter-acted by the ‘under-spending’ problem discussed below.

6The lack of investment in fixed-line capacity by PT Telkom, the state-owned telecommunications company, is being offset by tremendous growth in mobile telecommunications, where there is a strong private sector presence.

7The Jakarta and Surabaya stock exchanges merged to become the Indonesia Stock Exchange (IDX), effective from 30 November 2007.

8Not all fuel prices are still subsidised, so rising oil prices will have an indirect impact on inflation through increases in the production and transport costs of domestic industries.

9Yet as recently as December, the central bank suggested that its reserves could rise to $72.9 billion in 2008 (Dow Jones International News, 7/12/2007).

10PT Excelcomindo Pratama, the third-largest provider of mobile phone services, announced a 62% increase in the number of its subscribers in 2007, to 15.5 million (JP, 22/2/2008).

11This misinterpretation of the law can also be found in numerous newspaper reports about the Temasek case.

12The number of mobile phone subscribers, by comparison, has grown from zero to well over 60 million in the last decade.

13Interestingly, the union withdrew its complaint almost six months later, and yet the KPPU decided to proceed with its investigation.

14The other successful candidates were Chandra Hamzah, a lawyer; Bibit Samad, a retired police general; Haryono, an official of the Finance and Development Supervisory Agency (BPKP, Badan Pengawas Keuangan dan Pembangunan); and M. Jasin, the outgoing director for research and development at the KPK.

15The Anti-Corruption Study Centre at Gadjah Mada University flew its flag at half-mast as a sign of its concern.

16BPK Chairman Anwar Nasution was a member of BI's board of governors at this time, but has stated that he did not attend this meeting. Nasution is a member of the international advisory board of this journal.

17On 15 February, the president forwarded two nominations to the DPR for the post of BI governor (JP, 16/02/2008): Agus Martowardojo, president director of Bank Mandiri, and Raden Pardede, deputy president director of the state-owned Assets Management Company (PPA)–both outsiders to the central bank. Burhanuddin Abdullah had indicated a few days earlier that he was not seeking re-appointment.

References

  • Abdullah, Burhanuddin 2008 Speech of the Governor of Bank Indonesia at the Annual Bankers Dinner , 18 January, available at < www.bi.go.id/web/id/ >.
  • Abimanyu , Anggito and Megantara , Andie 2007 ‘Mengamankan APBN 2008 [Safeguarding the 2008 Budget]’ , 28 November, available at < http://www.fiskal.depkeu.go.id/webbkf/kolom/detailkolomasp?NewsID=N799537213 >.
  • IMF (International Monetary Fund) 2008 ‘World Economic Outlook Update’ , 29 January, available at < http://www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/weo/2008/update/01/index.htm >.
  • KPPU (Business Competition Supervisory Commission) 2007 ‘Putusan, Perkara Nomor: 07/KPPU-L/2007’, Komisi Pengawas Persaingan Usaha [‘Decision in Case No. 07/ KPPU-L/2007’, Business Competition Supervisory Commission] , 19 November .
  • Lindblad , J. Thomas and Thee Kian Wie 2007 ‘Survey of recent developments’ . Bulletin of Indonesian Economic Studies 43 (1) : 7 – 33 .
  • Lingga , Vincent 2007 ‘Anti-monopoly body shoots Temasek, hits government’ , Jakarta Post , 21 November .
  • MacIntyre , Andrew 2003 The Power of Institutions: Political Architecture and Governance , Cornell Studies in Political Economy, Cornell University Press , Ithaca, NY and London .
  • McLeod , Ross H. 1999 ‘Crisis-driven changes to the banking laws and regulations’ . Bulletin of Indonesian Economic Studies 35 (2) : 147 – 54 .
  • McLeod , Ross H. 2005 ‘Survey of recent developments’ . Bulletin of Indonesian Economic Studies 41 (2) : 133 – 57 .
  • Manning , Chris , and Roesad , Kurnya 2006 ‘Survey of recent developments’ . Bulletin of Indonesian Economic Studies 42 (2) : 143 – 70 .
  • Ministry of Finance 2007 Data Pokok APBN-P 2007 dan APBN 2008 [Basic Data from the Revised 2007 Budget and the 2008 Budget], Jakarta .
  • Narjoko , Dionisius A. and Jotzo , Frank 2007 ‘Survey of recent developments’ . Bulletin of Indonesian Economic Studies 43 (2) : 143 – 69 .
  • Nurhayati , Desy and Suharmoko , Aditya 2008 ‘Govt revises economic growth, budget assumptions’ , Jakarta Post , 16 February .
  • Osman , Salim 2007 ‘Flawed: Indonesian civil society group seeks to overturn Temasek ruling’ . Straits Times , 18 December .
  • Pangestu , Mari E. 2008 ‘Prospects of the Indonesian economy in the years to come’ . Presentation to the Indonesian Council on World Affairs at the Financial Club, Jakarta, 9 January .
  • Ramayandi , Arief 2003 ‘Economic growth and government size in Indonesia: some lessons for the local authorities’ . Working Papers in Economics and Development Studies (WoPEDS) 200302, Department of Economics, Padjadjaran University, Bandung .
  • Reuters News 2007 ‘Indonesia Newmont boss says no complaints on mining’ , 23 January, available at < http: //www.renters.com/article/latestCrisis/idUSJAK317202 >.
  • Thee Kian Wie 2001 ‘Reflections on the New Order “miracle”’ , in Indonesia Today: Challenges of History Grayson J. Lloyd and Shannon L. Smith , Institute of Southeast Asian Studies , Singapore .
  • Trimegah Research 2008 Indonesia Strategy: The Journey Continues (Year book) , Trimegah Securities, Jakarta, January .
  • USAID (United States Agency for International Development) 2006 ‘Indonesia finds new resource for clean, safe drinking water’ , available at < http://www.america.gov/St/washfile-english/2006/September/20060921144649 AKllennoCcMO.8310205.html >.
  • Wongso , Yenwy 2008 ‘Land capping “not the solution”’ , Jakarta Post , 9 January .
  • World Bank 2004 Indonesia: Averting an Infrastructure Crisis: A Framework for Policy and Action , World Bank , Jakarta and Washington, DC .
  • World Bank 2008 ‘Transport in Indonesia’ , available at < http://web.worldbank.org/ >. World Bank , Washington, DC .

Reprints and Corporate Permissions

Please note: Selecting permissions does not provide access to the full text of the article, please see our help page How do I view content?

To request a reprint or corporate permissions for this article, please click on the relevant link below:

Academic Permissions

Please note: Selecting permissions does not provide access to the full text of the article, please see our help page How do I view content?

Obtain permissions instantly via Rightslink by clicking on the button below:

If you are unable to obtain permissions via Rightslink, please complete and submit this Permissions form. For more information, please visit our Permissions help page.