416
Views
11
CrossRef citations to date
0
Altmetric
Articles

Commitment, Learning, and Alliance Performance: A Formal Analysis Using an Agent-Based Network Formation Model

&
Pages 1-23 | Published online: 21 Dec 2012
 

Abstract

Current theoretical arguments highlight a dilemma faced by actors who either adopt a weak or strong commitment strategy for managing their alliances and partnerships. Actors who pursue a weak commitment strategy—that is, immediately abandon current partners when a more profitable alternative is presented—are more likely to identify the most rewarding alliances. On the other hand, actors who enact a strong commitment approach are more likely to take advantage of whatever opportunities can be found in existing partnerships. Using agent-based modeling, we show that actors who adopt a moderate commitment strategy overcome this dilemma and outperform actors who adopt either weak or strong commitment approaches. We also show that avoiding this dilemma rests on experiencing a related tradeoff: moderately-committed actors sacrifice short-term performance for the superior knowledge and information that allows them to eventually do better.

[Supplementary material is available for this article. Go to the publisher's online edition of The Journal of Mathematical Sociology for the following free supplemental resource: Technical Appendix.]

Acknowledgments

The author order is alphabetical.

We thank Marcel van Assen, Vincent Buskens, Roberto Fernandez, Werner Raub, Ezra Zuckerman, and two anonymous referees, for many useful comments and suggestions.

Notes

1Here we are not employing the term “mixed strategy” in a game-theoretic sense.

2Our moderate commitment strategy is different than a mixed strategy in the standard game-theoretic sense. In game theory, a mixed strategy (in equilibrium) implies that agents are indifferent between the pure strategies they are mixing over. In our setting, a moderately committed actor is not indifferent between weak or strong commitment, but rather the actor is playing a distinct strategy which is superior in the long run.

3All technical details (including proofs) that are not necessary to understand the main intuitions are contained in the Technical Appendix, available online.

4By competence we mean proficiency in some technical field, for example, a profession for individuals or an industry (or geographical market) for firms.

5We could let our agents have more than one competence and/or vary in terms of their competence levels. Doing so, however, would complicate our analysis but would not change our substantive conclusions.

6We could have specified a more general functional form, but this one is simple, captures the essential features we want to model regarding link formation, and is also concave in each of its arguments. The latter property is convenient once we solve each agent's maximization problem (see footnote 9).

7We note that our notion of commitment is unilateral, in the sense defined in Buskens and Royakkers (Citation2002).

8This corresponds to “best-response dynamics,” which is one way to converge to a stable Nash equilibrium.

9Second-order conditions always obtain, given the concavity implied by Eq. (Equation2).

10An additional interpretation is that the future is very risky and, thus, agents discount expected values at high rates.

11For an overview of this type of process see Hamilton (2008).

Note. The order of presentation in the table is the same as the order in which parameters and variables apper in the article.

12For our two-state Markov chain, the average number of periods until transition is given by 1/(1 − φ), so in our case hidden means are unchanged for an average of 20 periods (we simulate the model for 50,000 periods, which allows for many transitions).

Note. Shows summary statistics for societies composed of three commitment types: weak commitment (WC), moderate commitment (MC), and strong commitment (SC) actors.

Coordination failure stands for the proportion of rounds where no link materialized; average performance per alliance excludes rounds where no link materialized; knowledge/information is measured by how close an actor's beliefs are to true hidden mean payoffs. The network was simulated for 50,000 periods.

13In the model, this means a change associated with actor i's competence value, measured by the average , across m(j).

Note. Shows regression coefficients and robust standard errors (in parenthesis). The dependent variables are average overall performance, average performance per alliance, level of coordination failure, and amount of knowledge and information. The independent variables are weak commitment (WC), strong commitment (SC), time since demand change (TIME), and a constant (CONST). The interactions are WC × TIME and SC × TIME.

Average performance per alliance is conditional on at least one link having materialized; coordination failure is the proportion of rounds where an actor did not materialize at least one link; knowledge and information measures how close an actor's beliefs are to true hidden combination payoffs; TIME counts the number of rounds since the last change in hidden combination payoffs. Results obtained by simulating network evolution for 50,000 rounds (same data as in Table 2) and averaging across TIME (note that this is a fully exogenous variable in our model).

14Also, note that whether an agent revises or not is an exogenous random variable.

Note. Shows average overall performance, coordination failure, and knowledge and information for a mixed society with three commitment levels: weak commitment (WC), moderate commitment (MC), and strong commitment (SC).

Coordination failure stands for the proportion of rounds where no link materialized; knowledge and information is measured by how close an actor's beliefs are to true hidden mean payoffs. The network was simulated for 50,000 periods. All magnitudes besides α are set at the benchmark level.

15We construct a measure of in-group focus, which for weak commitment actors is the average fraction of time devoted to other weak commitment actors. This measure correlates very negatively with the performance of weak commitment actors (estimate of −0.76).

Note. Shows average overall performance, coordination failure, and knowledge and information in a society composed of weak commitment (WC) actors.

Coordination failure stands for the proportion of rounds where no link materialized; knowledge and information is measured by how close an actor's beliefs are to true hidden mean payoffs. The network was simulated for 50,000 periods. All magnitudes besides α are set at the benchmark level.

16In many instances, Nash equilibria are not stable; that is, they only correspond to fixed points of the system if the system starts at the equilibrium. This lack of stability is present in our dynamic model, as propositions 2 and 3 illustrate.

17So, on average, ego would be motivated to keep his current partners.

18The results from Sections 3.2.2 and 3.2.3 suggest that starting conditions are important. However, we hasten to add that starting conditions matter little in our simulations. Since our societies contain actors who can learn and we provide these actors with the opportunity to do so, starting conditions only matter during the initial rounds of the simulation.

Log in via your institution

Log in to Taylor & Francis Online

PDF download + Online access

  • 48 hours access to article PDF & online version
  • Article PDF can be downloaded
  • Article PDF can be printed
USD 53.00 Add to cart

Issue Purchase

  • 30 days online access to complete issue
  • Article PDFs can be downloaded
  • Article PDFs can be printed
USD 1,078.00 Add to cart

* Local tax will be added as applicable

Related Research

People also read lists articles that other readers of this article have read.

Recommended articles lists articles that we recommend and is powered by our AI driven recommendation engine.

Cited by lists all citing articles based on Crossref citations.
Articles with the Crossref icon will open in a new tab.