427
Views
7
CrossRef citations to date
0
Altmetric
Original Articles

Sovereignty, the exchange rate, collective deceit, and the euro crisis

Pages 355-375 | Published online: 23 Dec 2015
 

Abstract

This paper presents an interpretation of the European crisis based on balance-of-payments imbalances within the Eurozone, highlighting the role of the “internal” real exchange rates as a primary cause of the crisis. It explores the structural contradictions that turn the euro into a “foreign currency” for each individual Eurozone country. These contradictions imply the inability of national central banks to monetize the public and private debts, which makes the euro crisis a sovereign crisis similar to those typical of emerging countries, but whose solution presents additional obstacles.

Notes

1According to data of the Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development (OECD) Southern countries’ 2009–13 yearly growth rates were all negative: Portugal (−1.4 percent), Spain (−1.4 percent), Greece (−5.2 percent), Italy (−1.5 percent), and Ireland (−1.1 percent).

2Williamson (1983) develops the concept of fundamental equilibrium exchange rate and defines it as the exchange rate level that enables the economy to simultaneously achieve domestic and foreign equilibria, where domestic equilibrium is given by the use of production resources without generating inflationary pressures, and foreign equilibrium is that which enables a sustainable current account. In spite of the controversy surrounding this concept as an indicator of the appropriate exchange rate level, the evolution of rates as calculated by Jeong et al. (Citation2010) is regarded as a relevant indicator of intra-European exchange rate disequilibria.

3Keynes (1924) shows how adjustments to the bank rate establish foreign equilibrium under the gold standard regime.

4The euro is more similar to the disastrous gold standard model that was in force between the two world wars, when surplus-posting countries sterilized gold inflows from current transaction surpluses, preventing inflationary adjustment and making it difficult for countries showing deficits to adjust.

5According to Hein (Citation2012), France, Italy, and Portugal do not fit either model. Although they do not match the debt-led consumption boom, growth in those countries was driven by domestic demand, accompanied by either a relative increase (Portugal) or a relative decrease in wages (France, Italy) and, in any case, with sizable public deficits.

6Miranda (2012, p. 36), for instance, asserts that: “The euro is a unique currency among its international peers. It is a single currency issued and managed by a statutorily federative central bank whose equity capital belongs to a politically nonexistent federation and whose deliberative power is entirely independent from its adopting sovereign states. It is thus a currency that countries share, but that does not, as a monetary policy instrument, have a unified sovereign debt bond to show for itself because budget administration is decentralized, that is, because fiscal federalism does not exist.”

7The American case of quantitative easing is illustrative: in spite of the financial crisis and the U.S. fiscal and foreign deficits, economic actors never questioned the Federal Reserve’s ability to ensure the solvency of public bonds.

8The other side of the German path is the “internal appreciation” of surplus-posting countries, that is, inflationary price and wage adjustments.

9In this and other works, Keynes stands as a critic of the gold standard’s deflationary adjustments. According to him, wages can only be reduced with unemployment and recession, partly because only an unemployed worker would accept returning to work for a smaller wage.

10Establishment of such a fiscal authority would imply establishing a centralized budget and a market for unified sovereign debt bonds.

11For instance, in a recent survey of Ipsos for Accenture, when asked how they self-identify, 49 percent of the French responded French, and only 14 percent responded European (Le Monde, December 2, 2014).

12Quite simply, if €-Fr =x€ and 1€ =y$, then 1 Fr-€ =x.y$.

Additional information

Notes on contributors

Luiz Carlos Bresser-Pereira

Luiz Carlos Bresser-Pereira is Emeritus professor, São Paulo School of Economics, Getulio Vargas Foundation, Sao Paulo.

Pedro Rossi

Pedro Rossi is professor in the Economics Institute at Campinas State University.

Log in via your institution

Log in to Taylor & Francis Online

PDF download + Online access

  • 48 hours access to article PDF & online version
  • Article PDF can be downloaded
  • Article PDF can be printed
USD 53.00 Add to cart

Issue Purchase

  • 30 days online access to complete issue
  • Article PDFs can be downloaded
  • Article PDFs can be printed
USD 231.00 Add to cart

* Local tax will be added as applicable

Related Research

People also read lists articles that other readers of this article have read.

Recommended articles lists articles that we recommend and is powered by our AI driven recommendation engine.

Cited by lists all citing articles based on Crossref citations.
Articles with the Crossref icon will open in a new tab.