642
Views
5
CrossRef citations to date
0
Altmetric
Rejoinder

Why economics needs to be distinguished from physics, and why economists need to talk to physicists: a response to Foster and Holleman

Pages 187-192 | Published online: 03 Dec 2014
 

Abstract

Foster and Holleman argue that the systems ecologist H.T. Odum offered a valid theoretical framework for conceptualizing ecologically unequal exchange, and demonstrate its affinity with the Marxian theory of unequal exchange of embodied labour. However, both approaches suffer from the same fundamental confusion of the biophysical and the economic. The affinity between labour and energy theories of the unequal exchange of value was demonstrated by S.C. Lonergan already in 1988, but to thus define asymmetric transfers of biophysical resources in terms of underpaid ‘use values’ is misleading. Foster's recent endorsement of Odum is inconsistent with his earlier rejection of Odum's intellectual ancestor S. Podolinsky. While the ambition to ecologize Marx is laudable, it is in the interests of correct historiography and contemporary environmental justice activism to untangle some of the analytical problems in Foster and Holleman's article. A major problem is their failure to acknowledge the implications of N. Georgescu-Roegen's conceptualization of the relation between economics and thermodynamics.

Notes

1Emmanuel (Citation1972) applied the Marxian notion of labour value to international trade, arguing that the values embodied in exports from low-wage countries are underpaid in relation to those from high-wage countries, a pattern which generates asymmetric transfers of surplus value on the world market. Foster and Holleman (Citation2014, 29) similarly define ecologically unequal exchange as ‘the disproportionate and undercompensated transfer of matter and energy from the periphery to the core’ (emphasis added).

2Foster and Holleman's complete silence on material flow analysis and so-called Physical Trade Balances (e.g., Pérez Rincón Citation2006) is a major omission.

3The same question, of course, pertains to ’economic’ unequal exchange, i.e., asymmetric transfers of embodied labour: should these unequal transfers of ‘labour value’ be measured in dollars or expended energy? The fact that Emmanuel (Citation1972) and Amin (Citation1976) calculate such flows in dollars (cf. Lonergan Citation1988, 135) is difficult to reconcile with Foster and Burkett's assertions that, in Marx's view, surplus labour is a transfer of energy to the capitalist (Burkett and Foster Citation2006, 120, 126; Foster and Burkett Citation2008, 26).

4This consideration appeared particularly relevant at the time of writing this response, a few days before hosting an international workshop on Ecologically Unequal Exchange and Ecological Debt (at Lund University, 27–28 March 2014) with the explicit aim of exploring means of collaboration between environmental justice activists and academics.

5Costanza's name is misspelled 26 times in the article.

6For example, Odum (Citation1996, 230–6) has deliberated on the extent to which higher-wage professions requiring substantial education (and even the development of human culture!) represent more ‘emergy’ per individual. Such suggestions clearly aim to explain wage differences in terms of an energy theory of value. This is difficult to reconcile with Marxian class analysis.

7Foster and Holleman misleadingly phrase this observation as the conclusion that ‘the more money attached to a product the less available energy was associated with it’, which misses the main point. For the full argument, they could have consulted my 1992 article on the ‘thermodynamics of imperialism’ (Hornborg Citation1992).

8Quite contrary to my own conclusions (Hornborg Citation2014), Foster and Holleman (Citation2014, 25–6, n. 26) suggest that Odum represents a more radical approach to ecological economics than, e.g., Herman Daly. Daly's (Citation1996) critique of neoclassical economics is aligned with that of his mentor Nicholas Georgescu-Roegen (Citation1971), whose reconceptualization of economics must be considered cataclysmic. However, Foster and Holleman demonstrate no understanding of the radical implications of Georgescu-Roegen's and Daly's perspectives.

9If ‘Howard Odum studied Marx's political economy very closely’, it seems remarkable that he was not aware of Marx's theory of metabolic rift (Foster and Holleman Citation2014, 13, n. 13). This should have suggested to Foster and Holleman that the significance of the latter theory for Marx's understanding of capitalism has been overstated.

Additional information

Alf Hornborg is an anthropologist and Professor of Human Ecology at Lund University, Sweden. He is the author of The power of the machine (2001) and Global ecology and unequal exchange (2011) and lead editor of The world system and the Earth system (2006), Rethinking environmental history (2007), International trade and environmental justice (2010) and Ecology and power (2012)

Log in via your institution

Log in to Taylor & Francis Online

PDF download + Online access

  • 48 hours access to article PDF & online version
  • Article PDF can be downloaded
  • Article PDF can be printed
USD 53.00 Add to cart

Issue Purchase

  • 30 days online access to complete issue
  • Article PDFs can be downloaded
  • Article PDFs can be printed
USD 265.00 Add to cart

* Local tax will be added as applicable

Related Research

People also read lists articles that other readers of this article have read.

Recommended articles lists articles that we recommend and is powered by our AI driven recommendation engine.

Cited by lists all citing articles based on Crossref citations.
Articles with the Crossref icon will open in a new tab.