2,896
Views
8
CrossRef citations to date
0
Altmetric
Articles

We demand work! ‘Dispossession’, patronage and village labour in Bibiyana, Bangladesh

ABSTRACT

This paper critically appraises the usefulness of idioms and theories of ‘dispossession’ to describe changes taking place in rural Bangladesh, where rapid industrialization and ‘development’ have led to profound shifts in the agrarian economy. On the basis of long-term fieldwork in north-eastern Bangladesh, where the multinational company Chevron operate a large gas field, I argue that rather than political and economic struggles in the area involving access to land, it is access to work which is now all important for livelihoods and, as such, has become the basis for local patronage and political power. Theories of ‘accumulation by dispossession’, still widely cited in the anthropology of neo-liberal development in South Asia, are thus of limited help in explaining the changes and continuities which animate local political and economic struggles.

It is January 2014, two weeks after a general election characterised by violence, blockades and civil disorder on an unprecedented scale. I am picking beans with two friends in a village about 200 miles north of Dhaka. At first sight the picture is one of bucolic calm. A kingfisher flits across the water; above us, an eagle soars. On the land next to the pond men are planting paddy; ankle deep in mud, they work in lines, leaving patches of vibrant green in their wake. Glancing across the fields I notice a large group moving along the distant road. They are walking with intent and seem to be holding something above their heads: at least a hundred or so figures, their white prayer caps catching the winter sun. My friends peer across the fields. ‘Procession’, they say, using the English word. ‘They’re going to the gas field for work’.

Shift the gaze and another reality is revealed: the hulking outline of a vast gas plant operated by the multinational energy corporation Chevron, the towering flare smudged into the horizon; a high road, cutting across the land to the north until it meets the arterial highway that a generation earlier was a rural track. Both shudder with heavy industrial traffic. On the other side of the fishery a huge pipeline is being constructed, connecting the South ‘Pad’ to a new site a few miles east. The thump of drills is audible a mile away. For a moment we can hear the chants of the men as they move along the road; then they are gone. They have marched from the nearby market town of Enatganj bearing banners and caps marked with the words Chakri Pai! (‘We demand work!’). When they reach the junction they find it blocked with police vehicles.

This is not the first procession to the gas field; there have been many such marches. Some have resulted in meetings with the corporation but most have been met by police. In recent weeks local villages have set up samity (committees) to negotiate for work. Other encounters have been more chaotic and violent. During my stay a Chevron contractor is struck in the face. A few weeks later an American employee is beaten. Worse, a year earlier a fight between villages over labour contracts ended in murder.

The Enathganj procession takes place a week into my visit to Bibiyana, the location of my doctoral research in 1987–1988 and more recently where three researchers from Jahangirnagar University and I researched the impact of the gas field in 2008–2011.Footnote1 During our research local people expressed fury and bewilderment at finding themselves living next door to an industrial enclave which offered neither employment nor access to gas whilst Chevron attempted to mollify them with various neoliberal schemes of income generation, credit and training, which I termed ‘disconnected development’ (Gardner Citation2012; Gardner, Ahmed, Rana and Bashar Citation2014).Footnote2 In the four years since, the situation has radically changed. There is a third gas field a mile north, a new road and a new pipeline. Crucially, there are over 1000 jobs; many of the people who in 2009–2010 were furious at being overlooked are now employed. Chakri – employment in the formal sector – is what everyone wants, for agriculture is seen as too expensive and insecure. Today, many of the most vociferous critics of Chevron are now enthusiastic supporters.

The journey back to Dhaka reveals a rapidly altered landscape from the Bangladesh of my previous research in the 1980s and 1990s (Gardner Citation1991, Citation1995). The vista of rice fields and rivers remains but vast tracts of land have been overtaken by brick-kilns and factories, highways and urban sprawl. Reports have it that nearly one percent of agricultural land is being lost each year to unplanned building, causing irreversible environmental damage and threatening the country's hard-won food security; other estimates suggest that over the next 25 years 50 percent of the country's arable will be lost. Indeed, Feldman and Geisler call the country ‘an epi-centre of displacement’ (Citation2012, 973; see also Gardner and Gerharz Citation2016). Kathy Le Mons Walker's observation that land is the main site of struggle in India (Citation2008) applies equally to Bangladesh, even whilst in other quarters the country is being applauded for its advances in measures of human development (Dreze and Sen Citation2013).

Back in Bibiyana significant and unpredictable about-turns had taken place in the fortunes, and, indeed, opinions, of many people. Whilst our research up to 2011 had covered the struggles surrounding the loss of land, the situation had changed. In what follows I recount how opposition which originally united people against the gas field during the initial stage of land dispossession has, nine years later, changed into escalating estrangement and conflict between groups, based around new forms of patronage. Indeed, the shift from land to precarious labour seems not to have led to a decrease in the moral economy of village-based patronage and political allegiance, but instead has strengthened it, partly as a result of Chevron's ‘community engagement measures’. Similar processes of ‘elite capture’, and the reinforcement of pre-existing or altered forms of inequality as the result of ‘development’ or industrialisation, have been documented across South Asia (for example, Pattenden Citation2010; Shah Citation2010; Levien Citation2012; Carswell and De Neve Citation2014). What was more striking on our return to the area in 2014 was how some of the poorest rural families who were dispossessed of their land and livelihood in 2005 appeared to be doing well, at least for the time being. Clearly, the story had moved on.

Theorising the future

Before describing these changes, let us consider the way in which the future is theorised and approached both in Bibiyana and in academic work on economic transformation. As we shall see, anticipation (a state in which one waits for or looks forward to events in the future) runs through every part of my account and is reflected in both liberal and neo-Marxist theories of agrarian change. In terms of the latter, much of the emerging anthropology of industrialisation and neoliberalism in South Asia engages with the work of David Harvey and other Marxist theorists interested in capital accumulation and new forms of inequality (Adnan Citation2013; Kasmir and Carbonella Citation2008; Le Mons Walker Citation2008; Levien Citation2011, Citation2012, Citation2013; Münster and Münster Citation2012; Corbridge and Shah Citation2013; Carswell and De Neve Citation2014; Münster and Strümpell Citation2014). Harvey's work has particular resonance for anthropologists researching the repercussions of the spread of global capital into new territories (Citation2003). Arguing that capitalism's chronic over-accumulation is solved by ‘spatio-temporal fixes’ which displace the problem over time and space into new territories, Harvey refers both to the ways in which capitalist infrastructure is physically fixed (the crisis) and how its global spread fixes the problems, opening up new markets and finding new resources to exploit. He terms this process ‘accumulation by dispossession’ (ABD), a contemporary version of Marx's primitive accumulation,Footnote3 though with important differences. Land and natural resources, often seized via alliances with states, remain important whilst new forms dispossession include debt, structural adjustment, copyright and so on.

As Michael Levien has argued with reference to the development of special economic zones (SEZs) in India, two features distinguish ABD from the processes of primitive accumulation that Marx observed in the nineteenth-century English countryside (Levien Citation2012). The first is that contemporary dispossession is characterised by extra-economic factors, usually the collusion of the state with capitalist interests. The second is that whilst in the case of industrialising England, primitive accumulation forced the peasantry from the land, transforming them into an industrial proletariat, in South Asia today landlessness does not usually precede industrial employment. As Levien writes: ‘ABD has more to do with the multiple forces seeking to turn land and other resources into capital … than about what may or may not be its result: adding to the pool of wage-laborers’. (Levien Citation2012, 938). In the case of the SEZ in Rajistan which Levien documents, the result of ABD was not industrial work for the dispossessed, but rampant land speculation, the development of a rentier class of wealthier farmers and even more precarious livelihoods for the rural poor. As this work shows, contemporary forms of dispossession do not lead to predictable futures for the poorest.

ABD has proven to be a compelling formulation for those researching predatory global capitalism in South Asia, with anthropologists adding important provisos involving cultural context, local and national politics and history (cf. Münster and Münster Citation2012; Gardner and Gerharz Citation2016). In contrast is the neoliberal narrative of ‘development’. Here, the future is foregrounded and change naturalised in an evolutionary and lineal way: as inevitable, though with some bumps and obstacles (tradition, weak governance, lack of democracy and so on) to get over. Like Marxism, the future is brought to us care of The Economy, though in mainstream development theory this process is benign, for economic growth brings social goods and well-being.

Whilst anthropologists of development have spent much time critiquing this paradigm, it's important to remember that in many parts of the world people believe in it passionately. As Craig Jeffery notes in his work on ‘time pass’ in India, the promise of ‘development’ – which will arrive in the future – has led people to readjust their temporal horizons, reconciling themselves to adjusting their short-term goals in the hope of pay-offs in the longer term (Jeffrey Citation2010, 4). Waiting for the future, which can be strategic as well as unavoidable, is an important element. This sense of anticipation is the focus of Jamie Cross's work on SEZs in India, which he argues lead to ‘economies of anticipation’, involving ‘dreamscapes’ as well as nightmares of what neoliberalism will bring. Whilst in some contexts there is intense resistance, in others the advent of SEZs involves fevered speculation as farmers rush to sell their land. Meanwhile, large-scale sites of industrial infrastructure become ‘arenas of imagination, hope, aspiration and desire in which people construct and assemble possible future worlds for themselves and others from existing ideas and images’ (Cross Citation2014, 10).

As we shall see, Bibiyana has also been animated by an ‘economy of anticipation’, in which peoples’ actions are directed at an imagined though contradictory future involving both nightmarish scenarios of industrial apocalypse leading to emptied-out landscapes depleted of fertility and hopes for economic security and modernity. As they try to predict uncertain futures, the strategies and alliances of different groups shift or involve sudden reversals. Charting these, and showing the complex processes involved, reveals that we cannot assume what side people are on, or what they want. Indeed, by focussing on a particular crisis in time – that caused by accumulation by dispossession – we are in danger of over-determining the future and forgetting about the past. In doing this we might also reflect upon how ethnography, both as a method and as a form of writing, ‘locks’ unfolding events into lineal narratives that pull us towards ‘end points’ which are actually snapshots of a moment in time, over-determining what in reality are ever-changing, disordered and tangled realities. As Line Dalsgaard and Martin Frederikson put it: ‘Every time we return to the field our conclusions or “endings” so to speak, were put to shame by the course of events’ (Dalsgaard and Frederiksen Citation2013, 58).

Bibiyana: ‘global villages’ and labour reserves

The history of Bibiyana, an area of about 10 square kilometres containing four villages close to the Bibiyana River in Habiganj, Bangladesh, is in many ways a history of global labour (Adams Citation1987; Gardner Citation1995, Citation2008, Citation2012). As documented throughout Bangladesh, the country's deltaic and constantly shifting geography has been matched by a similarly mobile population of Bengalis moving east in search of new lands (Van Schendel Citation2005; Amrith Citation2013). In Talukpur, the village where I did my doctoral fieldwork, accounts of older people tell of the village being settled in the early to mid twentieth century. Men had been working as lascars in Calcutta's ships since colonial times (Adams Citation1987; Choudhury Citation1993), many eventually settling in Britain. Most initially worked in heavy industry in Northern England before a typical ‘crisis of over accumulation’ (Harvey Citation2003) occurred in the shape of the 1970s recession and mass redundancy. Rather than return to Bangladesh, the majority switched to an emerging niche: ‘Indian’ restaurants, reinforcing their foothold in Britain by obtaining citizenship and reuniting their families.

Since then, the area has developed multiple links to foreign countries (bidesh).Footnote4 Those families that had connections to Britain, known as Londonis, invested first and foremost in improving their economic and social status at home, buying up land, building pucca houses and elevating their social standing via recourse to purist Islam, education and so on. By the 1980s, local socio-economic hierarchies directly reflected access to the global labour market. Not surprisingly, the benefits of connection to bidesh were bunched in particular lineages, especially those which had previously owned land and held power: the Pathans and Syeds. By the early 2000s, land ownership, concentrated entirely with Londoni families, remained a key arbiter of economic and political power in the area. The land was used for subsistence agriculture, with surplus sold on local markets; Londoni families supplemented their incomes with remittances from the UK whilst those without British connections sought other migrant destinations, in particular the Gulf, where men worked as construction labourers. ‘Time pass’ therefore has a particular complexion, as the sons of families with Londoni connections wait for their chance to migrate, through marriage, student visas or other ruses which families dedicate much energy, resources and time to planning. Some young men spend years unemployed and waiting for their own spatio-temporal fix: their imagined futures only possible by moving in the opposite direction of Harvey's capital, back to the crisis-ravaged centres of over-accumulation, the post-industrial towns of Northern Britain, to take their turns in the restaurant trade (Gardner Citation2008).

Meanwhile, households which did not have a member overseas had either always been land poor or landless, or had slipped down the hierarchy and lost land over time. Some of these were within the powerful migrant lineages (Gardner Citation1995). Today, they continue to be very poor, but are supported by the charity of their transnational kin (Gardner and Ahmed Citation2009; Gardner Citation2012). The poorest people in the area, however, were outside the dense networks of kinship and connection that had benefitted so greatly from overseas migration. These were people living in the adjacent village of Garibgram. Originally in-migrants from other parts of Sylhet attracted by the high wages offered by Londoni families for agricultural and domestic labour, in the 1960s and early 1970s, they lived on the outskirts of Talukpur or within family baris where they were employed as semi-permanent labourers, or kamla. According to local accounts, by the mid 1970s leaders in Talukpur had arranged for nearby khas (government owned) land to be settled by the in-migrants, since they were running out of space (perhaps the land rush caused by Londoni migration meant a shortage of available khas land in Talukpur).

The relationship between the two villages was strictly one of patron and client. Garibgram supplied labour for Talukpur. Men worked as seasonal agricultural labourers or permanent kamla living in farm buildings. Women were hired as ghor beti (housemaids) helping with domestic tasks and processing agricultural products. In general, relations were cordial, permanent labourers were addressed as mama (sister's brother) and support offered at times of crisis: handed-down clothes, meals, occasional charity and loans, plus land for long-term sharecropping arrangements were offered in return for political support and a constant supply of docile labour, the hallmarks of rural patron–clientage in South Asia (van Schendel Citation1981; Jansen Citation1987; Wood Citation2003, Citation2005). There were, however, clear boundaries between the two villages. There was no inter-marriage, nor did anyone from Garibgram migrate abroad. Garibgram people were known as chotomanoosh (literally: little people) by the bhalomanoosh (good people) of Talukpur and were treated accordingly: squatting rather than being seated, eating off tin rather than china plates. During the national crises and food shortages of the mid 1970s, a friend who had set up a school in the village recalls helping people from Garibgram raid the grain stores of their wealthy patrons in Talukpur; without this action, he told me, many would have starved.

By 1990 Garibgram still largely acted as a labour reserve for Talukpur, providing labour or sharecropping land left by absentee Londoni households. Over the next 15 years, these agriculturally based livelihoods were to become increasingly precarious as a shift of investment from agriculture towards business and property took place. Subsistence agriculture was slowly being replaced by commodification. Soaring land prices and attendant speculation meant that whilst land ownership remained important to Londonis, agricultural output was increasingly irrelevant. Rather than asking for a share of the crop, some landlords were now demanding rent, making it harder to farm without capital inputs. As documented across South and South East Asia, as agriculture has become monetarised and mechanised, making a living as a small farmer is increasingly difficult. Like elsewhere, in Bibiyana farmers say that agriculture is ‘too expensive’ because of the capital required for seeds, fertiliser, labour and irrigation (see also Welker Citation2012).

The gas field: resistance and compliance

By the early 2000s Garibgram and Talkpur were still linked by patronage, but the wealthier village's need for farm labour was diminishing. Meanwhile, landless or land-poor households without capital to invest in overseas migration, education or business opportunities were forced to take up alternative sources of income, such as rickshaw driving (Khan and Seeley Citation2005). In 2005 the District Commissioner arrived in Bibiyana to announce that large reserves of natural gas had been discovered. Land would be forcibly acquired by the government and leased to Unocal (which was merged with Chevron in 2007). There was already a smaller installation (the North Pad) at a village two or three kilometres away, but this was a major find which would eventually supply over 50 percent of Bangladesh's gas, a vital resource for the by-now rapidly industrialising country's energy security. At this stage the installation was to take up 60 acres of agricultural land plus much more for the high banked roads that were to connect the North and South pads.

Bibiyana's story should be contextualised within the broader picture of rapid industrialisation and economic growth in Bangladesh. Whilst governments since the 1990s have pursued neoliberal economic policies, encouraging foreign investment, nationally the role of multinationals in the extraction of natural resources was being fiercely debated over 2008–2011 and has caused serious political unrest. In 2006 protests against a proposed open-cast mine in Phulbari in north-west Bangladesh, to be operated by Asia Energy, led to the deaths of three people and injury of around a hundred (Gain Citation2006; Faruque Citation2012; Nuremowla Citation2012). Meanwhile national agitation centred around the content of production share contracts with foreign companies, with activists arguing that these grossly exploit the country's natural resources, leading to large profits for the multinationals, generous backhanders for corrupt government officials and nothing for Bangladesh (Shawkat and Faruque Citation2009). Few, however, would dispute the need for energy security (Wesley Citation2006; Islam, Islam, and Alam Beg Citation2008). Over 2008–2011 this was increasingly pressing; power shortages were hampering the industry which has motored Bangladesh's growth rate of 6.6 percent (in the first part of 2010). Such was the need for energy that in the years leading up to our research, power shortages caused riots at electricity stations.

Meanwhile, in Bibiyana in 2005, feelings were running high. As Unocal was carrying out ‘community consultations’, people from the four villages close to the site had organised themselves into ‘Demand Resistance Committees’. The most influential leader was Joyful Haque,Footnote5 the chairman of the union parishad, a member of the Bangladesh National Party and part of the most powerful lineage in Talukpur. Other men had more informal leadership roles. Samsun Khan, for example, told us that his high social status, saintly ancestry and family honour had contributed to his role as a leader in a nearby village. Samsun Khan was soon to become one of the largest land losers: his property was directly opposite the plant and nearly all of his fields were taken. During our research he was one of the fiercest opponents of the plant.

In 2005, opposition against the gas field seemed united. For the landless, the loss of land to the gas field was seen as a serious threat to their livelihoods, involving employment as agricultural labourers or sharecroppers, as well as a pool of land for cattle grazing, gathering grain and straw post-harvest, and small fish and prawns during the wet season. Recounting this time, Samsun Khan tells of a meeting of over 2000 people at his bari. Describing the ensuring protest movement, he told us: ‘We stopped government officials and Chevron's people from entering the villages … building a barricade. We lay down on the roads and went on hunger strike’.Footnote6

Whilst Unocal held ‘community consultations’ and took advice from community relations consultants who urged them to drive more carefully, meet peoples’ eyes and try not to be associated with forced land acquisitions (Reyes and Begum Citation2005), the government threatened violence, stationing hundreds of police in barracks at the construction site. Strong pressure was placed on party members such as Joyful Haque to back down. Accompanying this was the news that after Unocal's intervention the rate of land compensation had been increased. It was at this stage that some of the leaders began to negotiate with the company, who were now promising a range of community engagement gifts including an ‘Alternative Livelihoods Programme’ to be presided over by village development organisations (VDOs), headed by the same leaders. As these leaders withdrew their support, the organised protest movement came to a halt.

*

The story of the villages surrounding the Bibiyana gas field is thus a case par excellence of ‘accumulation by dispossession’. A multinational corporation with state assistance (the ‘extra economic’ forces noted by Levien Citation2012) dispossesses farmers in order to build a large gas extraction plant. The gas is piped far away, and sold back to the government in order to profit the multinational and boost the country's energy security on which its growth rate, powered largely by privately owned garment factories, depends. Neither the gas nor the profits are distributed locally; the site of extraction is surrounded by high perimeter fences and security guards, an enclave of high modernity surrounded by a disenfranchised and resentful population.Footnote7 Rumours abound nationally and locally about backhanders and bribes offered to government officials by corporations eager to win contracts in the rush to extract Bangladesh's natural resources, which are being represented within international mining finance as a new frontier (Gilbert Citation2015).

It should be noted that many of the land owners were living in the UK. In our meetings in Britain they expressed bewilderment, fury and grief at how land they had spent their lives amassing had been taken. One man decried the way that the rural charm of his ancestral village had been destroyed, turning it into ‘an industrial zone’. Another was so upset that he sat mute and morose through a group discussion with his neighbours and relatives in Burnley. Meanwhile, in his village home a few hundred metres from the perimeter fence of the South Pad, Samsun Khan told us he ‘felt fire in my heart’ when he thought of the land his family had once owned, now covered in concrete. Chevron had a ‘case’ out against him for his role in the protest, he explained. Oddly, an hour later he was smiling and posing for photos by the fence. As he departed for his other house in Sylhet Town he handed me a card that read ‘Chevron Contractor’.

Yet whilst our interviews with land owners revealed anger about the forced acquisition, what landless people from Garibgram and other villages were most concerned with were jobs. In 2005–20007, around 500 local men had been employed in the construction of the South Pad and its infrastructure. Once the building was completed they were laid off, and tossed back onto the depleted land reserves to find whatever means they could to survive. In 2008–2009, many households in Garibgram lacked basic food security. What they wanted was work, which they had hoped Chevron would provide, they told us. ‘We were given lots of hope’, one man said in 2009, ‘but we received nothing’.

Indeed, despite the initial resistance movement, the gas field had evoked intense hope for many people; as one man put it: ‘no more darkness’. As Gisa Weszkalyns points out in her work on prospecting for oil in Sao Tome, energy resources are laden with potential (Citation2008, Citation2014). As with the oil in Sao Tome, no-one knew exactly how much gas there was under the fields in Bibiyana; the extent of the resource was continually debated during our research, and used by national protesters to contest Chevron's presence, for example in arguing that they were extracting too much, too quickly. An invisible entity, piped away and only materialising in the shape of a towering flare, the potential of gas is even more elusive than the sticky, tangible material of oil. ‘There is gold under our land’, people said, but it was never seen, only guessed at: the source of continual rumours.

The anticipation of connection to the gas, and to modernity, is vividly materialised in the shape of gas cookers, waiting in would-be kitchens of large Londoni houses that are often empty. In my adoptive house, for example, I found a cooker and stainless steel sink in the section owned by cousins who were settled in northern England. Covered in dust, and the repository not of modern cooking utensils but sacks of betel nut and rice, the oven stood forgotten. It was never connected to the gas supply, for the gas was never supplied and never used, for the cousins had not returned. A mile up the road anticipation takes a different form: a newly constructed gas station, built by a local businessman. During our research this too remained unfinished, the pumps unused.

If people in Talukpur hoped for connection to the gas supply and speculated on the profits to come, in Garibgram, it was industrial employment that was eagerly awaited. In 2008–2011 the disappointment was visceral. Landless men, who had been scraping a living as agricultural labourers, had been given training, official papers and identity tags, which they waved in my face as material evidence of their brief inclusion in modernity, industrial employees of Chevron, but only ever temporary. Now, they were set aside once more. ‘All they gave us were bullshit promises’, one man told us. There was to be no employment, no connection to the gas and no inclusion. Indeed, all that Chevron was offering were various ‘alternative livelihood’ and self-help projects: the disconnected development I mentioned earlier. Hopes for the future jostled with fear. The terror of blow-outs, based on recent accidents at other gas fields in Sylhet, was palpable during our fieldwork. Alongside their anger at Chevron, who people said had ‘looted’ local resources whilst ‘giving nothing back’, informants described how the gas extraction was emptying and draining the land. This was not only causing a reduction in the fertility of the fields, which had been dried out as a result of changes in the annual inundation of monsoon water due to the high banked roads, but would eventually lead to the land caving in once the gas reserves were emptied. Here, rather than jobs, security and modernity, the vision of the future was of a desecrated landscape, its riches pumped away to profit others, whilst ‘they give us nothing’. ‘We live in terror of the fire’, people told us. When Chevron carried out a controlled flaring one night in 2010, many hundreds of people ran from their homes in panic, believing that the dreaded blow-out had finally occurred.

These alternative futures, of secure employment, prosperity and modernity versus industrial apocalypse, can be grafted onto the alternative theoretical paradigms which I discussed earlier: the stories of blow-out and terror read as local critiques of predatory capitalism and its contemporary tendency to create escalating land speculation which only profits the land-owning rural elite, and the hopes of connection, employment and business opportunities as an approving nod to neoliberal tales of growth and good things. Both are ways of thinking about the future, and both are mobilised at different times by different people according to context. Let us now consider employment at the gas field in more detail.

Employment and labour contractors: divisions deepen

Employment was one of the main complaints against Chevron in 2008–2011, for the few local labourers taken on were hired entirely through contractors, a practice widely reported across neo-liberal India and where, as Carswell and De Neve (Citation2014), Picherit (Citation2009; Citation2012) Breman (Citation1996) and Guérin (Citation2013) have shown, it is open to forms of bonded or exploitative labour practices banned in the formal sector. In Bibiyana as in many other cases, contractors supply a reserve army of informally hired labour enabling the formal sector to utilise flexible labour power on their own terms. A related practice which caused huge resentment in Bibiyana was the use of labour drawn from distant regions, creating a ‘docile’ workforce, for outsiders are less likely to abscond or make trouble as they remain dependent upon the contractor, a locally known patron, for their everyday necessities and protection. As the Community Liaison Officer (who, tellingly, had previously been a manager of a tea estate) explained, this led to an ‘easy flow of labour’ (Gardner et al. Citation2012). During 2008–2011 the few local people who were employed as guards and road workers were hired through the labour contractors, who were largely the same ‘local leaders’ who presided over the VDOs set up by Chevron for its community development programme (Gardner Citation2012). Meanwhile, jeeps filled with foreign engineers sped to and from the gas field.

So far, so predictable: the limited resource of employment and the benefits of Chevron's community development programmes were controlled by the same land-owning elite who had monopolised migration to the UK. As Jonathan Pattenden has observed in Karnataka, the shift away from agrarian-based livelihoods does not necessarily involve a loosening of the ties between the land-owning elite and their landless clients. Rather, by being the conduits through which decentralised government funds are siphoned, the elite gain new forms of control, mediating between the state and the poor as powerful gatekeepers (Pattenden Citation2010; see also Shah Citation2010). In Bibiyana these leaders were gatekeepers not to government resources but to a global energy corporation, which despite high expectations was offering very little. Once it became clear that Chevron was not going to provide jobs or much in the way of local services, the influence of the leaders who had built relationships with the company faltered, as they were accused by local people of corruption. They received no benefits from Chevron because their leaders had sold them down the river, we were told by the landless. They had taken bribes and stuffed their own pockets, but provided nothing, an accusation strenuously denied by the men in question, who argued that they simply didn't have enough jobs to distribute. Meanwhile, when the Awami League gained power in 2008/2009, leaders who had been allied to the BNP lost their foothold in the union parishad and upazila councils. This, plus their lack of success in bringing what their previous clients had hoped for – work and material benefits – led to the rapid fall from grace for Joyful Haque, the influential leader who by 2011 had withdrawn from political life.

The fate of Joyful Haque does not, however, indicate a shift away from village-based political allegiance and patronage. Rather, as the next turn of the story shows, the growing importance of industrial work in the aspirations of local landless and land-poor people has led to a strengthening of village-based loyalties and political organisation, this time based around access to industrial employment rather than agriculture, and drawing upon the village-based development organisations set up by Chevron as part of their community engagement programme. Indeed, village membership has never been so important, but in these new times, rather than Garibgram being a supplier of rural labour for their patrons in Talukpur, the two villages are pitted against each other.

We demand work! Village committees and employment, 2013–2014

It is now early 2014. More gas reserves have been discovered, leading to a third extraction site, a mile or so from Talukpur, a major pipeline connecting this new site to the South Pad and a new road. Crucially, there are many hundreds, perhaps thousands, of new jobs, leading to intense pressure on Chevron to distribute employment locally. In the few weeks of my stay the situation is volatile. Men march from Entaganj, a market town a few miles away, and thus not, as Talukpur people say indignantly, ‘victims of the gas field’; this is the procession I see from over the fields. A few days later there is an assault close to the gas field: furious that he hasn't been given work, a Garibgram man has attacked a Chevron contractor. There is more agitation; urgent meetings are called between leaders and Chevron. Crucially, it is now village committees (samity) that negotiate deals with the company, some of which are the same VDOs which Chevron set up in order to dispense ‘community development’. In response to pressure from these committees and the processions, blockades and sit-ins that characterise protest in South Asia, the company agrees in the early weeks of 2014 to give the contracts for supplying the labour to locals, to be distributed via the samity, rather than to private labour contractors. As the Secretary of the Garibgram samity explains, although originally the company filed cases against them, a meeting with the samity and the government's energy advisor (Towfiq Eliah Chowdhury) in 2009 had led to the change in policy.

Talukpur set up its samity in 2013. The objective was to provide employment for poorer people in the village, and a connection to the gas supply. As in the Garibgram samity, each member had to pay 200 taka (around £1.50) a month to cover expenses and act as a savings group. This is a stark contrast to the labour contractors, who demand tens of thousands of taka for supplying work. By March 2014 the Talukpur samity had 70 members and had distributed 16 jobs to men from the poorest households. Their leaders also told us that they had successfully bargained for higher wages, from 6000–8000 taka a month up to 12,000–15,000 (depending on the work). Meanwhile, the Garibgram samity had distributed 300 jobs and was expecting another hundred from Chevron. What seemed to be developing was a new geography of patronage, still headed by the rural elite but based around the VDOs that Chevron had instituted. Though the powerful lineages – the Syed and Pathans who were spread across all villages with the exception of Garibgram – had maintained their position, new alliances based around business interests, access to Chevron's personnel and the VDOs were also developing.

By 2014 the material changes were visible in Garibgram. Take for example the nephews of Abdullah, who worked for my Talukpur family as a permanent farm hand in the 1980s. In 2008–2009 the family of five brothers were surviving on an insecure and meagre agriculturally based livelihood. In 2005 one of the brothers had gained work, via a Dhaka-based contracting company involved in the construction of the gas field. This came to an end once the South Pad was completed; during my 2008–2010 research they were struggling to feed themselves and living in extreme poverty. Now, all five brothers have work at the gas field, earning around 10,000 taka a month (daily wage labour is around 300 taka a day, but is irregular). They were delighted at the turn in their fortunes. Regular employment and a degree of security, at least until the work runs out; this is what they wanted so badly. Clearly, we cannot assume that people want to be farmers, an important point to remember when considering processes of ‘dispossession’ (Hall Citation2012). Mostly, they don't, for it is a hard, gruelling life, and the rewards can be meagre. ‘Better to work at the gas field!’ Abdullah's nephews told us happily.Footnote8

The upturn in the fortunes of Abdullah's nephews and the employment of hundreds of local people reminds us it is important to look beyond the struggles of dispossession and see what happens next. By 2014 in Bibiyana, the poorest people, who in 2004 were struggling in the increasingly challenging agrarian economy, appeared to have benefited, their protests against Chevron having yielded a tangible result. No longer the clients or ‘little people’ of their wealthy patrons over the fields in Talukpur, in Garibgram they have their own samity which has successfully negotiated many jobs. In the wealthy, land-owning villages, the basis for patronage had changed. Even Samsun Khan, the biggest land loser who Chevron had a ‘case’ against in 2009/2010, was now telling us how much he approved of the multinational, the case long forgotten.Footnote9 The ‘Chevron Contractor’ card he had handed me in 2009 was a clue: desperate to maintain his earlier position as a land-owning patron, he had fought against ABD. Now that the battle was lost he was keen to find new sources of power, which in the newly formed landscape of the gas field meant forgetting his previous anger and forming an alliance with Chevron.

The story fractures: violence and conflict

It is at this point that, as is so common in Bangladesh, the story fractures with division and violence. By 2014 local resistance had fragmented and was not about obstructing global capitalism in the shape of the gas field, but wanting desperately to be included in it. Seeing the success of the Garibgram samity in negotiating jobs, by 2014, others wanted to get in on the act. As the president of the samity put it: ‘Chevron has a full sack. Through our samity we managed to open it … now everyone wants a share’.

In January, for example, the Enatjanj samity was formed. This time the leader is a labour contractor, and members pay a thousand taka a month. Here, profit, rather than benefitting the poor, seems to be the principal objective. Group discussions in Garibgram revealed that just as before, access to work depends upon maintaining good relationships with the leaders. In this sense, samity leaders are in a similar role to labour contractors, compiling lists of who should and shouldn't be given the work, and negotiating with Chevron. In Talukpur the samity leaders are the same figures who led the 2005 protests and from the same families who have dominated Londoni migration and land ownership since the 1980s – the old patrons returned, albeit with a different resource base. Indeed, Joyful Haque has re-emerged from his temporary political exile, becoming one of the leaders.

Crucially, what started as united resistance to Chevron and the state has turned into a new geography of conflict, with villages pitched against each other in the competition for jobs. In some cases the old land-owning elite remains powerful, because they have developed close links to Chevron which they use to create jobs for poor people in their villages. In others, the change is radical. Garibgram, for example, is now in direct conflict with Talukpur, the village's previous patron, for the people of Garibgram are no longer dependent upon their old Talukpur patrons for agricultural work, seeking new patrons from outside the area who can offer industrial employment. The location of the village immediately adjacent to the gas field has increased their bargaining power with Chevron as well as Talukpur, a mile away. This is vividly illustrated by a dispute which began when Chevron offered a contract to fill fields adjacent to Garibgram with sand in preparation for more building. Accounts differ, but it seems that a contracting company owned by businessmen in Talukpur and other nearby villages won the contract, but this was contested by the Garibgram samity. In some accounts the local upazila (council) member who also happened to be the president of the Garibgram samity was supporting a businessman from the next upazila, Baniachung (40 kilometres away) in the expectation of a cut of the profits. The end result was a battle between the people of Garibgram and an alliance between Talukpur plus other villages who wanted the work to go to their own people and who were outraged at the previous clients of Garibgram striking out alone. Whilst in Talukpur my friends had told me that since the arrival of the gas field people of Garibgram had become violent and dishonest, and the dispute had arisen because of their allegiance to the Baniachung contractor – an outsider who had no right getting contracts from Chevron – those in Garibgram described crowds of people coming in trucks to attack them with homemade weapons. Whilst many escaped to the fields, a woman was struck with a stick and later died.

As this sad story shows, groups of workers are organised by village-based samity in order to exert concerted pressure on Chevron to distribute work locally, but also to fight other villages. Whether or not the samity are controlled by contractors or more genuinely representative of local interests seems to vary. In early 2014 people were talking darkly of how the samity were being used to profit the leaders, and of increasing violence and intimidation. Later that year an American working for Chevron was assaulted by a man from Garibgram – yet more evidence for those in Talukpur who say the village is filled with criminal thugs.

Conclusion

In observing events over time and resisting the temptation to foreclose accounts of agrarian transition, we see how ABD in Bibiyana has been followed by complex shifts in power, with uncertain benefits for the poorest. In Bibiyana, as elsewhere in Bangladesh, land dispossession has a long history, as has been highlighted by many commentators who describe the aggressive tactics of elites seizing land and other resources since the early 1970s (Adnan and Mansur Citation1975; van Schendel Citation1981; Hartmann and Boyce Citation1983; Jenkins Citation1983).Footnote10 And if dispossession is nothing new, neither is the role of global capital in restructuring social and economic relations both within and between places. Many decades before Chevron's gas field, migration to the UK had led to the accumulation of property by individual men and their families, who gained land from the rapidly disenfranchised non-migrants (Gardner Citation1995). It was these families, largely settled in the UK, who were dispossessed in the most obvious sense of losing their property to the gas field. As we have seen, the discovery of greater-than-imagined natural gas reserves and the expansion of the gas field have meant that for now at least, those who were previously the ‘little people’ (chotomanoosh) seem to be benefitting, even if for now they remain dependent upon samity leaders and labour contractors, who control the distribution of industrial employment. Eventually the current phase of construction will end, and many hundreds will be laid off.

Whilst the protests of 2005 involved united force between villages against the construction of the gas field, closer attention to the stories shows significant ambivalence and disagreement. Over time it became clear that different people wanted different things. The land-owning elite were united for a while, but then opportunities appeared, political pressure was exerted from above and they became divided. Today, those from the elite who were most opposed, such as Samsun Khan, are working enthusiastically with Chevron as contractors. Meanwhile the landless of Garibgram, who were initially united behind their patrons in Talukpur but then showed their anger at local leaders and labour contractors/Chevron, were concerned not with the loss of land, but the availability of employment. This fury, articulated with focus groups and interviews in our research in 2009–2011 and violently expressed by individual assaults more recently, was not about dispossession in the sense of struggles over land but lack of inclusion in an eagerly anticipated future of industrial employment.

Crucially, rather than becoming increasingly detached from their villages or uniting as a proto-industrial class, what the ethnographic evidence shows is that over 2012–2014 the opposite process was taking place for the rural poor, with village-based patronage remaining important, but in different ways. Indeed, village-level political organisation has been strengthened by Chevron's promotion of ‘local leaders’ and VDOs as part of their community engagement programme. Whilst the patronage of Talukpur over their rural labour reserve in Garibgram has been overtaken by violence and conflict between the villages, the village-based samity which agitate for work reflect the structures of patronage encouraged by Chevron's granting of contracts to ‘local community leaders’ and their fashioning of ‘village development organisations’ to dispense their development gifts. Patronage thus continues to thrive, but within rather than between villages, and based around the ability of individuals to negotiate work contracts and wages with Chevron in their role as ‘community leaders’, rather than their ownership of land. Whilst agriculture may no longer be the basis of rural livelihoods, villages – as political units and conduits of patronage – remain vital to the survival of the poorest. What will happen in the future? As the twists and turns of my account show, whilst futurity has become ever more important to those concerned, whether local people attempting to foresee risks and opportunities, corporate strategists calibrating future gas reserves or, indeed, anthropologists seeking coherent stories, the uneven registers and scales of neoliberal temporality (Bear Citation2014) mean that only time will tell.

Acknowledgements

My collaborator in fieldwork in Bibiyana in 2014 was Professor Zahir Ahmed of Jahangirnagar University: huge thanks for his support and insights. Drafts of earlier versions of this paper were shared with the LSE Anthropology Department Friday Morning Seminar in July 2014 and the South Asia seminar at Oxford in October 2016. Many thanks for the extremely useful and stimulating feedback from colleagues at both events. Thanks also for the excellent feedback of the JPS reviewers.

Disclosure statement

No potential conflict of interest was reported by the author.

Additional information

Funding

The research on which some of this paper is based was funded by the ESRC [grand number RES-167-25-0297] over 2008–2011.

Notes on contributors

Katy Gardner

Professor Katy Gardner is currently Head of Anthropology at the LSE. She has been researching issues surrounding transnational migration and rural transition in Bangladesh since the 1980s. Her work includes research with Bengali communities in London, and, more recently, gas mining and land dispossession in North East Bangladesh. She is the author of four monographs and numerous articles, including Songs at the river’s edge (1991, Virago) Global migrants, local lives (1995, Oxford); Age, narrative and migration (2001, Berg); Discordant developments (2012, Pluto) and, with David Lewes, Anthropology and development: 21st century challenges (Pluto, 2015). Email: [email protected]

Notes

1 This research was funded by the ESRC-DFID joint fund for poverty-focussed research, for which I am extremely grateful. My colleagues at Janhangirnagar were Fatema Bashir, Masud Rana and Zahir Ahmed.

2 Julila Elyachar describes similar World Bank projects as ‘antidevelopment development’ (Citation2002); see also Karim (Citation2011) and Pattenden (Citation2010).

3 ‘Accumulation by dispossession’ draws attention to the ongoing processes of primitive accumulation, the process by which Marx argued that in pre-capitalist contexts the means of production – usually land –  was transferred from the producers to capitalist owners via violent and state sponsored methods such as the enclosures of the English countryside, slavery and colonial conquest.

4 In 2014 remittances from overseas migration were a major earner for Bangladesh, with destinations including the Gulf, South East Asia and South Africa. Migration to the UK, however, remained a monopoly of particular areas in Sylhet (Gardner Citation2008).

5 The names of villages and individuals have been anonymised.

6 Interview notes, 2008.

7 This is similar to what James Ferguson describes in his much-cited paper 'Seeing it Like an Oil Company’, which argues that extractive industries in Africa create discontinuous development – enclaves of modernity which use up productive resources but leave ‘un-useable’ Africa untouched (Ferguson Citation2005).

8 Their only complaint was the uniforms that Chevron forced them to wear, which were too heavy and hot.

9 His alliance with The Awami League may be a factor.

10 As documented in a Bangladeshi classic A quiet violence (Hartmann and Boyce Citation1983), the victims are usually the poorest, forced from their homes and land via the crude methods of arson, murder or violent intimidation. In other instances the poor are mobilised to support the claims of their patrons (see Adnan Citation2013 and Feldman and Geisler Citation2012). In Talukpur in the early 2000s, for example, a land dispute led to a fight between two groups in which a young man from a landless and marginal family was shot dead.

References

  • Adams, C. 1987. Across Seven Seas and Thirteen Rivers: Life Stories of Pioneer Sylhetti Settlers in Britain. London: Tower Hamlets Arts Project.
  • Adnan, S. 2013. “Land Grabs and Primitive Accumulation in Deltaic Bangladesh: Interactions Between Neoliberal Globalization, State Interventions, Power Relations and Peasant Resistance.” The Journal of Peasant Studies 40 (1): 87–128.
  • Adnan, S., and A. H. Mansur. 1975. Land, Power & Violence in Barisal Villages. Village Study Group based at the University of Dacca and the Bangladesh Institute of Development Studies.
  • Amrith, S. 2013. Crossing the Bay of Bengal. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.
  • Bear, L. 2014. “Doubt, Conflict, Mediation: the Anthropology of Modern Time.” Journal of the Royal Anthropological Institute 20 (S1): 3–30.
  • Breman, J. 1996. Footloose Labour: Working in India’s Informal Economy. Vol. 2. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
  • Carswell, G., and G. De Neve. 2014. “T-shirts and Tumblers Caste, Dependency and Work Under Neoliberalisation in South India.” Contributions to Indian Sociology 48 (1): 103–131.
  • Choudhury, Y. 1993. The Routes and Tales of the Bangladeshi Settlers. Birmingham: Sylhet Social History Group.
  • Corbridge, S., and A. Shah. 2013. “Introduction: the Underbelly of the Indian Boom.” Economy and Society 42 (3): 335–347.
  • Cross, J. 2014. Dream Zones: Anticipating Capitalism and Development in India. London Introduction: Pluto Press.
  • Dalsgaard, A. L., and M. D. Frederiksen. 2013. “Out of Conclusion: on Recurrence and Open-Endedness in Life and Analysis.” Social Analysis 57 (1): 50–63.
  • Dreze, J., and A. Sen. 2013. An Uncertain Glory: India and its Contradictions. Princeton: Princeton University Press.
  • Elyachar, J. 2002. “Empowerment Money: the World Bank, non-Governmental Organizations, and the Value of Culture in Egypt.” Public Culture 14 (3): 493–513.
  • Faruque, O. 2012. The Phulbari Movement: Political Struggle against Neoliberal Development in Bangladesh. University of Waterloo-Wilfrid Laurier University.
  • Feldman, S., and C. Geisler. 2012. “Land Expropriation and Displacement in Bangladesh.” The Journal of Peasant Studies 39: 971–993.
  • Ferguson, J. 2005. “Seeing Like an Oil Company: Space, Security, and Global Capital in Neoliberal Africa.” American Anthropologist 107 (3): 377–382.
  • Gain, P. 2006. Killings in Phulbari Ignite Unstoppable Protest: Local Communities Stand Strong against Open Cut Mining. Dhaka: Society for Environment and Human Development.
  • Gardner, K. 1991. Songs at the River’s Edge: Stories From a Bangladeshi Village. London: Virago.
  • Gardner, K. 1995. Global Migrants, Local Lives: Migration and Transformation in Rural Bangladesh. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
  • Gardner, K. 2008. “Keeping Connected: Security, Place and Social Capital in a Londoni Village in Sylhet.” Journal of the Royal Anthropological Institute (JRAI); N.S 14: 447–495.
  • Gardner, K. 2012. Discordant Development: Global Capitalism and the Struggle for Connection in Bangladesh. London: Pluto Press.
  • Gardner, K., and Z. Ahmed. 2009. “Degrees of Separation: Informal Social Protection, Relatedness and Migration in Biswanath, Bangladesh.” The Journal of Development Studies 45 (1): 124–149.
  • Gardner, K., Z. Ahmed, M. Rana, and F. Bashar. 2012. “Elusive Partnerships: Gas Extraction and CSR in Bangladesh.” Resources Policy 37 (2): 168–174.
  • Gardner, K., Z. Ahmed, M. Rana, and F. Bashar. 2014. “Field of Dreams: Imagining Development and Undevelopment at a gas Field in Sylhet.” South Asian Multi-Disciplinary Academic Journal (SAMAJ) 19, online http://samaj.revues.org/3704.
  • Gardner, K., and E. Gerharz. 2016. “Land, Development and Security in Bangladesh and India: An Introduction.” South Asia Multi-Disciplinary Journal (SAMAJ) (13), https://samaj.revues.org/4141.
  • Gilbert, P. 2015. “Money Mines: An Ethnography of Frontiers, Capital and Extractive Industries in London and Bangladesh.” (Thesis submitted for PhD). University of Sussex.
  • Guérin, I. 2013. “Bonded Labour, Agrarian Changes and Capitalism: Emerging Patterns in South India.” Journal of Agrarian Change 13 (3): 405–423.
  • Hall, D. 2012. “Rethinking Primitive Accumulation: Theoretical Tensions and Rural Southeast Asian Complexities.” Antipode 44 (4): 1188–1208.
  • Hartmann, B., and J. K. Boyce. 1983. A Quiet Violence: The View From a Bangladesh Village. London: Zed Books.
  • Harvey, D. 2003. The New Imperialism. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
  • Islam, R. M., R, Islam, and R. Alam Beg. 2008. “Renewable Energy Resources and Technologies Practice in Bangladesh.” Renewable and Sustainable Energy Reviews 12 (2): 299–343.
  • Jansen, E. 1987. Rural Bangladesh: Competition Over Scarce Resources. Dhaka: Dhaka University Press.
  • Jeffrey, C. 2010. Timepass: Youth, Class, and the Politics of Waiting in India. Stanford: Stanford University Press.
  • Jenkins, A. 1983. The Net: Power Structure in Ten Villages. Dhaka: BRAC.
  • Karim, L. 2011. Microfinance and its Discontents: Women in Debt in Bangladesh. Minneapolis: University of Minnesota Press.
  • Kasmir, S., and A. Carbonella. 2008. “Dispossession and the Anthropology of Labor.” Critique of Anthropology 28 (1): 5–25.
  • Khan, I., and J. Seeley. 2005. Making a Living: The Livelihoods of the Poor in Bangladesh. Dhaka: Dhaka University Press.
  • Le Mons Walker, K. 2008. “Neoliberalism on the Ground in Rural India: Predatory Growth, Agrarian Crisis, Internal Colonization, and the Intensification of Class Struggle.” The Journal of Peasant Studies 35: 4.
  • Levien, M. 2011. “Special Economic Zones and Accumulation by Dispossession in India.” Journal of Agrarian Change 11 (4): 454–483.
  • Levien, Michael. 2012. “The Land Question: Special Economic Zones and the Political Economy of Dispossession in India.” The Journal of Peasant Studies 39 (3-4): 933–969.
  • Levien, Michael. 2013. “Regimes of Dispossession: From Steel Towns to Special Economic Zones.” Development and Change 44 (2): 381–407.
  • Münster, D., and U. Münster. 2012. “Consuming the Forest in an Environment of Crisis: Nature Tourism, Forest Conservation and Neoliberal Agriculture in South India.” Development and Change 43 (1): 205–227.
  • Münster, Daniel, and Christian Strümpell. 2014. “The Anthropology of Neoliberal India: An Introduction.” Contributions to Indian Sociology 48 (1): 1–16.
  • Nuremowla, S. 2012. “Resistance, Rootedness and Mining Protest.” (University of Sussex Phd thesis.
  • Pattenden, J. 2010. “A neo-Liberalism of Civil Society? Self Help Groups and the Labouring Class Poor in Rural South India.” The Journal of Peasant Studies 37 (3): 485–512.
  • Picherit, D. 2009. “ Workers, trust us!’: Labour middlemen and the rise of the lower castes in Andhra Pradesh.”  Accessed 5/11/14. http://discovery.ucl.ac.uk/1380217/.
  • Picherit, D. 2012. “Migrant Labourers’ Struggles Between Village and Urban Migration Sites: Labour Standards, Rural Development and Politics in South India.” Global Labour Journal 3 (1): 143–162.
  • Reyes, D., and S. Begum. 2005. Corporate Engagement Project Field Report; CDA Collaborative Learning Projects. Accessed July 16, 2010. http://cdainc.com/publications/cep/fieldvisits/cepVisit19Bangladesh.pdf.
  • Shah, A. 2010. In the Shadows of the State: Indigenous Politics, Environmentalism, and Insurgency in Jharkhand, India. Durham: Duke University Press.
  • Shawkat, A., and A. Faruque. 2009. “Tragedy of Gas and Coal Exploration in Bangladesh: Towards Ensuring Corporate Environmental Accountability.” Asia Pacific Journal of Environmental Law 12 (1): 117–148.
  • van Schendel, W. 1981. Peasant Mobility: The Odds of Life in Rural Bangladesh. Assen: Van Gorcum.
  • Van Schendel, W. 2005. The Bengal Borderland: Beyond State and Nation in South Asia. London: Anthem Press.
  • Welker, M. 2012. “The Green Revolution’s Ghost: Unruly Subjects of Participatory Development in Rural Indonesia.” American Ethnologist 39: 389–406.
  • Wesley, M. 2006. Energy Security in Asia. London: Routledge.
  • Weszkalnys, G. 2008. “Hope & oil: Expectations in São Tomé e Príncipe.” Review of African Political Economy 35 (117): 473–482.
  • Weszkalnys. 2014. ‘Geology, potentiality, speculation: on the interdeterminancy of natural resources’ (forthcoming).
  • Wood, G. 2003. “Staying Secure, Staying Poor: The “Faustian Bargain”.” World Development 31 (3): 455–471.
  • Wood, G. 2005. “Poverty, Capabilities and Perverse Social Capital: an Antidote to Sen and Putnam.” In Making a Living, edited by I. Khan, and J. Seeley. Dhaka: Dhaka University Press.
  • Website
  • Asianews.it. 2006. “Six dead, 100 reportedly wounded in Bangledesh electricity protest.” January 24. http://www.asianews.it/news-en/Six-dead,-100-reportedly-wounded-in-Bangladesh-electricityprotest-5196.html (accessed October 14 2010)