2,485
Views
9
CrossRef citations to date
0
Altmetric
Articles

Assets and domestic units: methodological challenges for longitudinal studies of poverty dynamics

ORCID Icon, ORCID Icon, ORCID Icon, &

ABSTRACT

Tracking change in assets access and ownership in longitudinal research is difficult. Assets are rarely assigned to individuals. Their benefit and management are spread across domestic units which morph over time. We review the challenges of using assets to understand poverty dynamics, and tracking the domestic units that own and manage assets. Using case studies from longitudinal research we demonstrate that assets can afford useful insights into important change.

Introduction

Reading The Village that Vanished was a strange experience. The book, based on three years of research by Vesa-Matti Loiske, describes the village of Gitting, in central Tanzania, in the early 1990s. Loiske found high levels of destitution (32% of families). A further 27% of families were poor, living in inadequate houses, with few assets, no livestock and dependent on daily labour. The reader, Dan Brockington, was studying the book 20 years after Loiske’s work, while living in the village of Sagong (close to Gitting). He was perplexed because he could not recognise such high levels of poverty in his recent survey work and the previous 13 years of visits and nor could his in-laws, all lifelong Sagong residents.

Brockington contacted Loiske to discuss his confusion, leading to a series of visits to Gitting in 2013 and re-visits of the families in Loiske’s original survey. That research has shown that many of these once poor families were still present in a recognisable form, and they appeared to be richer due to better farming technology (ploughs, more oxen and improved crop breeds), higher crop prices and more equal social relations (Brockington et al. Citation2018).

At first sight this story of transformation appears easy to tell. Changes to farming activity have made people richer and they have invested in their homes, farms and businesses. But it is not that simple. Embedded in any claim about changing prosperity in Gitting are other important claims about how prosperity should be measured and the social units which experience that prosperity.

Many of the changes in wealth, as described by the villagers who experienced them, are best captured by exploring changes to assets. As we describe in the companion papers in this issue, and have reported elsewhere, assets are important in local definitions of wealth (Brockington et al. Citation2018; Östberg et al. Citation2018; Howland, Noe, and Brockington Citation2019; Brockington Citation2019b). Yet, as we have argued in these same papers, investment in assets can be poorly captured by standard measures of poverty such as poverty lines built on household consumption data. Studying assets therefore is useful as it complements other measures of prosperity and poverty, as well as providing insights into emic definitions of wealth and well-being.

Inseparable from any investigation of assets is the appropriate social unit of analysis required to understand change in them. Many of the assets described here (land, houses, livestock) are effectively owned and managed by social units larger than individuals. Their benefits are experienced collectively (if rarely equally). They are not, therefore, a good measure of change in individual fortunes. Any measure of wealth and poverty requires the right analytical social unit to track change. In the case of assets this will require reference to the families, households, domestic units or domestic groups who collectively own and manage these assets. We will talk about these units as ‘domestic units’ from hereon.

Research involving domestic units is difficult. It is well established, but inadequately recognised, that domestic units contain inequalities, power struggles and differences between intersections of gender and age (inter alia). These can be fundamental to understanding the nature and reproduction of poverty and prosperity. This issue is compounded in longitudinal research because domestic units shift. Their membership, location, activities and both internal and external power relations can change substantially and rapidly.

In this paper we explore the conceptual and practical challenges that can arise when trying to use assets, and therefore domestic units, in research which explores change in wealth and poverty over time. We argue that the methodological challenges of attempting this are significant. But we also contend that is important to try to explore the socially embedded dynamics of assets. We illustrate this argument with research from Tanzania, as well as findings from other longitudinal studies.

We proceed as follows. First, we explain why assets matter for longitudinal studies of prosperity and poverty. Then we consider the complications of exploring assets and wealth change over time. Next we turn to the problems of working with domestic units over time. Having considered these issues we then summarise insights from a collection of different longitudinal studies in Tanzania, setting them into the context of the broader genre of longitudinal research. We conclude by discussing the insights, and potential pitfalls of this approach.

What are assets and why do they matter?

The definition of assets varies. The most restricted definition refers to things which are owned, bought, saved and disposed of – land, livestock, houses and domestic goods. But the term can be used more liberally (Sahn and Stifel Citation2000; Booysen, Servaas van der Berg, and von Maltitz Citation2008; Young Citation2012). Barrett and colleagues recently defined assets

broadly … as the state/stock variables used to generate income, including future income against which one might borrow. This includes both public and private goods and encompasses financial, human, natural, and social capital. (Citation2016, 5)

These include aspects of prosperity such as levels of education, health, or more hard-to-measure notions of social connections or happiness. Johnston and Abreu (Citation2016) observed that the term ‘assets’ can be used in a way which makes it synonymous with ‘sustainable livelihoods’ (Scoones Citation1998) or ‘capabilities’ (Sen Citation1999).Footnote1 Ellis (Citation2000, 296) explicitly equates assets to the five forms of capital outlined in the sustainable livelihoods framework. Bebbington treats assets and capitals synonymously:

assets - or what I call capitals in this framework - are not simply resources that people use in building livelihoods: they are assets that give them the capability to be and to act. (199: 2022 emphasis in the original)

Even when broadly defined, assets are useful for exploring poverty dynamics because they allow researchers to distinguish between different sorts of income poverty, according to the asset profiles that underlie them (Barrett, Carter, and Little Citation2006; Carter and Barrett Citation2006). Those without assets are structurally poor and endure persistent poverty (Naschold Citation2012). Assets are also more easily surveyed than income (Johnston and Abreu Citation2016).

Assets can be divided into ‘productive assets’ which produce food or income (land or livestock), and ‘non-productive assets’ (phones, televisions and fridges) used primarily for consumption. But the productive and non-productive distinction can break down when non-productive assets also generate income. Fridges can store sodas in informal shops. Televisions attract customers to bars. Use of phones is sold. A home with electricity will charge for charging phones. Likewise farmland can be unused and oxen rested; productive assets are not always productive.

Asset dynamics can provide a number of insights into poverty and prosperity. One of the most important is that assets are fundamental to the definitions of poverty and wealth that are used by poor people (cf. Narayan Citation2000). Group discussions in Tanzanian villages about wealth tend to focus on the quality of houses, amount of land farmed, size of herds and the abilities and freedoms that derive from owning these things, rather than income per se (Howland, Noe, and Brockington Citation2019). Similarly poverty is defined, in part, by the lack of access to important assets. Barrett and colleagues observe that meagre asset bases yielding poor income streams can provide the conditions that promote behaviour that reinforces poverty (Barrett, Garg, and McBride Citation2016). Adato and colleagues have shown that poor asset bases and weak social capital limit economic mobility for the South African poor (Adato, Carter, and May Citation2006; Adato, Lund, and Mhlongo Citation2007).

The salience of assets in local meanings of wealth and poverty is underlined by the centrality of assets in understanding longitudinal poverty dynamics (Carter and Barrett Citation2006; Naschold Citation2012). When people experience better fortune they will often invest in assets rather than day-to-day expenditure (Scott Citation2010). Sustained extra income is not necessarily spent on frequent meat or bottled soda. Rather it is invested in education, sewing machines, livestock, a better home and so on. Changing assets can be a more sensitive measure to reductions in poverty than, for example, changes to diet. Liverpool-Tasie and Winter-Nelson found from panel data in Ethiopia that asset-based measures of wealth were much better at predicting future expenditure and asset portfolios than expenditure-based measures of wealth (Liverpool-Tasiea and Winter-Nelson Citation2011). Carter and Lybbert (Citation2012), exploring panel data from Burkina Faso in the mid-1980s, found two different responses to weather shocks with respect to assets that neatly capture the significance and role of assets in poverty dynamics. They observed that households who were poor with respect to their productive assets (herd sizes of less than 15.5 Tropical Livestock Units – TLU) conserved their assets, and experienced declines in every-day consumption due to weather shocks. These they call ‘asset smoothers’. Conversely those who were productive asset rich (more than 24.1 TLU) were able to offset consumption declines with herd sales, and readily did so (these were consumption smoothers). Productive assets therefore are a crucial means of becoming wealthy and people save in order to invest in them.

Sale of assets can also be important signs of stress and immiseration. Assets, particularly productive assets, are usually the things which poorer people experiencing immiseration hold onto for the longest (De Waal Citation1989). Better to go hungry than sell the cow that could sustain you when the rains return (Behnke and Scoones Citation1993). The sale of (important) productive assets therefore is a good indicator that things have got really bad, and might be about to get worse. Or in Chayanov’s chilling formulation, the best adapted peasant farmer ‘knows how to starve’ (Citation1991 [Citation1927], 40).

Assets and poverty dynamics over time

Assets are clearly important for understanding poverty dynamics. But their contribution is probably best described as a necessary complication, rather than a welcome clarification. Assets are central to any robust understanding of wealth and poverty, but how to capture that relationship and its changes over time is fraught with difficulty.

Assets are commonly used to construct asset indices and divide surveyed individuals or domestic units into groups. But asset indices present two challenges to understanding poverty dynamics. First, while groups in an index can be used to examine inequality, and one domestic unit’s wealth relative to another, it is not easy to compare indices over time. The asset base used to build two different indices, for the same place but at different times, can change dramatically, and will not be captured by comparison of groups.

Second, as Johnston and Abreu demonstrate (Citation2016), and as we discuss in a companion paper, asset indices are assumed to reflect underlying wealth (Howland, Noe, and Brockington Citation2019). However unless they are confined to relatively small areas and groups then they will also reflect variation in cultural preferences (which determine which assets people invest in) as well as broader infrastructural provision (such as the availability of electricity). Asset indices also have a well recognised urban bias (Howe et al. Citation2012). They can differentiate urban populations from rural populations but do not necessarily indicate the wealth of rural communities, which may prioritise different asset bundles, based on land, livestock and agricultural technology (Howland, Noe, and Brockington Citation2019).

If we do not use asset indices but instead the changing value of assets over time then other problems arise. The monetary value of assets is hard to capture because asset prices can vary considerably over various time scales both seasonally (livestock) and over years (land or motorcycles). Meaningful depreciation costs of houses, in contexts where houses are rarely bought or sold, and where each domestic unit constructs their own, are hard to calculate. This is particularly true of poorer people’s houses, or houses built from naturally and locally available materials. The value of land, especially where markets are dominated by informal exchanges, can be hard to ascertain.

These problems become particularly pressing when exploring the changing value of assets over the long term. In high inflationary environments converting an asset into a cash value and then subjecting that number to modifications due to inflation and purchasing power parity changes, further adds to the difficulties in determining the worth of assets. Even without these financial considerations, exploring change in asset ownership and wealth is complicated because local interpretations of assets change over time (cf. Mushongah and Scoones Citation2012).

Finally, the relationship of assets with more common measurements of poverty is not straightforward. The relationship between income and assets is not linear (Harttgen, Klasen, and Vollmer Citation2013) and asset indices are not always a good proxy for consumption (Howe et al. Citation2009). A recent study found that income increased in all groups studied, but that over the same time period the value of asset portfolios owned by these groups decreased (De Weerdt Citation2010; Beegle, De Weerdt, and Dercon Citation2011). Assets share the flaws of income, consumption and other measures in that all are imperfect measures of welfare in different ways.

None of these challenges make historical comparisons using assets futile. Indeed, the very fact that asset dynamics can behave in different ways than measures is another reason to include them – for otherwise the changes they signify will be missed. However the point of this section is to establish that it is no easy, or straightforward task. Indeed, as Angus Deaton and Thomas Pogge have pointed out for poverty line data, these difficulties attend all international and diachronic measures of poverty (Deaton Citation2004; Pogge Citation2005). Attention to assets therefore adds to recognised methodological woes; it does not solve them. But the difficulties of examining assets are not an objection to examining them at all.

Domestic units and poverty dynamics over time

If assets are important for understanding wealth and poverty dynamics then the social unit and scale of analysis used to assess also has to be considered carefully. The social consequences of access to a bundle of assets can only be understood in the context of the domestic units that own, access, use and share them (Meinzen-Dick et al. Citation2011; Johnson et al. Citation2016). Domestic units can be understood as the entities that come form around particular configurations of assets. Their origins, fission and fusion are signalled by transfers and changes in asset distribution. A classic example comes from pastoral societies where the transfer of livestock marks moments of engagement, marriage, childbirth and ties between families (Broch-Due Citation1990).

If the benefit streams and management costs of assets at any moment in time are controlled by domestic units then it follows that any sort of meaningful claim about changes in wealth based on assets which are owned by domestic units hinges on the conceptualisation, composition and stability of domestic units. For example, consider the claim that a particular village has become richer because the asset ownership of its constituent domestic units has improved – they have more livestock, more televisions, more smartphones and bigger houses. This single claim has in fact two components: the obvious claim that asset portfolios are better, and, underlying it, the claim that domestic units used have been stable enough to merit comparison.

If there is no such stability then the comparison becomes less meaningful. For example, it might be that a village appears to have become richer because its poorer residents are no longer present. This could be the case if poorer domestic units have died, or their members redistributed, because of their poverty, or been forced out, or been displaced by some process of gentrification. Another possibility might be that the organisation of domestic production has changed in ways which have allowed new forms of asset accumulation. There may have been no noticeable immigration or emigration, but the domestic units that people live in have changed. In either case the value of comparing one site like this over time recedes if the units composing it have undergone such profound change.

We must attend to the stability of the social unit used because there is a history of domestic units which has seen the term, and particularly cognate terms like ‘household’, used carelessly and in ways which disguise important dynamics. Specifically, they conceal inequalities between age groups and gender that make generalisations across ‘households’ problematic at best. These problems have been recognised for many years (cf. Guyer Citation1981; Vandergeest and Rigg Citation2012), but still persist (Randall, Coast, and Leone Citation2011; Randall and Coast Citation2015). The problems, serious enough in cross-sectional surveys, are compounded in longitudinal studies which attempt to revisit communities, and in particular the same domestic units more than once, because the sorts of economic activity (of production and consumption) that creates domestic units, and the social life that animates them, will vary considerably over time. They may be, in short, not at all the same units that were originally visited.

Numerous dynamics have to be accounted for when attempting to use domestic units as a vehicle for understanding social change. Perhaps the most well known is the ‘developmental cycle’ of domestic groups (Goody Citation1958). This refers to the stages through which domestic units pass as they age and members are born and die, which, to an extent, determine their residence patterns, control over resources, and membership, as well as their asset base. Fortes used this concept to explain how households from the same ethnic group could appear to adopt different residence patterns, demonstrating that this was simply a function of the ‘time factor’ that had to be grasped if we are to understand how these societies reproduce themselves (Fortes Citation1958, 2). As Stenning showed so clearly, the developmental cycle of WoDaabe pastoralists in northern Nigeria was marked clearly by stages of betrothal, child birth and then the subsequent dispersal and dissolution of the domestic units (Stenning Citation1958). He also made clear that exigencies of climate, disease and the internal dynamics of units themselves would mean that units would coalesce and fissure over varying time-scales. For the purposes of understanding dynamics in prosperity and wealth with respect to assets, the developmental cycle is essential. It shows how younger units and older units can be expected to be poorer than mature units. Growing prosperity may simply be a sign of a maturing family, and immiseration a sign of senescence.

But the developmental cycle contains important assumptions that, if violated, may limit its usefulness (Murray Citation1987). First, it assumes sufficient social homogeneity to allow these generational processes to be observed. Second, that the developmental cycle can be distinguished from other forces for change which are occurring over similar time spans. Murray argued that, in southern African contexts in the 1980s, there was too much variety in the form and dynamics of domestic units to generalise in terms of cycles. What people did, and what happened to their residential groups and larger families, was bound up in changes to the migrant labour economy of South Africa, more than it was driven by internal dynamics.

These tensions illustrate that the domestic unit is both a product of cultural expression that reproduces a society, and an expression of the ways that individuals interact through relations of mutual dependence in order to ensure their own survival in a context of varying economic, environmental and political conditions. To use Hyden’s language, we can see domestic units as part of an economy of affection which is characteristic of the peasant mode of production:

it denotes a network of support, communications and interaction among structurally defined groups connected by blood, kin, community or other affinities, for example, religion. It links together in a systematic fashion a variety of discrete economic and social units which in other regards may be autonomous. (Hyden Citation1983, 8)

Whilst the original analysis saw the economy of affection as offering resistance to the capitalist mode of production, Hyden (Citation2015) finds the concept still useful to describe social relations and reciprocity in increasingly urban and capitalist Africa. Ferguson’s recent work on notions of dependence in Southern Africa develops the idea that people seek relations of dependence on each other and on collective institutions (Ferguson Citation2013, Citation2015). Thus the domestic unit is buffeted and shaped by wider economic and political forces.

There are common forms of heterogeneity and instability in some societies that make it difficult to talk about developmental cycles, and indeed stymy the whole project of trying to explore change through the lens of domestic groups, particularly if those groups are seen as geographical nodes, rather than as networks of relationships. Membership of domestic units may be highly unstable because of divorce, fostering practices, or migration. Mathew Lockwood describes in detail the sorts of dynamism that occurred in rice growing districts of southern Tanzania that exemplify these difficulties:

The following is the history of the household in which I lived between December 1985 and September 1986. Before I moved in, the household consisted of a man in his forties, A, his wife, son from a previous marriage, aged about 15, and a daughter aged about 5. In December his wife left him and went to live with relatives in Zanzibar. The daughter went to stay with her grandmother in the village. At this point I moved in. January: a cousin of A’s arrives, with her teenage daughter. They start preparing to farm rice in the valley. February: A’s son argues with his father and leaves for relatives in Mkongo. A’s daughter comes back to the house. April: The visiting cousin moves to a dungu [small hut in the fields used when cultivation work is heavy] in the rice fields. Her daughter, together with A’s daughter, lives half there and half in the village. A’s son returns for a short time and then leaves again. Late May/June: A’s cousin and her daughter harvest rice and return to the village. They then go off to a village on the road to Dar es Salaam to visit her husband. Throughout this period, A would go to Dar es Salaam for a few days every month, where he acted as a rent collector for someone. The cousin’s husband would also come at weekends from the other village, where he was a teacher. (Lockwood Citation1998, 143 fn 1.)

The relationships and dependencies which through which domestic units exist in the first place, are themselves dynamic. Units may experience varied pressures as they take on tasks of educating children and young adults or providing migratory labour, or taking on new livelihoods (agriculture, urban occupations). The domestic unit which was configured around one set of assets, livelihoods and their social relations may have transformed into a differently structured and configured unit under new forms of livelihood, opportunity and constraint, whilst continuing to serve key roles as a site of socialisation, care and support.

When exploring change involving domestic units the stability of the unit becomes key. ‘Stability’ here does not refer simply to residential stasis, but to social relations within domestic units. Whitehead’s experience of working with ‘households’ in Northern Ghana provides a salutary example of the difficulties of comparing domestic units whose location remains the same, but whose developmental cycles have become so complex and convoluted that understanding how assets benefit different members cannot be understood without delving into the different components of the domestic unit. She describes, for example, (polygamously) married sons remaining with their (polygamously married) father in the same compound, and sometimes continuing to do so after their father had died. As a result:

Households could have several adults living in them and these adults included closely related married and single men, as well as polygamously married wives and the elderly widows of former male household members. This complex compound was an asset holding and cooperative work unit, although its physical, economic and social organization allowed for the possibility of overlapping circles of individual and collective responsibilities. (Whitehead Citation2006, 285)

The number of people living in these groups were large, with median household size being over 12 and ranging up to 73. Any assumption that domestic units remain sufficiently constant to compare over time is clearly ambitious in this case. Jane Guyer’s longitudinal study of change around Ibadan eschewed domestic units altogether because ‘people were mobile from one house to another, and their income earning, including farming, was individuated [so] at the pragmatic level of research method “the household” was unmanageable’ (Guyer Citation1997, 25).

It is possible therefore, that a domestic unit surveyed for one purpose, or at one particular moment, may not be the best vehicle to understand the relationships and dependencies around which different sorts of domestic units come to exist at a later time. Alternatively there may be so little stability, or even recognisability, in the constitution of domestic units from one period to the next that using domestic units when bounded by geographical location as a lens through which to view change simply makes no sense at all. They are too ephemeral. This is likely to be the case in Mathew Lockwood’s study site in Rufiji (Lockwood Citation1998). Housing structures might remain constant, but who lives in them, how they are related to each other, and, crucially, what assets bring which benefits to whom are too variable to be tracked over time.

Even if a once surveyed domestic unit ceases to exist, the relationships of dependence between individuals can still continue in ways largely invisible to the outsider using a survey tool. In 2004–2005, Mdee interviewed what she thought were several distinct households located around a public tap in the village of Uchira in Tanzania (Mdee Citationforthcoming). On marrying into one of those households, and over the course of several visits, she realised that these several households were in fact one domestic unit sharing blood relations, economic interests and assets. However, a survey of domestic units which assumed domestic units were constituted by housing units would have recorded two elderly female headed households, and two male headed households at different life stages. In fact, the ‘unit’ in the terms defined in this paper is constituted by relations of dependence, obligation and reciprocity that now extend across continents.

A variation of the scenario that Lockwood describes is that the amount of instability in social relations that make up domestic units varies within particular communities, and the degree of stability may be a contributing factor to the prosperity of the units. More stable units may experience more prosperity and derive more benefits from their assets. De Weerdt’s research on the Kagera panel study indicates as much (De Weerdt Citation2010). He used quantitative data to predict which households (as defined by the Kagera study) were more likely to lose and gain assets over time, and then focus group research to explore which households were bucking the expected trends (gaining assets when losses would have been predicted, and vice versa). This produced a number of characteristics that were typically missed by econometric analyses, including the importance of good co-operative relations between spouses for prosperity. Conversely, divorce could be particularly disadvantageous to women, as could widowhood in polygamous marriages.

In instances such as these the dynamism of domestic units becomes a means by which the fortunes of their members can be understood. Such longitudinal data cannot be organised by rows of ‘households’ in a spreadsheet – with obvious implications for panel data. Rather it is the changes to the definition and functioning of domestic units, and individuals within them, which becomes the focus for analysis. The domestic units become the dependent variable.

Once again the dynamism of the domestic units which come to exist around bundles of assets does not make exploration of asset dynamics impossible. That very dynamism, potentially visible through assets, can make exploring change in assets ever more important. Our point therefore is not that domestic units should not be used, just that they should be used carefully and, if necessary, re-defined, should the stability required for meaningful comparison simply be inadequate.

Exploring asset dynamics in longitudinal research

The broader value of following assets and the domestic units that manage them over time becomes clearer by putting them into the context of the larger, if somewhat niche, literature on longitudinal research. This work comprises, according to Vandergeest and Rigg (Citation2012, 11), restudies (of particular places), revisits (returning to specific people and domestic units), and panels (in which cohorts are recruited for repeated revisits). Panels tend to have shorter time intervals between their visits, whereas decades can elapse between revisits and restudies.

Longitudinal studies are niche because they are hard to do.Footnote2 Setting aside the methodological challenges, not many people are able to return to former study sites. It is hard enough undertaking one study, let alone finding the time and funding to return. Most of the best cases are from anthropology which is founded on deep commitments to particular places (Scoones Citation2015, 99).

Longitudinal studies, as Burawoy observed, have to cope with four types of change (Burawoy Citation2003). As well as the changes to internal dynamics and external pressures in the places studied that we have reported above, there are also changes to the researcher, and the theoretical contexts in which they are thinking. Vandergeest and Rigg neatly capture how in Asian and South East Asian research theoretical foci have shifted from self-contained ‘villages’ to ‘communities’ and to larger concerns of political economy.Footnote3 Revisits conducted now have to cope with the theoretical frames of earlier village contained baseline surveys (Vandergeest and Rigg Citation2012). Similarly earlier approaches may have used concepts like ‘household’ in ways which hid important dynamics. As Vandergeest and Rigg put it ‘there was [in our original studies] a tendency to expect individual voices to emerge, unbidden, from the household context’ (15).

Done well longitudinal research can offer exceptional insights, as two rather different studies illustrate. Li’s Land’s End (Citation2014) is based on nine visits (of up to several months) over a 19 year period to the same set of communities in Central Sulawesi. Her detailed and highly praised ethnography shows how exploitative capitalist relations and deprivation emerge from within, driven by endogenous desires for progress and change. Revisits to Palanpur, in India, every ten years for over fifty years (Bliss and Stern Citation1982; Lanjouw and Stern Citation1998; Himanshu, Lanjouw, and Stern Citation2018) has been lead by mainstream economists. These works are full of facts about income, assets, inequality, livelihoods and changing caste dynamics. The latest volume allows development economists the chance to reflect on how wrong theories were that had envisaged a shift of labour from rural economies to formal industrial employment. Contemporary livelihoods are much more precarious.Footnote4

However reviews of longitudinal studies highlight an unfortunate fact: they appear to be relatively rare in African research. White’s summary contains works from Asia, South-East Asia and Central America; Wolford adds examples from South America (White Citation2014; Wolford Citation2016).Footnote5 There are edited collections which compile longitudinal studies for India (Himanshu, Jha, and Rodgers Citation2016) and Southeast Asia (Rigg and Vandergeest Citation2012), but not Africa. The method is not as well used in African contests as it could be.

There are obvious exceptions. Caplan’s work in Mafia provides decades of insight built on strong persistent friendships, observation and conversation (Caplan Citation1997, Citation1992). Guyer’s An African Niche Economy studied change in the hinterland of Ibadan, Nigeria (Guyer Citation1997), to understand how farmers pursued careers within the constraints and opportunities that unfolded in the face of growing urban demand but restrictive national economic change. Mortimore’s seminal contribution to understanding adaptation to drought entailed a thirteen year study of a village in northern Nigeria (Mortimore Citation1989). The ‘AFRINT’ database has tracked four thousand farmers across nine countries with three visits since 2002 (Djurfeldt, Aryeetey, and Isinika Citation2011; Andersson-Djurfeldt, Dzanku, and Isinika Citation2018). Bill Kinsey and colleagues’s long term study of re-settlement in Zimbabwe provides unique insights into the consequences of land reform that stretch back over four decades (Hoogeveen and Kinsey Citation1999; Dekker and Kinsey Citation2011).

Other studies provide landscape scale studies of decades of changing prosperity. Tiffen, Mortimore’s and Gichuki’s More People Less Erosion (Citation1994) adopted a landscape scale approach documenting a rise in investment in the landscape – at the same time missing the exclusions and disadvantage that this change visited upon poorer domestic units within that landscape (Murton Citation1999). Moore and Vaughan’s remarkable re-study of Audrey Richards work in northern Zambia provides insights into 100 years of change across a large area, deliberately eschewing a village-based approach – partly because of the lack of precision that Richards herself provided on where she had worked (Moore and Vaughan Citation1994).

Shorter studies include Whitehead’s work, which we have already reported (Whitehead Citation2006). Mushonagh and Scoones examined changed meanings of wealth in one Zimbabwean village between 1986–1987 and 2006–2007 (Mushongah and Scoones Citation2012). They found, inter alia, that in 2006–2007 that cash had become less important for determining wealth, and health more important. A host of assets (house quality, solar panels, mobile phones) that had become elements of a wealthy lifestyle in the later survey that were absent in the 1980s. The Kagera restudy (Tanzania) provides remarkably detailed information in a region for which there is otherwise little historical data (De Weerdt Citation2010; Beegle, De Weerdt, and Dercon Citation2011). There are also some useful panel datasets from Ethiopia (Dercon Citation2006; Dercon et al. Citation2009; Liverpool-Tasiea and Winter-Nelson Citation2011; Dercon, Hoddinott, and Woldehanna Citation2012). These are characterised by their tendency to focus on the qualities of domestic units and individuals, and quantitative analyses of the same, and pay less attention to the politics of poverty creation and reduction (Harris Citation2009).

The value of following assets over time in longitudinal research is that it may provide a means of furnishing more insights in African contexts to places where there are few reliable data. This possibility is evident in summaries of some of the findings of a recently completed project which combined several longitudinal surveys in Tanzania.Footnote6 This work, like Rigg and Vandergeest, entailed identifying researchers who had worked in the country in the 1980s to early 2000s and then organising a series of revisits.

In a companion paper to this issue we present one of the more detailed case studies, which describes change to the village of Mtowisa in southwest Tanzania where Dan Brockington lived in 1999–2000 (Brockington Citation2019b). This village had once been remote, but well-endowed with fertile soils and ample lands. Its residents considered themselves poor. Their houses were small and rudimentary, most cultivated only two acres, and few used ploughs. But by 2016 the village had transformed with a busy market centre, motorbike taxis for hire, frequent bus services and solar-powered electricity. There was a mobile phone tower with good service. Within the village, housing quality had markedly improved.

During the return visit Dan Brockington was able to identify many of the people and domestic units from his previous survey. Most were better off as there had been substantial investment in assets (houses, oxen, pigs and ploughs) following a shift to commercially valuable crops. However, while individuals and domestic units who were present in 2000 appear to have prospered, the village population as a whole has not seen such a shift. This is because immigration into the village has brought more poorer domestic units (attracted by the cheap rental accommodation that sesame farmers built, and the labour it afforded). In addition the land frontier has closed making it harder for the youth of this village to acquire land and establish themselves.

Monique Borgerhoff-Mulder was based in Pimbwe, also in southwest Tanzania, a society which is characterised by high levels of instability in the form of migration and divorce (Borgerhoff-Mulder Citationforthcoming). However she was able to circumvent these difficulties by dint of effort, visiting the same community seven times over a 15 year period and conducting an entire village census on each occasion. She shows clearly that there has been a significant improvement in different types of assets for most domestic units. She shows that improvement in assets is, in this instance, well correlated with other measures of well-being, such as farm productivity, decreased stress, education and health. She also shows that significant levels of poverty remain. Borgerhoff-Mulder notes that she cannot extrapolate her findings beyond this village – they demonstrate the importance of detailed case studies, not a broader rule.

Wilhelm Östberg’s work in Dodoma began in the mid-1990s with one of the poorer and more remote communities in the country where farming had been characterised by extended fallows in plentiful woodland (Östberg Citation1995; Slegers and Östberg Citation2008; Östberg and Slegers Citation2010; Östberg et al. Citation2018). He too returned in 2016 to find villages transformed by their buildings, road connections and infrastructure. People were farming larger farms (growing sunflower as a cash crop) and the physical capital (especially watering points) of the village were much improved courtesy of the philanthropy (and business activity) of local entrepreneurs who had built public dams and used their tractors to transport and sell water. It was possible to trace individual domestic units and trace changes in asset bases, and explain those changes due to transformations in farming activity. Once again, assets only cover aspects of the dynamics that matter, as there has also been a transformation to the tree cover in the area which has substantially declined as farms have expanded. This was viewed locally to be associated with more precarious weather patterns.

Christine Noe’s study of Meru villages provided a particularly interesting re-study because she built on one of the largest samples taken (over 600 domestic units from seven villages). Christine did not conduct the original work; that had been undertaken by Rolf Larsson who tragically died en route to conduct an early return visit in 2004. Christine, however, was born and bred in Meru in a village neighbouring Larson’s study sites. Tracing changing assets through individual domestic units provided a useful lens for understanding changing forms and meanings of prosperity. This area has suffered from the collapse of the coffee economy, which had made it one of the most prosperous in the country (Larsson Citation2001), but this did not cause the poverty we had expected (Howland, Brockington, and Noe Citationforthcoming). The authors show that asset bases were reduced following population growth and the demise of coffee, but the meaning of both poverty and prosperity had changed. Wealth was no longer signified by coffee, but instead through accessing urban markets with small businesses and market gardening. Moreover women, on whose labour coffee had depended, but whose proceeds they had not controlled, welcomed the decline of the coffee economy. It freed their labour to focus on activities which they were better able to control. Understanding the change in assets that domestic units experienced required examining how that change was experienced by different individuals within those domestic units.

Ponte’s work in Morogoro provides an interesting case because of the disputes which surrounded his first work there (Van Donge Citation1992; Ponte Citation2001; Ponte Citation2002; Van Donge Citation2002). Van Donge had disputed the findings of Ponte’s first survey (in the mid-1990s) because he felt Ponte painted too optimistic a picture and had failed to spot the agricultural involution which Van Donge foretold. The revisit in 2016 seemed to re-confirm Ponte’s earlier arguments (Ponte and Brockington Citationforthcoming). There are no signs of involution and decline as Van Donge had predicted. Instead, by tracing domestic units and their investment in assets Ponte can identify different trajectories of change, from decline (particularly associated with age and illness) to stasis, to substantial improvement (associated with agricultural investment). Substantial improvements in livelihoods in this area are also confirmed by other separate research by one of the present authors (Mdee et al. Citation2018).

Finally, Anna Mdee’s work in Uchira, Kilimanjaro, demonstrates that the general improvement in assets that we have documented in these sites is not a nation-wide phenomenon (Mdee Citationforthcoming). It is patchily experienced – and in all these cases derives from different causes which unfolded at different times. In Uchira the growth in assets is generally absent. In this village there has been little improvement in agriculture, if anything changing climatic patterns (more erratic rainfall and a switch from bimodal to unimodal rainfall) has seen farming become less productive for most, while the wider economy of the village has not recovered from the collapse of cattle markets in the early 2000s. Instead, improvements in assets where they are seen tend to rely on migration and remittance through dispersed kin networks.

Assets, progress and change

Ben White, in his review of Revisting Rural Places captures well the dangers of longitudinal research. They are certainly pleasurable and exciting for the researcher but

however promising, many re-studies are ultimately disappointing, showing us ‘then it was like that, now it is like this’ but unable to tell us much more about how and why things changed, or how these changes have been experienced. To be useful, they must go beyond the presentation of contrasting snapshots or time slices to the more demanding project of writing rural social history, focusing on the processes and mechanisms, rather than just the ‘facts’ and outcomes, of rural change. (White Citation2014, 635)

We do not dispute this point. But for longitudinal studies to be taken seriously, there must be room for some more empirically focussed approaches. As we observe in a companion paper (Brockington Citation2019b), sometimes the facts are disputed, or obscured by techniques used to track change. We need to get a clear understanding of who gets what, or who owns what, as well as what do they do with it (following Bernstein Citation2010) to understand the role of assets (and not just land ownership) in class dynamics. That means knowing what the ‘what’ is.

In our case studies the assets we examined are also particularly important for understanding situated class dynamics. For example, change in Gitting, the example with which we began, was locally explained by the decline in ‘capitalism’ (Swahili: ubepare). This was a reference to a broadening of the control over the means of production which had seen ploughs, oxen and eventually tractors spread from a restricted number of individuals who charged extortionate fees for their use. Greater equality in asset ownership, through local investment, resulted in a general rise in prosperity. As we will show in the companion paper (Brockington Citation2019b), it is precisely this form of investment that poverty line data omit.

But the opposite proved to be the case in Dodoma, where Östberg worked. Here wealthy entrepreneurs’ tractors are new arrivals and essential to the larger farms that people are now working. Investment in shared water points has also reduced labour (particularly women’s work) in collecting water. Greater inequality, in the form of relatively benevolent wealthy businessmen, has been key to raising productivity generally. The changes to the village have also seen a change in the meaning of daily labour from being solely a sign of penury and disadvantage to also signifying, in some circumstances, the ability to invest in particular projects.

However, while greater attention to assets can provide more sensitive insights into local level class dynamics it is also possible for attention to assets to be used in ways which obscure change. In tandem with this burgeoning interest in measuring assets lies a significant danger of the ‘seduction of quantification’ (Merry Citation2016), with the push to quantify, track and compare complex social phenomena.

Specifically there is a danger that one or two assets become proxies for ‘prosperity’. For example, if the use of iron sheeting as a roofing material (which is helpfully visible to remote sensing) denotes progress (Jean et al. Citation2016; Watmough et al. Citation2019), then policy and resources might shift to fulfil this indicator. However, changes to the roofing of a dwelling can conceal all sorts of changes in the social lives of those living in it, and may not be linked to the ‘prosperity’ of the individuals living under it. Thus a single asset used as an indicator could conceal important dynamics, and become as a proxy for a normative concept (that iron sheeted roofing makes a better home).

This is a persistent tension in the quest for simple quantification in development metrics. For example, Sustainable Development Goal target 5a states a commitment to:

[u]ndertake reforms to give women equal rights to economic resources, as well as access to ownership and control over land and other forms of property, financial services, inheritance and natural resources, in accordance with national laws.

The specific indicators of 5.a.1 are (a) the proportion of total agricultural population with ownership or secure rights over agricultural land, by sex; and (b) the share of women among owners or rights-bearers of agricultural land, by type of tenure.

The choice of such asset-based indicators is not just a methodological problem, it has consequences in the policies that are adopted or promoted. For example, the formalisation of land titling measures, albeit crudely disaggregated by sex, pays little attention to the complex configurations of asset accumulation and use in the dynamic domestic unit. But the apparent consensus around formal land titling drives policy change, with potentially deleterious consequences for the poorest (Maganga et al. Citation2016).

If assets can be incorporated into national measures of well-being (cf Brandolini, Magri, and Smeeding Citation2010), it is important to understand how such changes might be grounded in specific instances in the lived experiences of particular domestic units in different places. General measures of change in assets across regions or countries may be based in very different experiences of the distribution and enjoyment of those assets in particular places. There remains a strong role for locally based and well-grounded research that can contextualise such change.

Conclusion

We began with an apparently straightforward account of simple changes, and improvements, in people’s lives that are measurable and locally meaningful because they detail changes that matter, for which people strive. We have shown that this improvement actually entails two claims – that people are richer in terms of their assets, and that the social units holding these assets are sufficiently stable for that comparison to be warranted.

It seems, from these data and existing literature, increasingly important to take into consideration emic conceptualisations of domestic units and asset ownership. Without this, we are merely imposing an etic and often Eurocentric view, of what a ‘household’ should look like, on local settings where the reality might be quite different. Without some understanding of the complex cultural context of asset-owning units, we are attempting to make a comparison of something which is meaningless to people in its original context.

Tracking change over time requires sufficient constancy in the unit of measurement. And if the individuals, households, or communities we are interested in effectively disappear, then we cannot make statements about change over time at those scales, and we may not be able to compare different places for which data at particular scales no longer exist. Or, to make this point another way: there are some aspects of the world which are unknowable or unmeasureable because of the ways that they are constituted and because of the ways in which they change.

The challenge of research in development is to push the boundaries between what can be known, and what cannot. We believe that tracing assets through domestic units does indeed push the boundaries of our knowledge and understanding of social change, but only if the limitations of what we can learn from assets, and how we treat domestic units, are taken seriously. Attempts to use assets as proxies for change without due care will miss the social contexts that make assets meaningful in the first place. As the consequences of land loss and economic investment strategies are vigorously debated we encourage more researchers to use this sort of longitudinal approach to understand change in rural areas. However progress in understanding will only be achieved if researchers recognise the heterogeneity of change and the critical importance of local context and conditions, often at small scales.

Acknowledgements

The authors gratefully acknowledge the support of the DfID ESRC Growth Research Programme (ES/L012413/2) which has funded this research project and of the Research Council of Norway which has supported this work through the Greenmentality project. We are grateful for the support of the ODI and in particular the critical engagement of Steve Wiggins and Louise Shaxson throughout. Many thanks to the anonymous reviewers for their hard work and critical commentary.

Disclosure statement

No potential conflict of interest was reported by the authors.

Dan Brockington directs the Sheffield Institute of International Development. He studied for his thesis at University College London with Kathy Homewood and has worked on aspects of natural resource management and livelihood change in East Africa based on long term fieldwork in remote locations. His books include Celebrity Advocacy and International Development, Fortress Conservation and Nature Unbound (with Rosaleen Duffy and Jim Igoe). He has recently published (with Peter Billie Larson) The Anthropology of Conservation NGOs.

Ernestina Coast is Professor of Health and International Development at the London School of Economics and Political Science. Her research is multidisciplinary and she is a social scientist with training in demography and anthropology. Her research uses mixed methods (quantitative and qualitative) and has two main foci: the production and consumption of evidence for policy; and sexual and reproductive health and rights.

Olivia Howland an ethnographer, anthropologist, painter and professional gypsy, with roots in the English traveller community. She gained her PhD in 2016 in Applied Anthropology, and has been based in East Africa for the past 12 years. Olivia’s home is in rural Kenya, which she built in 2012, on the side of a very beautiful mountain. She currently works in Kenya and is a researcher by day on a project for the University of Liverpool.

Anna Mdee is Associate Professor in International Development at the University of Leeds. She is a social anthropologist working on the aid industry, livelihoods and local governance, primarily in Tanzania. She has a particular focus on water governance and work in Tanzanian villages with members of her extended family.

Sara Randall was trained in demography at the London School of Hygiene and Tropical Medicine and has worked in the University College London Anthropology department since 1991. Along with understanding the demographic dynamics of rural West African populations her recent research focuses on using anthropological approaches to unpicking and understanding concepts, data and metrics used in quantitative data collection and analyses and thus for policy making.

Additional information

Funding

This work was supported by Economic and Social Research Council: [grant number ES/L012413/2].

Notes

1 We are mainly concerned in this paper with tangible assets that can be bought, used and sold because we are interested in the social units that are engaged in the processes of acquiring and distributing them. This means that we will use a more restrictive definition of assets.

2 One indication of their rarity is that recent edited collections to this genre use the method in their title. Their authors know it will distinguish them. We are thinking of The Changing Village in India, Insights from Longitudinal Research (Himanshu, Jha, and Rodgers Citation2016) and Revisiting Rural Places (Rigg and Vandergeest Citation2012). The other marker of their rarity is that there are few other collections like these.

3 The village frame is clearly visible in some longitudinal works – such as Epstein’s (Epstein Citation1973; Epstein, Suryanarayana, and Thimmegowda Citation1998).

4 This was Stern’s response to Dan Brockington’s question to him at a book launch of How Lives Change. Brockington asked him what was the biggest surprise of seven decades of study of one village. He replied that the surprise for him was learning how wrong Arthur Lewis’ theories of development were. Lewis had posited a switch to formal manufacturing employment as labour is released from agriculture. In Palanpur, labour is being released, but to informal employment (Himanshu, Lanjouw, and Stern Citation2018, 447).

5 White, reviewing Rigg and Vandergeest’s edited collection (Citation2012) invoked several other studies (Eder Citation2000; Pincus Citation1996; Redfield Citation1950; Castañeda Citation1995) (Epstein Citation1973; Epstein, Suryanarayana, and Thimmegowda Citation1998). Wolford, reviewing Li’s work (Citation2014) mentioned (Ortiz Citation1999; Stolcke Citation1988).

6 The research on Gitting with which we began has triggered a broader research effort to develop more longitudinal case studies which examined change over time in different villages. See Brockington (Citation2019a) for more details about this project.

References

  • Adato, Michelle, Michael R. Carter, and Julian May. 2006. “Exploring Poverty Traps and Social Exclusion in South Africa Using Qualitative and Quantitative Data.” Journal of Development Studies 42 (2): 226–247. doi: 10.1080/00220380500405345
  • Adato, M., Francie Lund, and Phakama Mhlongo. 2007. “Methodological Innovations in Research on the Dynamics of Poverty: A Longitudinal Study in KwaZulu-Natal, South Africa.” World Development 35 (2): 247–263. doi: 10.1016/j.worlddev.2006.10.003
  • Andersson-Djurfeldt, Agnes, Fred Mawunyo Dzanku, and Aida Cuthbert Isinika. 2018. Agriculture, Diversification and Gender in Rural Africa. Longitudinal Perspectives from Six Countries. Oxford: OUP.
  • Barrett, Christopher B., Michael R. Carter, and Peter D. Little. 2006. “Understanding and Reducing Persistent Poverty in Africa: Introduction to a Special Issue.” Journal of Development Studies 42 (2): 167–177. doi: 10.1080/00220380500404587
  • Barrett, Christopher, Teevrat Garg, and Linden McBride. 2016. “Well-being Dynamics and Poverty Traps.” Centre for Climate Change Economics and Policy Working Paper No. 250.
  • Beegle, Kathleen, Joachim De Weerdt, and Stefan Dercon. 2011. “Migration and Economic Mobility in Tanzania: Evidence from a Tracking Survey.” Review of Economics and Statistics 93 (3): 1010–1033. doi: 10.1162/REST_a_00105
  • Behnke, Roy H., and Ian Scoones. 1993. “Rethinking Range Ecology: Implications for Rangeland Management in Africa.” In Range Ecology at Disequilibrium. New Models of Natural Variability and Pastoral Adaptation in African Savannas, edited by R. H. Behnke, I. Scoones, and C. Kerven, 1–30. London: ODI.
  • Bernstein, Henry. 2010. Class Dynamics of Agrarian Change. Halifx and Winnipeg: Fernwood Publishing.
  • Bliss, C. J., and Nicholas H. Stern. 1982. Palanpur: The Economy of an Indian Village. Oxford: Clarendon Press.
  • Booysen, Frikkie, Ronelle Burger Servaas van der Berg, and Michael von Maltitz. 2008. “Using an Asset Index to Assess Trends in Poverty in Seven Sub-Saharan African Countries.” World Development 36 (6): 1113–1130. doi: 10.1016/j.worlddev.2007.10.008
  • Borgerhoff-Mulder, M. forthcoming. “Tracing the Relationships Between Assets and Well-Being in Complex Social Environments.” In Prosperity in Rural Africa? Insights from Longitudinal Studies in Tanzania, edited by Dan Brockington and Christine Noe. Oxford: OUP.
  • Brandolini, Andrea, Silvia Magri, and Timothy M. Smeeding. 2010. “Asset-Based Measurement of Poverty.” Journal of Policy Analysis and Management 29 (2): 267–284. doi: 10.1002/pam.20491
  • Broch-Due, Vigdis. 1990. “Livestock Speak Louder Than Sweet Words: Changing Property and Gender Relations among the Turkana.” In Property, Poverty and People: Changing Rights in Property and The Problems of Pastoral Development, edited by P. T. W. Baxter and R. Hogg, 147–163. Manchester: Manchester University Press.
  • Brockington, Dan. 2019a. Accessed August 15, 2019. http://livelihoodchangeta.wixsite.com/tanzania/project-summary.
  • Brockington, Dan. 2019b. “Persistent Peasant Poverty and Assets. Exploring Dynamics of New Forms of Wealth and Poverty in Tanzania 1999–2018.” Journal of Peasant Studies. doi:10.1080/03066150.2019.1658081.
  • Brockington, Dan, Olivia Howland, Vesa-Mati Loiske, Moses Mnzava, and Christine Noe. 2018. “Economic Growth, Rural Assets and Prosperity: Exploring the Implications of a 20-Year Record of Asset Growth in Tanzania.” Journal of Modern African Studies 56 (2): 217–243. doi: 10.1017/S0022278X18000186
  • Burawoy, Michael. 2003. “Revisits: An Outline of a Theory of Reflexive Ethnography.” American Sociological Review 68 (October): 645–679. doi: 10.2307/1519757
  • Caplan, Pat. 1992. “Socialism from Above: The View from Below.” In The Tanzanian Peasantry: Economy in Crisis, edited by Peter G. Forster and Sam Maghimbi, 103–123. Aldershot: Avebury.
  • Caplan, Pat. 1997. African Voices, African Lives: Personal Narratives from a Swahili Village. Abingdon: Routledge.
  • Carter, M. R., and C. B. Barrett. 2006. “The Economics of Poverty Traps and Persistent Poverty: An Asset-Based Approach.” Journal of Development Studies 42 (2): 178–199. doi: 10.1080/00220380500405261
  • Carter, Michael R., and Travis J. Lybbert. 2012. “Consumption Versus Asset Smoothing: Testing the Implications of Poverty Trap Theory in Burkina Faso.” Journal of Development Economics 99: 255–264. doi: 10.1016/j.jdeveco.2012.02.003
  • Castañeda, Q. E. 1995. “‘The Progress that Chose a Village’: Measuring Zero-Degree Culture and the ‘Impact’ of Anthropology.” Critique of Anthropology 15 (2): 115–147. doi: 10.1177/0308275X9501500201
  • Chayanov, Alexander V. 1991 (1927). The Theory of Peasant Co-Operatives. Introduction by Victor Danilov. Columbus, OH: Ohio State University Press.
  • De Waal, A. 1989. Famine that Kills. Darfur, Sudan, 1984–1985. Oxford: Clarendon Press.
  • De Weerdt, Joachim. 2010. “Moving Out of Poverty in Tanzania: Evidence from Kagera.” Journal of Development Studies 46 (2): 331–349. doi: 10.1080/00220380902974393
  • Deaton, Angus. 2004. “Measuring Poverty.” Princeton Research Program in Development Studies Working Paper. SSRN: https://ssrn.com/abstract=564001 or http://dx.doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.564001.
  • Dekker, Marleen, and Bill Kinsey. 2011. “Contextualizing Zimbabwe’s Land Reform: Long-Term Observations from the First Generation.” Journal of Peasant Studies 38 (5): 995–1019. doi:10.1080/03066150.2011.632089.
  • Dercon, Stefan. 2006. “Economic Reform, Growth and the Poor: Evidence from Rural Ethiopia.” Journal of Development Economics 81: 1–24. doi: 10.1016/j.jdeveco.2005.05.008
  • Dercon, Stefan, Daniel O. Gilligan, John Hoddinott, and Tassew Woldehanna. 2009. “The Impact of Agricultural Extension and Roads on Poverty and Consumption Growth in Fifteen Ethiopian Villages.” American Journal of Agricultural Economics 91 (4): 1007–1021. doi: 10.1111/j.1467-8276.2009.01325.x
  • Dercon, Stefan, John Hoddinott, and Tassew Woldehanna. 2012. “Growth and Chronic Poverty: Evidence from Rural Communities in Ethiopia.” Journal of Development Studies 48 (2): 238–253. doi: 10.1080/00220388.2011.625410
  • Djurfeldt, Goran, Ernest Aryeetey, and Aida C. Isinika. 2011. African Smallholders. Food Crops, Markets and Policy. Wallingford: CABI.
  • Eder, J. 2000. A Generation Later: Household Strategies and Economic Change in the Rural Philippines. Quezon City: Ateneo de Manila University Press.
  • Ellis, Frank. 2000. “The Determinants of Rural Livelihood Diversification in Developing Countries.” Journal of Agricultural Economics 51 (2): 289–302. doi: 10.1111/j.1477-9552.2000.tb01229.x
  • Epstein, T. S. 1973. South India: Yesterday, Today and Tomorrow. Mysore Villages Revisited. London: Macmillan.
  • Epstein, Scarlett, A. P. Suryanarayana, and T. Thimmegowda. 1998. Village Voices: Forty Years of Rural Transformation in South India. Londonq: Sage.
  • Ferguson, James. 2013. “How to Do Things with Land: A Distributive Perspective on Rural Livelihoods in Southern Africa.” Journal of Agrarian Change 13 (1): 166–174. doi: 10.1111/j.1471-0366.2012.00363.x
  • Ferguson, James. 2015. Give a Man a Fish: Reflections on the New Politics of Distribution. Durham, NC: Duke University Press.
  • Fortes, Meyer. 1958. “Introduction.” In The Developmental Cycle in Domestic Groups, edited by Jack Goody, 1–14. Cambridge: CUP.
  • Goody, Jack. 1958. The Developmental Cycle in Domestic Groups. Cambridge: CUP.
  • Guyer, Jane. 1981. “Household and Community in African Studies.” African Studies Review 24 (2/3): 81–137. doi: 10.2307/523903
  • Guyer, Jane L. 1997. An African Niche Economy. Farming to Feed Ibadan 1968–88. Edinburgh: Edinburgh University Press.
  • Harris, John. 2009. “Bringing Politics Back Into Poverty Analysis: why Understandings of Social Relations Matters More for Policy on Chronic Poverty Than Measurement.” In Poverty Dynamics: Interdisciplinary Perspectives, edited by Tony Addison, David Hulme, and Ravi Kanbur, 205–224. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
  • Harttgen, Kenneth, Stephen Klasen, and Sebastian Vollmer. 2013. “An African Growth Miracle? Or: What Do Asset Indices Tell Us about Trends in Economic Performance?” Review of Income and Wealth 59 (Special Issue, Oct 2013): s37–s61. doi: 10.1111/roiw.12016
  • Himanshu, Praveen Jha, and Gerry Rodgers. 2016. The Changing Village in India: Insights from Longitudinal Research. Oxford: OUP.
  • Himanshu, Peter Lanjouw, and Nicholas H. Stern. 2018. How Lives Change. Palanpur, India and Development Economics. Oxford: OUP.
  • Hoogeveen, Johannes G., and Bill Kinsey. 1999. “Land Reform, Growth and Equity: Emerging Evidence from Zimbabwe’s Resettlement Programme - A Sequel.” Journal of Southern African Studies 27 (1): 127–136. doi: 10.1080/03057070120029536
  • Howe, Laura, Bruna Galobardes, Alicia Matijasevich, David Gordon, Deborah Johnston, Obinna Onwujekwe, Rita Patel, Elizabeth A. Webb, Debbie A. Lawlor, and James R. Hargreaves. 2012. “Measuring Socio-Economic Position for Epidemiological Studies in Low- and Middle-Income Countries: A Methods of Measurement in Epidemiology Paper.” International Journal of Epidemiology 41 (3): 871–886. doi: 10.1093/ije/dys037
  • Howe, Laura, James Hargreaves, Sabine Gabrysch, and Sharon Huttly. 2009. “Is the Wealth Index a Proxy for Consumption Expenditure? A Systematic Review.” Journal of Epidemiology and Community Health 63 (11): 871–877. doi: 10.1136/jech.2009.088021
  • Howland, Olivia, Dan Brockington, and Christine Noe. forthcoming. “Women’s Tears or Coffee Blight? Gender Dynamics and Livelihood Strategies in Contexts of Agricultural Transformation in Tanzania.” Agrarian South: Journal of Political Economy. doi:10.1080/03066150.2019.1658080.
  • Howland, Olivia, Christine Noe, and Dan Brockington. 2019. “The Multiple Meanings of Prosperity and Poverty. A Cross-Site Comparison from Tanzania.” Journal of Peasant Studies. Advance Published online.
  • Hyden, G. 1983. No Shortcut to Progress: African Development in Perspective. Berkeley: University of California Press.
  • Hyden, G. 2015. “The Economy of Affection.” In Routledge Handbook of African Politics, edited by N. Cheeseman, D. Anderson, and R. Scheibler, 334–345. Abingdon: Routledge.
  • Jean, Neal, Marshall Burke, Michael Xie, W. Matthew Davis, David B. Lobell, and Stefano Ermon. 2016. “Combining Satellite Imagery and Machine Learning to Predict Poverty.” Science 353 (6301): 790–794. doi: 10.1126/science.aaf7894
  • Johnson, Nancy L., Chiara Kovarika, Ruth Meinzen-Dick, Jemimah Njuki B., and Agnes Quisumbing. 2016. “Gender, Assets, and Agricultural Development: Lessons from Eight Projects.” World Development 83: 295–231. doi: 10.1016/j.worlddev.2016.01.009
  • Johnston, D., and Alexandre Abreu. 2016. “The Asset Debates: How (Not) to Use Asset Indices to Measure Well-Being and the Middle Class in Africa.” African Affairs 115 (460): 399–418. doi: 10.1093/afraf/adw019
  • Lanjouw, Peter, and Nicholas H. Stern. 1998. Economic Development in Palanpur Over Five Decades. Oxford: Clarendon Press.
  • Larsson, Rolf. 2001. Between Crisis and Opportunity. Livelihoods, Diversification and Inequality among the Meru of Tanzania. Lund: Lund University.
  • Li, Tania Murray. 2014. Land’s End. Capialist Relations on an Indigenous Frontier. Durham: Duke University Press.
  • Liverpool-Tasiea, Lenis Saweda O., and Alex Winter-Nelson. 2011. “Asset Versus Consumption Poverty and Poverty Dynamics in Rural Ethiopia.” Agricultural Economics 42: 221–233. doi: 10.1111/j.1574-0862.2010.00479.x
  • Lockwood, Matthew. 1998. Fertility and Household Labour in Tanzania: Demography, Economy, and Society in Rufiji District, C. 1870–1986. Oxford: OUP.
  • Maganga, F. P., K. Askew, R. Odgaard, and H. Stein. 2016. “Dispossession Through Formalization: Tanzania and the G8 Land Agenda in Africa.” Asian Journal of African Studies 40: 3–49.
  • Mdee, Anna. forthcoming. “The Urbanising Frontier, Change and Continuity: Uchira 1996–2018.” In Prosperity in Rural Africa? Insights from Longitudinal Studies in Tanzania, edited by Dan Brockington and Christine Noe. Oxford: OUP.
  • Mdee, Anna, Alex Wostry, Andrew Coulson, and Janet Maro. 2018. “A Pathway to Inclusive Sustainable Intensification in Agriculture? Assessing Evidence on the Application of Agroecology in Tanzania.” Agroecology and Sustainable Food Systems 43 (2): 201–227. doi:10.1080/21683565.2018.1485126.
  • Meinzen-Dick, Ruth, Nancy Johnson, Agnes Quisumbing, Jemimah Njuki, Julia Behrman, Deborah Rubin, Amber Peterman, and Elizabeth Waithanji. 2011. “Gender, Assets, and Agricultural Development Programs. A Conceptual Framework.” CAPRi Working Paper No. 99.
  • Merry, S. E. 2016. The Seductions of Quantification: Measuring Human Rights, Gender Violence, and Sex Trafficking. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
  • Moore, Henrietta L., and Megan Vaughan. 1994. Cutting Down Trees. Gender Nutrition and Agricultural Change in the Northern Province of Zambia, 1890–1990. Portsmouth, NH: Heinemann.
  • Mortimore, Michael. 1989. Adapting to Drought. Farmers, Famines and Desertification in West Africa. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
  • Murray, Colin. 1987. “Class, Gender and the Household: The Developmental Cycle in Southern Africa.” Development and Change 18: 235–249. doi: 10.1111/j.1467-7660.1987.tb00271.x
  • Murton, John. 1999. “Population Growth and Poverty in Machakos District, Kenya.” The Geographical Journal 165 (1): 37–46. doi: 10.2307/3060509
  • Mushongah, Josphat, and Ian Scoones. 2012. “Livelihood Change in Rural Zimbabwe Over 20 Years.” Journal of Development Studies 48 (9): 1241–1257. doi: 10.1080/00220388.2012.671474
  • Narayan, Deepa. 2000. Voices of the Poor. Can Anyone Hear Us? Washington, DC: World Bank.
  • Naschold, Felix. 2012. “‘The Poor Stay Poor’: Household Asset Poverty Traps in Rural Semi-Arid India.” World Development 40 (10): 2033–2043. doi: 10.1016/j.worlddev.2012.05.006
  • Ortiz, S. 1999. Harvesting Coffee, Bargaining Wages: Rural Labor Markets in Colombia, 1975–1990. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.
  • Östberg, W. 1995. Land is Coming Up: The Burunge of Central Tanzania and their Environments. Stockholm: Stockholm Studies in Social Anthropology, Stockholm University.
  • Östberg, W., O. Howland, J. Mduma, and D. Brockington. 2018. “Tracing Improving Livelihoods in Rural Africa Using Local Measures of Wealth: A Case Study from Central Tanzania, 1991–2016.” Land 7 (44): 1–26.
  • Östberg, W., and M. F. W. Slegers. 2010. “Losing Faith in the Land: Changing Environmental Perceptions in Burunge Country, Tanzania.” Journal of Eastern African Studies 4 (2): 247–265. doi: 10.1080/17531055.2010.487335
  • Pincus, J. 1996. Class, Power and Agrarian Change. London: Macmillan.
  • Pogge, T. 2005. “The First UN Millennium Development Goal: A Cause for Celebration?” In Real World Justice. Grounds, Principles, Human Rights and Social Institutions, edited by A. Follesdal and T. Pogge, 317–338. Dordrecht: Springer.
  • Ponte, S. 2001. “Trapped in Decline? Reassessing Agrarian Change and Economic Diversification on the Uluguru Mountains, Tanzania.” The Journal of Modern African Studies 39 (1): 81–100. doi: 10.1017/S0022278X01003536
  • Ponte, S. 2002. “Reply to van Donge.” The Journal of Modern African Studies 40 (2): 313–320. doi: 10.1017/S0022278X02003932
  • Ponte, Stefano, and Dan Brockington. forthcoming. “From Pyramid to Pointed Egg? A Twenty-Year Perspective on Poverty, Prosperity and Rural Transformation in Tanzania.” African Affairs.
  • Randall, Sara, and Ernestina Coast. 2015. “Poverty in African Households: The Limits of Survey and Census Representations.” The Journal of Development Studies 51 (2): 162–177. doi: 10.1080/00220388.2014.968135
  • Randall, Sara, Ernestina Coast, and Tiziana Leone. 2011. “Cultural Constructions of the Concept of Household in Sample Surveys.” Population Studies 65 (2): 217–229. doi: 10.1080/00324728.2011.576768
  • Redfield, R. 1950. Chan Kom: A Village that Chose Progress. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
  • Rigg, J., and P. Vandergeest. 2012. Revisiting Rural Places: Pathways to Poverty and Prosperity in Southeast Asia. Singapore: NUS Press.
  • Sahn, David E., and David C. Stifel. 2000. “Poverty Comparisons Over Time and Across Countries in Africa.” World Development 28 (12): 2123–2155. doi: 10.1016/S0305-750X(00)00075-9
  • Scoones, Ian. 1998. “Sustainable Rural Livelihoods: A Framework for Analysis.” IDS Working Paper 72. IDS, Sussex.
  • Scoones, Ian. 2015. Sustainable Livelihoods and Rural Development. Rugby: Practical Action Publishing.
  • Scott, Lucy. 2010. Giving Assets: An Effective Approach for Reducing Vulnerability and Building Livelihoods? The Case of the Chars Livelihoods Programme. PhD. Diss. The University of Manchester.
  • Sen, A. 1999. Development as Freedom. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
  • Slegers, M. F. W., and W. Östberg. 2008. “The Strength of the Land and the Missing Rains. Environmental Change in Goima, Tanzania, and Farmers’ Growing Concerns.” In Exploring Farmers’ Perceptions of Drought in Tanzania and Ethiopia, edited by M. F. W. Slegers, 129–150. Wageningen: Wageningen University: Erosion and Soil & Water Conservation Group.
  • Stenning, J. 1958. “Household Viability among the Pastoral Fulani Derrick.” In The Developmental Cycle in Domestic Groups, edited by Jack Goody, 92–119. Cambridge: CUP.
  • Stolcke, V. 1988. Coffee Planters, Workers, and Wives: Class Conflict and Gender Relations on São Paulo Plantations, 1850–1980. New York: St. Martin’s Press.
  • Tiffen, M., M. Mortimore, and F. Gichuki. 1994. More People, Less Erosion: Environmental Recovery in Kenya. Chichester: John Wiley.
  • Van Donge, J. K. 1992. “Agricultural Decline in Tanzania: The Case of the Uluguru Mountains.” African Affairs 91: 73–94. doi: 10.1093/afraf/91.362.73
  • Van Donge, J. K. 2002. “Trading Images? A Comment on Ponte’s Reassessment of Agrarian Change in the Uluguru Mountains.” The Journal of Modern African Studies 40 (2): 303–311. doi: 10.1017/S0022278X02003920
  • Vandergeest, Peter, and Jonathan Rigg. 2012. “The Restudy ‘Problem’ and Agrairan Change: Revisiting Rural Places in Southeast Asia.” In Revisiting Rural Places: Pathways to Poverty and Prosperity in Southeast Asia, edited by Jonathan Rigg and Peter Vandergeest, 1–24. Singapore: Singapore University Press and Hawaii University Press.
  • Watmough, Gary R., Charlotte L. J. Marcinko, Clare Sullivan, Kevin Tschirhart, Patrick K. Mutuo, Cheryl A. Palm, and Jens-Christian Svenning. 2019. “Socioecologically Informed Use of Remote Sensing Data to Predict Rural Household Poverty.” Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences. www.pnas.org/cgi/doi/10.1073/pnas.1812969116.
  • White, Ben. 2014. “Revisiting Rural Places: Pathways to Poverty and Prosperity in Southeast Asia.” The Journal of Peasant Studies 41 (4): 635–638. doi: 10.1080/03066150.2014.924680
  • Whitehead, Ann. 2006. “Persistent Poverty in North East Ghana.” Journal of Development Studies 42 (2): 278–300. doi: 10.1080/00220380500405410
  • Wolford, Wendy. 2016. “Land’s End: Review by Wendy Wolford.” The Journal of Peasant Studies 43 (4): 950–954. doi: 10.1080/03066150.2016.1237096
  • Young, Alwyn. 2012. “The African Growth Miracle.” Journal of Political Economy 120 (4): 696–739. doi: 10.1086/668501