1,726
Views
36
CrossRef citations to date
0
Altmetric
Original Articles

The productivity–wage relationship in South Africa: an empirical investigation

Pages 109-132 | Published online: 01 Oct 2010

Abstract

This article investigates the relationship between labour productivity, average real wages and the unemployment rate in South Africa at the macroeconomic level, using time‐series econometric techniques. There is strong evidence of a structural break in 1990, after which time all three variables rose rapidly. The break appears to have negatively affected the level of employment in the first instance, and subsequently fed through into per worker wages and productivity. A long‐term equilibrium (cointegrating) relationship was found between real wages and productivity, but unemployment was apparently unconnected to the system, which lends support to the insider–outsider theory. A long‐term wage–productivity elasticity of 0,58 indicates that productivity has grown more rapidly than wages, which is consistent with the finding that labour's share of gross output has been shrinking over the past decade. These trends may be explained plausibly by the adoption of job‐shedding technology and capital intensification.

1 INTRODUCTION

Real wages, productivity and the unemployment rate represent an important nexus within labour markets, which has received a significant amount of attention in the economics literature. Several economic theories have been put forward justifying a relationship among these variables, including efficiency wage, bargaining, search and contract theories. This article aims to contribute to the body of literature addressing the productivity–wage–unemployment relationship in South Africa by applying modern time‐series econometric methods. Rather than setting out to test a specific theory, the objective is to ‘let the data speak for themselves’, i.e. to apply statistical techniques to establish the properties of the time‐series and their interrelationships. These results can then be compared with various economic theories.

The following specific questions are addressed in the article. First, is there a long‐term equilibrium (cointegrating) relationship between productivity, real wages and unemployment? Secondly, what are the short‐term or dynamic relationships among these variables? Thirdly, can statistical techniques shed any light on the directions of causality between the three series? A fourth and related issue to be explored is how labour's share of value added has changed over time, relative to the profit share.

Section 2 of the article presents a brief review of relevant international and South African literature exploring the links between productivity, real wages and unemployment, and thereby provides a backdrop for the empirical analysis. Section 3 outlines the empirical methodology and describes the data used in the study. Section 4 analyses the data and reports the results of cointegration tests, error correction models and causality tests. Section 5 discusses the issue of labour's share of gross value added. Section 6 summarises the main results and presents the conclusions.

2 LITERATURE REVIEW AND THEORETICAL BACKGROUND

This section begins by discussing the definitions of the variables, and then turns to brief reviews of some relevant international and South African studies for comparative purposes. It concludes with a discussion of the various possible causal links between real wages, labour productivity and unemployment.

2.1 Defining real wages, productivity and unemployment

In the literature, real wages are defined either as real consumption wages (where nominal wages are deflated by the consumer price index to provide a measure of workers' real purchasing power), or as real product wages (where nominal wages are deflated by the producer price index to provide a measure of the labour cost of production). The appropriate choice of wage measure depends on the exact relationship being investigated, but is by no means unambiguous. For example, in a situation of contract bargaining, workers are concerned with their real purchasing power (hence consumption wages), while management is more concerned with the production costs (hence product wages). Resolving this ambiguity may involve a somewhat arbitrary choice of either consumption or production wages. This study chooses a variant of real product wages, where the gross domestic product (GDP) deflator is used to deflate the nominal wage rate. This may be seen as a compromise and also allows for a closer fit with the measure of productivity used, which is based on real value added. A final point to note is that average (i.e. per worker) real wages are under consideration. The series is derived by dividing the total wage bill by the number of workers employed, which implies that observed changes in average real wages could emanate from changes in either the wage bill or the level of employment, or both. More precise details of the data used in this study are provided in Section 3.

Theoretically, the most appropriate concept of productivity in economics is marginal productivity, i.e. the contribution to output of the last worker hired. However, this cannot be readily measured. Next best would be a measure of output per hour of labour input, but again such a measure is not easily obtainable, certainly not in South Africa. In practice, therefore, one frequently has to resort to the use of average labour productivity. This may be calculated in various ways, for example total output (either in physical or monetary terms) divided by total employment. The measure we adopted in this study is value added per worker. This follows the precedent in South Africa set by Fallon & Pereira da Silva (Citation1994), for whom the logarithm of non‐government GDP expressed as a ratio of non‐government employment is taken as an index of productivity. Clearly, the ‘productivity’ series is affected both by value added (positively) and by employment levels (negatively). This obfuscates the interpretation of changes in measured productivity as, for example, an observed increase in our measure of productivity may be due to a decline in employment levels with no increase in physical output or value added. This issue is discussed further in Section 5.

The definition and measurement of unemployment are thorny issues. The main differentiation is between the so‐called ‘strict’ definition, which includes only active work seekers in the labour force, and the ‘expanded’ or ‘broad’ definition, in which ‘all persons are considered as unemployed who did not work in the past week and who either looked for work in a given reference period or were discouraged workers, i.e. they did not look for work in the belief that none was available’ (Kingdon & Knight, Citation1998: 1). The unemployment data used in the present study are based on the broad definition, in recognition of the arguments put forward by Nattrass (Citation2000: 76). These include, for example, that ‘given the low probability of finding employment, high transport costs… and low incomes, one would expect a labour‐surplus economy like South Africa to manifest a high level of discouraged work seekers’. This is contrary to the government's stance, namely that the ‘official rate’ of unemployment is defined as the strict measure.

2.2 International literature

The relationship between labour productivity, real wages and unemployment has received much attention in the international and (to a lesser extent) South African literature, although a number of different approaches have been taken. The purpose of this brief review is to provide a flavour of some of these approaches, and thereby establish the theoretical and prior empirical basis for the quantitative analysis conducted in Section 4.

Blanchflower & Oswald (Citation1993, 1994, 1995) pioneered a body of international wage curve literature, in which a negative relationship between real wages and unemployment is hypothesised and substantiated empirically. This approach represented a departure from previous views on the subject, developed initially by Harris & Todaro (Citation1970). These authors argue – on the basis of compensating differentials – that the relationship between wages and unemployment is expected to be positive across space. Blanchflower & Oswald (Citation1994: 1026) employ a number of different model specifications, which include controls for personal characteristics, and find a wage‐unemployment ‘elasticity’ of approximately –0,10.

The approach taken in this article differs from that of Blanchflower & Oswald (Citation1994) in two important respects. First, the main emphasis is on the relationship between wages and productivity, as opposed to that between wages and unemployment. Secondly, a time‐series econometric approach is applied to macroeconomic data, in contrast to these authors' spatial approach using panel data. Nevertheless, their micro‐evidence provides a testable hypothesis, namely that a negative relationship exists between unemployment and wages.

Wage equations have also been derived and estimated in recent international macroeconomic literature (see Blanchflower & Oswald, Citation1994, for a list of citations). For example, Blanchard & Katz (Citation1999) suggest the following specification: (-1)

where wt is the nominal wage rate, prodt is the level of productivity, Ut is the unemployment rate, and pet is the expected price level in time t.

Once again, the coefficient on the unemployment term is expected to be negative. The lagged real wage term is included to reflect earnings from participation in activities outside of the labour market, i.e. a proxy for the reservation wage. In the South African context it is implausible that lagged real wages in the formal sector relate to the levels of earnings derived from activities outside of the formal sector, or even that these extra‐labour market activities exert a direct influence on the level of real wages. On both counts, this lagged term cannot be taken to serve as a proxy for the reservation wage in a South African version of the equation given above – at least from a theoretical perspective. As will be seen, however, the statistical approach taken in this article enables one to test explicitly whether a lagged real wage term is appropriate empirically, although it need not be seen as a proxy for the reservation wage.

The methodology adopted in the present article follows that of Alexander (Citation1993), who investigates at a macroeconomic level the relationship between productivity, wages and unemployment in the United Kingdom for the period 1955–91. After finding evidence of a structural break in 1979, Alexander divides her sample into two subperiods. She then applies the cointegrating vector autoregression (VAR) methodology developed by Johansen (Citation1988), to test for long‐term relationships, and finally applies the concept of Granger causality (see Section 3.1) in an attempt to establish empirically the causal links between the three variables. Alexander's (Citation1993: 88) principal finding is that the relationships differ significantly between the subperiods: ‘Before 1979 unemployment is the central variable, being caused by both wages and productivity’, while after 1979 there is ‘a strong bivariate causality between wages and productivity, [with] unemployment becoming almost divorced from the system’. Alexander relates this shift to a change in the policy environment introduced by Prime Minister Margaret Thatcher.

2.3 South African literature

In the South African literature, the relationship between wages, productivity and unemployment has thus far been addressed mainly in terms of a real wage equation, in which wages are determined by a variety of factors. These determinants include productivity, unemployment, extent of unionisation, number of strikes, intensity of apartheid and (in pooled time‐series cross‐section regressions) legislated minimum wages and year and industry dummy variables (see Fallon, Citation1992; Fallon & Pereira da Silva, Citation1994; Fallon & Lucas, Citation1998). However, in only one instance is something analogous to a productivity term included on the right‐hand side of the equation. This single exception is the wage equation for skilled workers, for whom the estimated real wage ‘productivity’ elasticity is 0,51 in Fallon (Citation1992: 44) and 0,309 in Fallon & Pereira da Silva (Citation1994: 207). Note also that all of this literature deals with the real consumption wage rather than the real product wage, which is the emphasis of the present study. An extensive review of the real wage estimations of the three texts mentioned here revealed nothing else of direct relevance to an investigation of the relationship between productivity and real wages. Of all the possible explanatory variables, this study focuses specifically on productivity and unemployment. Preliminary analysis of a strike variable revealed no significant statistical relationship with the other variables.

Unemployment is of great importance in the South African context, and consequently it may be expected to be a key determinant of real wages. Kingdon & Knight (Citation1998) apply the wage curve methodology of Blanchflower & Oswald (Citation1994) to South Africa, using household survey data. They find evidence of a negative relationship between wages and unemployment across space, but reconcile this with a positive relationship over time for the macroeconomy as implied by the negative wage elasticity of employment found by Fallon (Citation1992) and Fallon & Lucas (Citation1998).

In a study of 48 South African economic sectors, Fedderke & Mariotti (Citation2002: 853) find that ‘where the real wage is less closely linked to real labour productivity, the growth in employment also tends to be lower’. Furthermore, when wages grow faster than productivity, employment declines – from which may be inferred that unemployment rises, ceteris paribus. Another result of Fedderke & Mariotti's (Citation2002: 850) analysis is that ‘for all the sectors with a strong improvement in real labour productivity, there is a strong improvement in the real per labour remuneration’, indicating that productivity may drive wages. While these authors' work utilises sectoral panel data as against aggregate time‐series data, and focuses on employment as opposed to unemployment, similar relationships between our three key variables are expected in the present study for the formal, non‐agricultural economy.

2.4 Causality issues

Based on theory and previous empirical evidence, a number of causal relations between real wages, productivity and unemployment may be hypothesised for the South African economy. These are summarised in , along with the expected signs.

Hypothesised causal relations among real wages, productivity and unemployment

Changes in productivity may cause changes in real wages for at least two reasons: if individuals' pay is performance‐based, and if labour unions bargain for real wage increases on the basis of past improvements in productivity. The effect of an increase in average labour productivity on unemployment is ambiguous. It could reduce the demand for labour, as workers are more efficient and hence raise the unemployment rate – assuming other factors such as the labour force participation rate remain constant. Alternatively, a rise in productivity could have a positive impact on employment through an ‘output effect’, thereby reducing the unemployment rate, ceteris paribus.

According to efficiency wage theory, a rise in real wages may induce higher worker productivity by raising the costs of job loss. At the macroeconomic level, an increase in real wages is expected to raise the cost of labour and therefore cause factor substitution from labour to capital. This could have two effects: it could raise marginal (and hence average) labour productivity, and it could add to the unemployment rate. Therefore, it is hypothesised that real wages positively affect both productivity and unemployment.

If the unemployment rate were to rise as a result of factors other than real wage or productivity increases, one may expect this to weaken union bargaining power and therefore dampen real wages. Also, a rise in unemployment may incentivise workers to increase effort and hence productivity to secure their jobs. Furthermore, as less productive workers are usually the first to be retrenched, increased unemployment may be associated with higher average productivity among the remaining workers.

Clearly, this discussion suggests that the interrelationships between productivity, real wages and unemployment are highly complex, with many feedback effects as well as ambiguous or multiple signs. This article attempts to shed some light on which of these effects are strongest, on the basis of empirical testing.

The causality between productivity and real wages has massive policy implications for the distribution of income in South Africa. If real wage increases (e.g. due to strong unions) are driving productivity gains through the substitution of capital and technology for labour, then it can be concluded that workers/unions are at least partially responsible for increasing unemployment, inequality and poverty. If, on the other hand, productivity is rising ahead of real wages, then capital/business is capturing an ever‐larger share at the expense of labour, both the employed and the unemployed.

As a final note, the widespread existence of one‐year contracts in the formal labour market lends credence to the view that the variables may influence each other after some time rather than contemporaneously. Furthermore, labour market data become available only after a lag of at least two quarters. Consequently, if workers have only one opportunity to bargain for higher real wages per year, they are likely to base their demands on the growth in productivity in the year up to the latest available data, which is likely to be six months old. Hence productivity could influence real wages after a lag of at least two quarters. The plausibility of lags in these relationships underpins the VAR econometric specification as well as the use of Granger causality tests, both of which are discussed further in the next section.

3 METHODOLOGY AND DATA

3.1 Empirical methodology

The productivity–wage–unemployment nexus is investigated as follows. First, the series are presented graphically, as much can be learned from the behaviour of the variables over time. For example, it is important to look for evidence of trends and structural breaks in time‐series. Following the common practice in macroeconomics (see also Alexander, Citation1993), a natural logarithm transformation is applied to the real wage and productivity series for the remaining analysis. The unemployment rate remains untransformed. Augmented Dickey–Fuller tests are then applied to the three series to determine their order of integration.

Assuming the variables are found to be non‐stationary, the next step is to apply Johansen's (Citation1988) multivariate test for cointegration. This approach is superior to that of Engle & Granger (Citation1987) for two main reasons. First, we have a system of three variables which may all be endogenously determined, suggesting that a VAR framework is appropriate (i.e. no one variable is clearly the dependent variable). Secondly, the statistical properties of the Johansen test are superior to those of the Engle–Granger approach. The Johansen procedure begins by selecting an appropriate lag order for the VAR, and then applies maximal eigenvalue and trace tests to establish the number of cointegrating vectors in the system. Should a cointegrating relation be found, the long‐term elasticities can be computed. Furthermore, an error correction model (ECM) can then be estimated to account for the short‐term dynamics in the system as well as the long‐term equilibrating mechanism. This series of tests is performed for the whole period (1983/Q1 to 2002/Q4) and tests are carried out to determine whether a structural break is present in the data. Based on strong evidence of a structural break, the period is split into two subperiods and the testing procedure repeated for the more recent period. Estimations and tests in this study were performed using the Microfit 4.0® and EViews 4.0® econometric packages.

Finally, Granger causality tests are performed to establish the direction of dynamic short‐term relationships among the variables. ‘Granger causality’ is a statistical term, which is interpreted thus: ‘If X and Y are two jointly covariance stationary processes, then X is said to “Granger‐cause” Y if past Y and past X better predict current Y than past Y alone’ (Alexander, Citation1993: 87). Hence, the issue is technically one of ‘predictability’ involving lead‐lag relationships rather than ‘causality’ in the strict sense of an endogenous/exogenous relationship. We may find a unidirectional causal relationship between two variables, a bidirectional relationship or independence. One of the practical issues encountered when applying Granger causality tests is the choice of lag length. The generally accepted wisdom is to err on the side of including more lags rather than fewer, as omitted variable bias is more serious than inefficiency resulting from the inclusion of irrelevant variables. However, testing for appropriate lag length in a VAR using various statistical information criteria assists in selecting an appropriate lag length. The error correction specification is then used for the causality tests as it ensures stationarity of the variables.

3.2 Data

The study makes use of quarterly data from 1983/Q1 to 2002/Q4 taken from the South African Reserve Bank's Quarterly Bulletin, (SARB, Citation2003). The main source of the SARB's data is Statistics South Africa (StatsSA), which in turn collects its data via quarterly surveys. The principal series used in the investigation are an index of average real product wages (remuneration per worker at constant prices) and an index of average labour productivity. Both series pertain to the non‐agricultural formal sector of the economy, are seasonally adjusted and have the year 2000 as the base date. The SARB is not fully transparent about how these two indexes are calculated, but presumably they involve ratios between the wage bill and total employment, and between value added and total employment, respectively. Wages were deflated by the non‐agricultural GDP deflator. The third variable is the total, economy‐wide unemployment rate, calculated according to the broad definition. The following notation is used for the three variables: LRW = log (real wage index); LPROD = log (productivity index); UR = total unemployment rate (percentage).

The SARB issues the following caveat in respect of these data: ‘From the first quarter of 1998 basic data originate from the Survey of Employment and Earnings in industries selected by Statistics South Africa, and are not strictly comparable with earlier data’ (SARB, Citation2003: S‐132). Both real wages and productivity increased discontinuously between 1997/Q4 and 1998/Q1, apparently due mainly to a sharp drop in measured employment, which appears as a denominator in both the wage and productivity terms. This study makes no adjustment to these data, as any modification would be arbitrary, and the results should therefore be treated with circumspection.

An annual unemployment rate series was constructed from various sources. Figures from 1983 to 1993 were provided by the Development Bank of Southern Africa (DBSA, Citation2003), which calculated the numbers using censuses and interpolation. The figures for 1994–9 come from StatsSA's (Citation1999) annual October Household Survey (OHS) and for the remaining years from StatsSA's (Citation2002) Labour Force Survey (LFS). As the LFS is conducted twice annually, in February and September, averages were calculated to obtain annual figures.

The annual data were then interpolated to quarterly figures using a quadratic match average function (see Eviews, Citation1997). While this clearly results in an overly smooth series with loss of short‐term information this is not deemed too serious a problem, as it seems unlikely that the total unemployment rate in the economy would fluctuate greatly from one quarter to the next. Also, when testing for a long‐term relationship, it is the overall trend in the series that is important. However, this becomes more of an issue when estimations of the short‐term dynamics are involved. Clearly, many doubts can be cast on the reliability of this unemployment series considering the differences in the surveys used to collect the raw data, as well as the interpolation methods applied. Consequently, one should view with caution the empirical results pertaining to unemployment presented in the following section.

4 EMPIRICAL RESULTS

Much can be learned from a preliminary analysis of the data before econometric modelling is conducted. The following subsection therefore presents several graphs, correlation coefficients, growth rates and tests for integration. This sets the scene for the cointegration and Granger causality tests that follow.

4.1 Preliminary data analysis

The point of departure is a visual examination of time plots of real wages, productivity and the unemployment rate, along with total employment (). This employment series is the SARB's (Citation2003) index of total, non‐agricultural, formal sector employment (year 2000 = 100).

Real wages, productivity, employment and unemployment, 1970–2002

Real wages, productivity, employment and unemployment, 1970–2002

Real wages fluctuated considerably around a horizontal trend throughout the 1970s and 1980s. These large swings in real wages coincided with periods of general economic instability, such as the recessions of 1974 and 1979 induced by the Organisation of the Petroleum Exporting Countries (OPEC), the gold price boom of 1981 and the political events in 1985. In other words, for the period 1970–89, real wages appear to have followed the business cycle quite closely. Since about 1990, however, the real wage index has risen considerably, with much more muted variations around a roughly linear trend.

The productivity series displays a broadly similar pattern, although it is much smoother. Over the 1970s and 1980s there is a slight positive trend, interrupted by a number of shocks. From 1990–4 the productivity curve appears to be exponential, while it seems to follow an almost linear trend for the remainder of the sample, rising somewhat more steeply than real wages.

The employment series is very striking, in that it rises fairly consistently from 1970–90 (other than a drop from 1976, possibly following the Soweto riots), whereafter it declines almost monotonically, with a brief hiccup after the democratic election in 1994. The unemployment rate has grown consistently, except for dips in 1995 and 2000, which cannot easily be reconciled with the smoothly declining employment series during the same period, as one expects labour force growth to be relatively consistent over time. The upward trend in unemployment was most pronounced between 1992 and 1994, during a deep recession. In the context of a growing population, this continual job shedding goes a long way in explaining South Africa's high levels of inequality and poverty (Leibbrandt et al., Citation2000).

4.1.1 Evidence of a structural break

The key features identified in the real wage, productivity and employment series all indicate that a structural change may have occurred in the labour market around 1990. The structural break occurring in 1990/Q1 is most clearly evident in the employment series. Fedderke & Mariotti (Citation2002) also find clear evidence of a structural break in 1990 in their sectoral analysis. This break manifested in changing employment growth rates and an increasing skills intensity of production.

Several factors may explain a structural break in or around 1990. First, by 1990 the South African economy had entered a severe, sustained recession lasting until 1994 when the democratic election turned the tide of confidence. This recession was the result of several factors, including a severe drought, the impact of economic sanctions against South Africa, a global economic downturn and, not least of all, the uncertainty leading up to the political transition. It seems plausible that this recession would have had a major impact on the labour market and on employment levels in particular. Secondly, in 1989, the SARB came under the governorship of Dr Chris Stals, who made it his primary mission to reduce inflation through the use of high real interest rates. This policy arguably slowed the rate of output growth and consequently stifled job creation. Thirdly, the 1990s was a period in which many firms increasingly began to substitute capital machinery and relatively scarce high‐skilled labour for relatively abundant unskilled labour (see Fedderke & Mariotti, Citation2002). From 1994 onwards it can be argued that increasing competition resulting from South Africa's reintroduction to the world economy stimulated this factor substitution. Fedderke & Mariotti (Citation2002: 843) state that ‘technological change has effectively been capital‐ rather than labour‐augmenting over time, thus decreasing the capacity of South African industry to expand employment’. Finally, the break may also have been driven by increasing labour market intervention by the government, which raised the wage and non‐wage costs of labour (Barker, Citation1999). Fedderke & Mariotti (Citation2002) point out that the structural shift as a result of policy changes was not limited to the labour market.

The existence of a structural break will be tested more formally in the econometric modelling in Section 4.2. We subsequently examine other features of the data.

4.1.2 Growth rates

The relationship between real wages and productivity is further demonstrated in , which plots the year‐on‐year growth rates of these series. Clearly, real wage growth has been far more volatile than productivity growth throughout the sample. Real wages rose rapidly during the period 1980–3, possibly due to black wages becoming more commensurate with white wages as the black trade union movement gathered momentum. For the remainder of the 1980s, productivity and real wage growth moved in similar directions, although wages were still more volatile. During the 1990s, both series grew more rapidly. The large swings in real wage growth during the latter period may be explained at least in part by the volatility of inflation, which has been influenced by several currency crises.

Growth in productivity and real wages, 1970–2002

Growth in productivity and real wages, 1970–2002

displays the average, year‐on‐year growth rates of productivity and real wages for each of the last three decades. In the 1970s, the growth rate of productivity was slightly positive, while that of real wages was small and negative. In the 1980s, real wages grew marginally faster than productivity, possibly reflecting the rise of black trade unions during this period. The figures from 1990 to the present are strikingly different on two counts: the (positive) growth rates are much larger and the average growth of real wages has been greater than the average growth of productivity by a factor of two‐thirds. This is clear evidence that labour has been receiving a diminishing share of output in recent years. This, together with increasing unemployment, may explain to a significant degree why inequality in South Africa is worsening.

Average year‐on‐year growth rates of productivity and real wages

4.1.3 Correlations

The correlation coefficients presented in afford a more precise summary of the relationships between real wages, productivity and unemployment. The figures corroborate the earlier discussion based on the graphs, in that they show no significant relationship between real wages and productivity in the 1970s and 1980s, but an extremely high correlation in the 1990s. Real wages are negatively associated with unemployment in the 1980s – although this coefficient is insignificant at the 10 per cent level – but strongly positively related in the 1990s. The correlation between unemployment and productivity was positive and moderate in the 1980s but strongly positive in the 1990s. The overall picture is that the three variables were weakly related in the 1980s but very strongly (positively) related in the 1990s.

Pairwise correlation coefficients

In the longest period for which data are available on all variables, 1983–2002, the pairwise correlations are all very strongly positive. The structural break in 1990 appears to have affected all three variables in a similar manner, i.e. they all grew more rapidly since 1990. One possible rationalisation of this result is that real wages have not been able to grow quite as fast as productivity because the bargaining power of labour has been undermined by rising unemployment. This hypothesis is further investigated through cointegration analysis in Section 4. Some possible answers as to what is driving this dynamic are provided in the concluding section.

4.1.4 Orders of integration

Having gathered some very useful information from graphs and growth rates, we turn to an analysis of the time‐series properties of the series. A priori, the visible evidence of upward trends (see ) suggests that all three series are non‐stationary. This is tested formally by way of Dickey–Fuller (DF) and augmented Dickey–Fuller (ADF) tests for stationarity. The ADF test allows one to distinguish between difference stationary and trend stationary time‐series processes; the former contain unit roots, while the latter are stationary once a linear trend has been removed. However, DF and ADF tests have low power in small samples and are not effective in distinguishing borderline cases.

The results, shown in , indicate that LPROD, LRW and UR are all I(1) variables, i.e. integrated of order one (non‐stationary in levels but stationary in first differences). This result is robust to the inclusion of a deterministic trend in the test regressions (column four), and in all but one case is also robust to the inclusion of one or four lagged difference terms, which account for possible autocorrelation. The exception is the DF test statistic for LPROD. However, the ADF(1) specification is selected by the three model selection criteria.

Testing for order of integration, 1983–2002

The properties of any particular series may change over time, particularly after a structural break. Also, the DF and ADF tests are sensitive to the presence of structural breaks, in that they tend to find unit roots more often when breaks are not taken into account (see Maddala & Kim, Citation1998). Hence, based on the evidence presented in Section 4.1.1 for a structural break in 1990, the testing procedure is repeated for the sample 1990/Q1 to 2002/Q4. The results are presented in . When no trend term is included, the DF and ADF tests all indicate that the three variables are non‐stationary in levels (third column). The same applies to LPROD and UR when a deterministic trend is included, but the results indicate that LRW is trend stationary in this period. According to Alexander (Citation1993: 89), this justifies the inclusion of a general constant term in the cointegration tests (to be performed later). None of the variables is I(2), as all of the test statistics in the final column are significant at the 5 per cent level, meaning that the variables are stationary in first differences.

Testing for order of integration, 1990–2002

For both periods (1983–2002 and 1990–2002), therefore, we have established that the variables are I(1). Therefore, cointegration tests are necessary before regression results can be considered reliable (non‐spurious).

4.2 Cointegration tests

4.2.1 Testing for cointegration with a structural break in 1990

We turn now to test for the existence of a long‐term cointegrating relationship between LNPROD, LNRW and UR over the period for which data are available, namely 1983/Q1 to 2002/Q4. Following the graphical indications that a structural break occurred in 1990, and the supporting discussion, allowance is made in the testing procedure for such a break. Maddala & Kim (Citation1998: 417) recommend a general‐to‐specific methodology that allows for structural breaks in the first instance. The methodology involves estimating a VAR and testing for lag order, determining the number of cointegrating vectors using the Johansen procedure, and then estimating error correction models should a cointegrating relation be found. Throughout this process, a dummy variable (D90) is used to test for the presence of a structural break in 1990/Q1. D90 takes on values of zero up to and including 1989/Q4, and values of one thereafter.

The first step is to test for the appropriate lag order (p) in the VAR. A starting‐point of four lags is chosen, as the data series are of quarterly frequency. In general one could allow for more lags, but shows this is clearly unnecessary in the present example. The results, displayed in , unambiguously indicate that a VAR(2) is appropriate: the AIC, SBC, likelihood ratio (LR) test and adjusted LR test all select p equal to two. The LR tests indicate that one should reject the restriction that lags two to four should be excluded, but accept the restriction that lags three and four should be dropped. The adjusted LR test is considered more reliable in small samples (Pesaran & Pesaran, Citation1997). Lagrange multiplier (LM) tests applied to the residuals of each equation yield no evidence of autocorrelation, so one can safely say that two lags are sufficient for the VAR. The χ2 test statistics with four degrees of freedom for the LRW, LPROD and UR equations are 3,27 (p = 0,51), 1,60 (p = 0,81) and 7,28 (p = 0,12), respectively. The null hypothesis is no serial correlation.

Testing for lag order in the VAR

An LR test of restrictions was applied to test the significance of the D90 variable. The χ2 statistic with three degrees of freedom is 6,59 (p = 0,086), which is insignificant at the 5 per cent level (implying the dummy variable is not significant), but significant at the 10 per cent level. The reason for this weak evidence of a structural change could be that the break primarily affected the level of employment, which affects the per worker real wage, productivity and unemployment series in a similar manner. As a result, it was decided to continue from this point without the dummy variable. The Johansen procedure was also applied with D90 included and there was no solid evidence of a cointegrating relationship in that case. Re‐estimating the VAR excluding D90 yields very similar results, and again the lag order is unambiguously two.

With the VAR order having been established, Johansen's (Citation1988) maximum likelihood test for cointegration can be applied. However, one first has to make an assumption about whether intercept and/or trend terms are appropriate in the VAR model. For the sake of transparency, the test results are shown in for four combinations of intercept/trend specification. The results show just how sensitive the cointegration tests are to the way in which intercept and trend terms are included in the VAR. They also demonstrate that the various tests for the number of cointegrating vectors are often inconsistent for a given specification. The preferred tests, developed by Johansen (Citation1988), are the ‘maximal eigenvalue’ and ‘trace’ tests, while the three model selection criteria (AIC, SBC and HQC) may be used as additional evidence.

Cointegration tests for LRW, LPROD and UR, 1983–2002

Because of the possibility that LRW has a deterministic trend, and the graphical evidence that the three series are trending together, the ‘unrestricted intercepts, no trends’ option is selected as being most appropriate in this instance (Alexander, Citation1993; Pesaran & Pesaran, Citation1997). The detailed results of this cointegration test are reported in . There is clearly a great deal of variation among the criteria: the maximal eigenvalue test suggests that the number of cointegrating vectors (r) is zero; the trace test indicates r = 1; the AIC and HQC suggest r = 2; and the SBC favours parsimony (r = 0). Weighing up this evidence is not easy. However, by applying the law of averages and with the support of theory it may be justifiable to assume that there is a single cointegrating vector. This allows one to estimate the long‐term relationship and ECMs.

Cointegration test using ‘unrestricted intercepts, no trends’, 1983–2002

The long‐term equilibrium vector is estimated to be Z=LRW – 0,74 LPROD+0,40 UR. The coefficient of LPROD has a standard error of 0,15 and is therefore significant, while the coefficient of UR has a standard error of 0,37 and is clearly insignificant. The latter result is tested further via an overidentifying restriction (that the coefficient of UR = 0), which produces a χ2 statistic of 1,43, which is not significant (p = 0,103). Hence, the evidence suggests that UR is not part of the long‐term relationship. The coefficient of LPROD under the overidentifying restriction changes to –0,57, which is almost identical to the elasticity found in Section 4.2.3 for the period 1990–2002 (where UR is omitted from the start).

4.2.2 Testing for multivariate cointegration, 1990–2002

Although the foregoing statistical evidence for a structural break is rather weak at best, the economic and empirical reasons discussed earlier would seem to justify splitting the data sample into two subperiods: 1983/Q1 to 1989/Q4, and 1990/Q1 to 2002/Q4. Unfortunately, these relatively short time periods may undermine the robustness of the econometric results, but this is traded off against the possible effect of the break. As the recent past is of greater interest and the sample is larger, the tests are repeated for the latter period only. This allows one to check whether the result obtained above (in particular that there is a cointegrating relation between LRW and LPROD but not with UR) is robust to the sample period.

As before, the ‘unrestricted intercepts, no trends’ option is chosen as most appropriate in this instance. The test results are mixed once again – interestingly, they are identical to those obtained for the expanded sample. The full results are reported in .

Cointegration test using ‘unrestricted intercepts, no trends’, 1990–2002

Following the same logic as before, it is assumed that there is one cointegrating vector. The long‐term equilibrium vector is estimated to be Z = LRW – 0,85 LPROD+0,75 UR (). The coefficient of LPROD has a standard error of 0,42 and is therefore significant, while the coefficient of UR has a standard error of 1,15 and is clearly insignificant. The latter result is tested further via an overidentifying restriction (that the coefficient of UR = 0), which produces a χ2 statistic of 1,43, which is not significant (p = 0,23). Hence, we can again safely conclude that UR is not part of the long‐term relationship and should be omitted. This has interesting implications for theory and policy, which are discussed in the concluding section.

Cointegrating vector Z = LRW −0,85 LPROD +0,75 UR

Cointegrating vector Z = LRW −0,85 LPROD +0,75 UR

4.2.3 Cointegration between LRW and LPROD, 1990–2002

The last result suggests that a cointegration test for the bivariate relationship between LRW and LPROD should be conducted. (Cointegration tests were also conducted for the period 1970–2002 with a dummy variable for the years 1990 onwards. The results were qualitatively similar, in that a single cointegrating vector was found with a wage–productivity elasticity of 0,53.)

Applying the same methodology as before, a VAR(1) was selected. The two equations were tested for residual serial correlation and none was found, which further validates the lag order selection. χ2 values (d.f. = 4) for the LM serial correlation test of 2,14 (p = 0,71) and 3,76 (p = 0,44) were obtained for the LRW and LPROD equations, respectively. However, using only one lag in the VAR for quarterly data is very restrictive, and subsequent ECM modelling showed that using a VAR(2) is more informative, without changing any of the substantive results. Therefore, the Johansen cointegration test was applied in a VAR(2), again with unrestricted intercepts and no trends. The evidence in is consistent with the existence of a single cointegrating vector and is far more robust than earlier estimations. The maximal eigenvalue test clearly indicates a single cointegrating vector at the 5 per cent level, although the trace test suggests r = 1 at the 10 per cent level only. However, the AIC, SBC and HQC all select r = 1, and therefore it seems safe to assume there is one cointegrating vector.

Cointegration test for LRW and LPROD, 1990–2002

The long‐term equilibrium vector is estimated as Z=LRW – 0,58 LPROD, which is depicted in . The standard error on the coefficient of LPROD is 0,04, implying a high degree of significance. This implies that for every 1 per cent rise in productivity, real wages rise by 0,58 per cent in the long term. This elasticity is statistically significantly different from zero and from unity. An overidentifying restriction for the long‐term coefficient of LPROD equal to unity yields a χ2 statistic of 14,42, which is significant at the 1 per cent level, implying rejection of the restriction.

Cointegrating vector Z = LRW −0,58 LPROD

Cointegrating vector Z = LRW −0,58 LPROD

4.3 Error correction models and Granger causality

As a cointegrating relation was found between LRW and LPROD, it may be concluded that there is a long‐term causal relationship between the variables. It also means that ECMs may be estimated, which allow us to test for short‐term or dynamic causality. The results of the ECM estimations are reported in . The DLRW model has low explanatory power, but the F‐statistic is significant and the model passes all of the conventional tests for serial correlation, functional form, residual normality and heteroscedasticity at the 10 per cent level. It can be seen that only the constant and error correction terms are significant, which is consistent with the evidence mentioned earlier that a single lag in the VAR may be appropriate. On the other hand, in the DLPROD model the lagged real wage term is significant at the 5 per cent level, and the lagged productivity term is significant at 10 per cent. Overall, this model is significant at 1 per cent, although the residuals fail the normality test, which casts doubt on the reliability of t‐ and F‐tests.

Error correction models for LRW and LPROD, 1990–2002

Granger causality may be inferred from the ECMs by testing restrictions on the lagged difference terms. For the DLPROD equation, the Wald statistic for testing the restriction that DLRW(−1) has a zero coefficient is 7,01 (p = 0,008), which implies that real wages Granger‐cause productivity (see Section 3.1). It is interesting to note, however, that the coefficient is negative, which runs counter to efficiency wage theory. Interestingly, Alexander (Citation1993: 99) finds the same result for the United Kingdom in the period 1979–91. The ECM term is significant but positive, which is contrary to expectations.

Conversely, for the DLRW equation, the Wald statistic for testing the restriction that DLPROD(−1) has a zero coefficient is 0,71 (p = 0,401), which implies that productivity does not Granger‐cause real wages. This result is evidence against the supposition that employers use performance‐related pay schemes, and is contrary to the wage bargaining hypothesis presented earlier.

However, the lack of a short‐term effect could be related to fixed wage contracts, which in South Africa tend to be a year long in most cases (i.e. four quarters). Similarly, the DLRW(−1) term is insignificant, which shows that there is no short‐term feedback in the dynamics of real wages. This supports the argument put forward in Section 2 about the proxy for a reservation wage being inappropriate in a wage curve equation in the South African context. On the other hand, the negative error correction term is significant with a Wald statistic of 6,2702 (p = 0,012). Real wages therefore adjust back towards long‐term equilibrium (with productivity) following a shock, which conforms to expectations. The coefficient is also quite large, indicating a fairly rapid adjustment to equilibrium.

In sum, the econometric evidence suggests the following dynamic causal system: real wages impact on productivity negatively but productivity has no effect on real wages; productivity has a weak autoregressive pattern but real wages lack this altogether; and adjustment to equilibrium occurs through both wages (negatively) and productivity (positively). Not much of substance can be said about unemployment in the short term, mainly due to the way in which the data series was constructed.

5 LABOUR'S SHARE OF VALUE ADDED

The main result of the previous section is that the relationship between real wages and productivity has not been one to one, as productivity has grown more rapidly than real wages. The implication to be drawn from this is that labour's share of value added has declined since 1990. This is made clearer by emphasising the components of the two series. The average real wage is the wage bill divided by total employment, while productivity is value added divided by (exactly the same) total employment. Hence, a simplified way of looking at this issue is to examine the ratio of the wage bill to value added directly, so that the employment denominators cancel out. This is employed in , which plots the shares of value added accruing to labour (in the form of the wage bill) and employers (in the form of gross operating surplus), respectively.

Decomposition of gross value added into wage bill and gross operating surplus

Decomposition of gross value added into wage bill and gross operating surplus

As can be seen in , labour's share of value added fluctuated considerably over much of the 1960s to 1980s, although the long‐term trend appears to be stable. However, the wage share had been declining steadily since the late 1980s, and by 2002 had reached its lowest level in 43 years (51 per cent). The maximum value during this period (1960–2002) was 60 per cent, while the long‐term average wage share was 56,4 per cent. A long‐term average is meaningful, as the wage share series is stationary according to ADF tests (the test statistics are significant at the 5 per cent level whether or not a trend term is included). The only previous year in which the wage share dropped to the level of 51 per cent was 1980, in the wake of the second OPEC oil price shock and subsequent global recession. Clearly, workers in South Africa are feeling the pinch in a very significant way. This situation, together with the extremely high unemployment rate, is further evidence of the increasing inequality in our society.

What might be the reasons for the declining wage share? In the first place, it seems to be clear that some major restructuring has taken place in the South African economy over the past two decades. In particular, there appears to have been a substitution of capital for labour in the production function. This has been evidenced by the rapid decline in employment levels but growth (albeit slow) in both capital stock and output during the 1990s. This trend has been particularly evident in the mining and manufacturing sectors.

The cause of this restructuring is by no means certain, but one possible scenario is that rising real wage demands induced firms to substitute other factors of production for labour. This is consistent with the findings of a negative wage‐employment elasticity in South Africa. See, for example, Bhorat & Leibbrandt (Citation1998), Fallon (Citation1992) and Fallon & Lucas (Citation1998). However, an unambiguous causality between wages and employment has not been established either empirically or theoretically. Nevertheless, wage increases seem likely to be at least part of the story.

An alternative scenario can also be hypothesised. Instead of rising average real wages driving the restructuring, the underlying cause could have been other incentives facing producers, such as labour market inflexibility or technological advances embodied in capital. The immediate result was the same, i.e. slow growth in value added in the face of falling employment, resulting in growth in measured average productivity. This may have served as a basis for labour unions bargaining for higher real wages, although from the results in the previous section it appears that this bargaining power was rather weak, so that labour enjoyed a relatively meagre portion of the productivity gains.

Diwan (Citation1999) offers another possible explanation for the recent sharp decline in the share of value added accruing to labour. His panel data analysis of a group of developing countries yields the conclusion that labour's share of GDP is adversely affected by financial shocks, such as the Asian crisis of 1997–8. Diwan (Citation1999: 19) concludes that ‘[financial] crises are resolved when workers end up bearing large costs that resemble bail‐outs of capital’, which amount to 20 per cent of GDP on average. He notes that the labour share recovers only partially after such crises. His work also shows that there has been a general trend towards declining labour shares in most regions of the world in the past two decades, which ‘may be connected to a race to the bottom, generated by increased globalisation’ (Diwan, Citation1999: 19).

Since the democratic transition in 1994, South Africa has experienced no fewer than three financial shocks, transmitted principally through the exchange rate. Their effect on the economy has been clearly visible in many indicators, such as upward pressure on inflation and interest rates, slow economic growth and continued job shedding. In the light of Diwan's (Citation1999) evidence, it seems plausible that these crises could be at least partially responsible for the recent decline in the labour share of GDP. The biggest drop in labour's share has occurred since 1999, while the main impact of the Asian crisis was felt in the second half of 1998. There may plausibly be a time lag between the early indications of a crisis (e.g. plunging currency and rising interest rates) and its restructuring effect on the economy, particularly in the context of fixed wage contracts. The massive depression in the South African rand in 2001 may be partly responsible for the sharp decline in labour's share in the past two years, and it will be interesting to see whether and to what extent this recovers following the rand's recent appreciation.

Whether the effects of financial crises are permanent or transitory – considering South Africa's vulnerability to financial shocks due to the free‐floating exchange rate regime operated by the SARB – the foregoing findings raise the question of what the authorities could or should do to limit the distributional impact of such shocks. Clearly, further research is required to investigate empirically the factors that are associated with variations in labour's share, for example business cycle fluctuations, financial crises and labour market policy interventions.

6 CONCLUSIONS

The aim of this article was to investigate the empirical relationship between productivity, real wages and unemployment in South Africa, using appropriate time‐series econometric techniques. The value of this approach lies therein that it makes no a priori theoretical assumptions regarding the relations between the variables, but rather allows the data to ‘speak for themselves’. The results may then be used in one of two ways. Either they allow one to interrogate the validity of the data by comparing the results with well‐established labour market models, or – assuming the data are deemed reliable – they can be used to provide evidence for or against labour market theories (Alexander, Citation1993: 101). This seems, however, to land one in a catch‐22 situation and inevitably the economist has to make an informed assumption about which is more reliable: the data, the theoretical models, or neither. In the present case, the real wage and productivity data are regarded as fairly reliable, but the unemployment series is rather makeshift in the absence of accurate annual (let alone quarterly) data over a long period of time. The long‐term upward trend in unemployment does, however, seem plausible.

The key findings of this study are as follows:

1.

First, there is strong evidence of a structural break in 1990, which seems to have affected the level of employment in the first instance, and fed through into other variables such as per worker wages and productivity. This evidence is substantiated by various economic and policy factors, as well as by other empirical work.

2.

Secondly, real wages, productivity and unemployment have all risen rapidly since 1990. A long‐term equilibrium (cointegrating) relationship seems to exist between real wages and productivity for the period 1983–2002, but unemployment was apparently not connected to the other two variables. There is also strong evidence that productivity and real wages are cointegrated in the period 1990–2002. In the long term, a 1 per cent rise in productivity is associated with a rise of approximately 0,58 per cent in real wages. The econometric modelling matches the preliminary analysis of growth rates, in that real wages have not kept pace with productivity gains in the long term.

3.

Thirdly, the unemployment rate behaves in a manner inconsistent with the theory underlying the specification of the wage curve equation. The econometric results show that unemployment is divorced from the long‐term equilibrium between real wages and productivity. More specifically, it seems clear that in the South African labour market, the high rate of unemployment has little or no effect in terms of restraining real wage growth. Conversely, real wage increases cannot be blamed for raising the level of unemployment. This carries the implication that the neoclassical view of the labour market has serious shortcomings. On the other hand, this study provides evidence for the insider–outsider model of the labour market, in that the unemployed appear to have little effect on wage rates.

4.

Fourthly, the econometric evidence suggests that the following dynamic (short‐term) causal system operates in the labour market: real wages impact on productivity negatively but productivity has no effect on real wages; productivity has a weak autoregressive pattern but real wages lack this altogether; and adjustment to equilibrium occurs through both wages (negatively) and productivity (positively). Little can be said about unemployment in the short term owing to the construction of the unemployment data series.

5.

Fifthly, given the economy's slow growth performance over the past decade, the rapid rise in productivity (and average real wages) reflects in large part the sharp decline in employment levels. South Africa's productivity performance should not be looked at in isolation of the employment trend, which indicates the job‐shedding nature of economic growth in this country over the past 13 years. The decline in employment cannot be fairly blamed on real wages growing in excess of productivity (thus forcing employers to cut jobs). The reverse is true, namely that productivity has grown faster than real wages. As a result, labour's share of gross output has been shrinking over the past decade, and has now reached its lowest proportion relative to capital's share in the past 40 years. This trend has been observed in many other developing countries around the world and reflects an increasing concentration of wealth among owners of capital. This is particularly alarming in the South African case, given the high levels of inequality, unemployment and poverty.

In conclusion, at least two possible avenues for further research stemming from this article may be identified. One is to repeat the analysis at a sectoral level. Previous (unpublished) work by the author on one‐digit sectors revealed a high degree of variability in the productivity–wage relationship, which suggests that aggregation to the national level may obscure further complexities in the labour market. Another potentially enlightening way forward would be to unpack the factors that have contributed to the recently declining share of wages in value added. This seems particularly important in the light of South Africa's widening inequality and our economy's susceptibility to external shocks.

Notes

REFERENCES

  • Alexander, CO, 1993. The changing relationship between productivity, wages and unemployment in the UK, Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Statistics 55 ((1)) (1993), pp. 87–102.
  • Barker, FS, 1999. On South African labour policies, South African Journal of Economics 67 ((1)) (1999), pp. 1–33.
  • Bhorat, H, and Leibbrandt, MV, 1998. "Estimates of wage‐employment elasticities for South Africa". 1998, Unpublished paper. Cape Town: University of Cape Town.
  • Blanchard, O, and Katz, L, 1999. Wage dynamics: reconciling theory and evidence, American Economic Review 89 ((2)) (1999), pp. 69–74.
  • Blanchflower, DG, and Oswald, AJ, 1993. The wage curve, Scandinavian Journal of Economics 92 (1993), pp. 215–35.
  • Blanchflower, DG, and Oswald, AJ, 1994. Estimating a wage curve for Britain: 1973–1990, Economic Journal 104 (1994), pp. 1025–43.
  • Blanchflower, DG, and Oswald, AJ, 1995. "The wage curve". 1995, London: MIT Press.
  • 2003. "Annual unemployment rate figures, 1983–1993". 2003Development Bank of Southern Africa (DBSA), Unpublished. Midrand: DBSA.
  • Diwan, I, 1999. "Labour shares and financial crises". 1999, Draft paper. Washington, DC: World Bank.
  • Engle, RF, and Granger, CWJ, 1987. Co‐integration and error correction: representation, estimation and testing, Econometrica 55 (1987), pp. 251–76.
  • Eviews, , 1997. "User's guide". 1997, Irvine, CA: Quantitative Micro Software.
  • Fallon, P, 1992. "An analysis of employment and wage behaviour in South Africa". 1992, Informal discussion paper on aspects of the economy of South Africa, No. 3. Washington, DC: World Bank Southern Africa Department.
  • Fallon, P, and Lucas, R, 1998. "South African labour markets: adjustment and inequalities". 1998, Informal discussion paper on aspects of the economy of South Africa, No. 12. Washington, DC: World Bank Southern Africa Department.
  • Fallon, P, and Pereira Da Silva, L, 1994. "South Africa: economic performance and policies". 1994, Informal discussion paper on aspects of the economy of South Africa, No. 7. Washington, DC: World Bank Southern Africa Department.
  • Fedderke, JW, and Mariotti, M, 2002. Changing labour market conditions in South Africa: a sectoral analysis for the period 1970–1997, South African Journal of Economics 70 ((5)) (2002), pp. 830–64.
  • Harris, JR, and Todaro, MP, 1970. Migration, unemployment and development: a two‐sector analysis, American Economic Review 60 (1970), pp. 126–42.
  • Johansen, S, 1988. Statistical analysis of cointegration vectors, Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control 12 (1988), pp. 231–54.
  • Kingdon, G, and Knight, J, 1998. "Unemployment and wages in South Africa: a spatial approach". 1998, Centre for the Study of African Economies Working Paper No. WPS/99/12. Oxford: Oxford University.
  • Leibbrandt, MV, Woolard, I, and Bhorat, H, 2000. Understanding contemporary household inequality in South Africa, Journal for Studies in Economics and Econometrics 24 ((3)) (2000), pp. 31–51.
  • Maddala, GS, and Kim, I‐M, 1998. "Unit roots, cointegration, and structural change". 1998, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
  • Nattrass, N, 2000. The debate about unemployment in the 1990s, Journal for Studies in Economics and Econometrics 24 ((3)) (2000), pp. 73–89.
  • Pesaran, H, and Pesaran, B, 1997. "Working withMicrofit 4.0". 1997, Oxford: Oxford University Press.
  • 2003. "Quarterly Bulletin". 2003South African Reserve Bank (SARB), June. Pretoria: SARB.
  • 1999. "Labour statistics: survey of total employment and earnings". 1999Statistics South Africa (STATSSA), Statistical Release P0317. Pretoria: StatsSA.
  • 2002. "Labour Force Survey". 2002Statistics South Africa (STATSSA), Statistical Release P0210, September. Pretoria: StatsSA.

Reprints and Corporate Permissions

Please note: Selecting permissions does not provide access to the full text of the article, please see our help page How do I view content?

To request a reprint or corporate permissions for this article, please click on the relevant link below:

Academic Permissions

Please note: Selecting permissions does not provide access to the full text of the article, please see our help page How do I view content?

Obtain permissions instantly via Rightslink by clicking on the button below:

If you are unable to obtain permissions via Rightslink, please complete and submit this Permissions form. For more information, please visit our Permissions help page.