2,568
Views
25
CrossRef citations to date
0
Altmetric
DEBATE ARTICLE

Financing climate-friendly energy development through bonds

&
Pages 337-349 | Published online: 11 May 2012

Abstract

In this paper we review the various instruments that have been proposed and implemented for financing renewable energy and low-carbon technology projects, in both the developed and developing world, with a focus on private sector involvement. We consider their common features and compare their total impact so far with the scale of renewable energy funding likely to be needed over the next several decades, as estimated by such bodies as the International Energy Agency, which puts the amount at one trillion US dollars per year. An increase of this magnitude in the required financing provides opportunities for developing new financing instruments, based on what has been accomplished so far, and for regional development banks to be involved in the process, subject to sound risk management principles.

1. Introduction

It is widely agreed that the energy systems currently used by both developed and developing countries are creating problems. Countries that use fossil fuels (coal, oil and gas) face energy shortages and economic insecurity (caused, for example, by the fluctuating prices of these fuels), and the world as a whole faces severe environmental problems because of global warming (Stern, Citation2006). Whatever stand one takes on these issues – and there is surely scope for many opinions – it is undeniable that a shift to renewable energy and low-carbon technologies would be prudent, for developing as much as for developed countries.

The important question is how such a shift is to be financed. In this paper we review the financing mechanisms that have been used to date (tax credits, equity investments, bank loans, green bonds) to see how they measure up to the level of investment considered necessary by such agencies as the International Energy Agency (IEA) and the UK's Green Investment Bank Commission. The former cites a global investment requirement of up to one trillion US dollars per year until 2050 (IEA, Citation2010), and the latter a figure of 550 billion pounds sterling as the scale of UK investment required between now and 2020 (GIBC, 2010).

Focusing on climate-friendly bonds as a critical component of any future financing system capable of scaling up energy investments to this level, we discuss the likely structural features of such bonds, arguing that they must be kept as plain, or ‘vanilla’, as possible if they are to be widely adopted. We provide some hypothetical illustrations of how such bonds are likely to work, grounded in the experience of investment banks obtained to date, both with green bonds and earlier targeted bonds such as Industrial Development Bonds in the US. We provide some examples of current renewable energy projects in South Africa, where some initial funding has been provided under the World Bank's Clean Technology Fund programme, and demonstrate how the projects could be advanced (and others stimulated) through the climate bond mechanisms we discuss. We conclude our argument by making the point that development banks can play a leading role in issuing such climate-friendly bonds, without running excessive risks for themselves and the investors they seek to attract.

We start by describing a swing in investment finance towards a range of ‘green’ issues. This swing suggests that ‘climate bonds’ are beginning to be seen as an attractive investment offering security in long-term sustainable energy futures. In this paper we probe the advantages of using such bonds, while drawing attention to the risks that such debt instruments involve (Sturzenegger & Zettelmeyer, Citation2007).

2. Green finance

Already there are several precedents as well as proposals for new kinds of private financial instruments that are intended to help mitigate the negative effects of climate change. Consider the following items of financial news.

Clean Renewable Energy Bonds 2009, US Treasury. The US Treasury in its 2009 stimulus package authorised 2.4 billion US dollars' worth of Green Bonds to generate financing for renewable energy initiatives. These are known as Clean Renewable Energy Bonds (CREBs) and the government undertakes to pay interest in the form of a tax credit to bondholders in lieu of coupon interest payments.Footnote1 The bonds are targeted at municipalities, municipal utilities, public power utilities and rural cooperatives, which are authorised to issue bonds under the programme. The funds generated by the sale of such bonds are to be used in a range of clean energy investments approved by the Department of Energy, such as moves towards a ‘smart grid’ in the US, and wind, solar, geothermal and biomass projects. The same stimulus package (the American Recovery and Reinvestment Act of 2009) has provided a range of funding for renewable energy projects, including direct tax credits, loan guarantees and federal cash grants. The CREBs are known as a form of tax credit bonds, paying returns in the form of tax credits in place of coupon interest (see Klein, Citation2009).

Climate Awareness Bonds 2007 and 2009, European Investment Bank. The European Investment Bank (EIB), established as the official banking arm of the European Commission, has issued bonds as part of its climate awareness programme to a value of €840 million. The first tranche was issued in the form of a €600 million five-year bond, issued by the EIB through the services of the merchant bank Dresdner Kleinwort. Its return was linked to the performance of the Financial Times FTSE4Good Environmental Leaders Europe 40 Index (an index designed to identify European companies building environmentally sustainable business models). The EIB enjoys the highest credit rating possible, and has offered the Climate Awareness Bond to a wide range of investors contacted by Dresdner Kleinwort (a UK-based investment bank). It was fully subscribed, and the funds raised were used in EIB renewable energy and energy efficiency projects. A second tranche, also oversubscribed, was issued in 2009, denominated in Swedish kroner, to a value of SEK 2.2 billion (about €240 million).

Green Bonds, World Bank. After some initial small issues of green bonds, the World Bank joined with the Scandinavian bank SEB (Skandinaviska Enskilda Banken) in November 2008 to issue a Green Bond targeted at institutional investors. The first tranche of the bond was denominated in Swedish kroner to a total value of SEK 2.325 billion (approximately €250 million), with a maturity of six years. Interest payable on the bond was 0.25% above current Swedish government bond rates, giving investors an estimated yield of 3.15% per annum. The investors are for the most part institutional investors such as Swedish pension funds. Several subsequent tranches have been issued, always appealing to institutional investors. The State of California Teachers' pension fund purchased US$300 million of the second issue, again managed by SEB but denominated in US dollars, as a sign that California wanted to contribute tangibly to climate solutions. As of late 2010, these World Bank Green Bonds had been issued to a total value of approximately €1.5 billion, with varying maturity dates of five, seven and even 10 years.Footnote2

Breeze Bonds, Germany. The company CRC Breeze Finance has issued a series of seven asset-backed bonds, secured against wind farms operating in Germany, up to a total value of €900 million. The Breeze Bonds are structured so that revenues from the wind farms are used to pay interest on the bonds as well as capital repayments, thus using the bonds markets directly. These bonds are designed to make use of reasonably certain revenues flowing from the wind farms under the German feed-in tariff law. The bonds were lowered from B+ to B grade in 2009 by the ratings agency Fitch, which indicates that these bonds are taken seriously by the ratings agencies.

Green Investment Bank proposal, UK. Shortly after its election the new coalition government in Britain formed a Green Investment Bank Commission, with a remit to produce a blueprint for the bank and for financial instruments that could be issued under its authority, including Green Bonds. The Commission issued its first report in June 2010, and at the time of writing a response from the government was awaited (GIBC, 2010). The Commission identified an investment need of around 55 billion pounds sterling per year for the next decade to be channelled into renewable energy and low-carbon technology projects, and compared this with global spending on such projects in 2009 of around €90 billion.

Green Bank Act of 2009 Congressional Bill, USA. In 2009 a bill was tabled in the US Congress by Chris van Hollen (a Democrat representative from Maryland), calling for the creation of a US Green Bank as an independent, tax-exempt, wholly owned corporation of the US, with a mandate to provide financing for qualified renewable energy and energy efficiency projects, and initial capitalisation of US$10 billion. The bill lapsed for lack of support.

Climate Investment Funds, World Bank and regional development banks. Under the leadership of the World Bank, a number of multilateral lending banks, including the African Development Bank, the Asian Development Bank and the Inter-American Development Bank, have joined forces to create two major new funds to promote renewable energy and low-carbon technology investments in developing countries. These are known as the Clean Technology Fund (CTF) and the Strategic Climate Fund (SCF). After meeting in Manila in March 2010, the Climate Investment Fund (CIF) governing body issued a statement saying they envisaged attracting investments of up to US$40 billion, but they did not specify the measures needed to attract such funding.Footnote3

These items carry a clear and distinct message, namely that the financial system is now being enlisted as a player in this most demanding of challenges. They mirror discussion in the wider press and in papers issued by such bodies as the OECD and the UNFCC.Footnote4

Yet these finance instruments (or in other words debt instruments) as issued so far clearly go nowhere near the scale required, if estimates such as the GIBC's €500 billion up to 2020 (GIBC, 2010) and the IEA's even more ambitious one trillion US dollars per year each year up to 2050 (IEA, Citation2010), mentioned above, are to be believed.Footnote5 In this paper we explain what these financial instruments have in common and discuss how they can be generalised and scaled up so as to meet the challenges of building new energy systems around the world. This is both an energy challenge and a development challenge, since the new low-carbon energy systems can be viewed as drivers of industrial development. Following Mathews et al. Citation(2010), we call this generalised financial entity ‘climate bonds’, treating these as a new species in the rapid evolution of financial forms.Footnote6

There are of course many ways of financing the development of infrastructure and in particular the new infrastructure required by renewable energy and low-carbon technologies. The simplest and most straightforward, as the pure forms of equity and debt investment structures, are equity investments, by the project promoters or by energy investment houses or both, and bank loans. In between are various kinds of intermediate financing, mezzanine finance, tax credits and different kinds of subsidies, as well as various forms of insurance to reduce the risks involved in investing in novel energy projects.Footnote7 We see bonds as private and public sector financial instruments that are uniquely suited to facilitating major infrastructure investment projects, and this why we focus on them in this paper. In the following section we offer some historical background, before going on to discuss the options for climate bonds to be issued over the next decade.

3. Bonds as instruments of credit and development

Bonds issued by Renaissance Italian city states, such as the prestanze of Florence or the Venetian prestiti, proved to be financial innovations of the first order, in that they created debt securities that had the same status as traditional fixed property (Ferguson, Citation2008). In time they came to be called ‘mobile property’ (as in the later French innovation of crédit mobilier). The issuer had to have either the power to compel uptake of the bond (as in the first cases, specifically the Florence cases of prestanze, where the bonds were a form of tax) or the sovereign status to inspire confidence that the fixed interest of, say, 5% per annum for 20 years, would indeed be paid. Eventually the bond market expanded to accommodate issues (known as debentures) from private firms backed by the reputation and market strength of the leading merchant banks (such as Barings in London, or Goldman Sachs in New York) which acted as their underwriters.

The evolution of financial instruments has already moved through several major innovations and adaptations, from the invention of giro banks and then credit-creating banks to the securitisation of government debt via bonds and the subsequent innovations involving shares (equity) and markets where such instruments can be exchanged and liquidated. New institutions have been established in the past to meet new financing needs – such as the Crédit Agricole, an institution founded in 1860 to channel credit towards the French agricultural industry, or the European Investment Bank, founded in 1958 as part of the European project initiated by the founder members of the European community. In Spain the ICO (Instituto de Crédito Oficial) was founded as a state-owned bank to help implement the Spanish Government's social and economic goals, including those linked to renewable energy. In Japan ‘long-term credit’ banks were established as a means of channelling savings into targeted industries, where the banks attracted savings by issuing bonds and then lending at favourable rates to small and medium-sized firms in selected industries.

The literature mentions many precedents for developing countries to issue specially designated industrial development bonds to overcome some of the obstacles to the issue of debt financing vehicles (see for example Zervos, Citation2004). In each case the financial institution acts as an intermediary between the sources of the funds (the lenders or investors) and the desired object of investment, with the bond acting as the instrument of choice because it aggregates the funds available.

3.1 Industrial Development Bonds

There are already a number of important precedents for the kinds of targeted bonds now envisaged for green-tech and clean-tech projects, and which provide experience in the workings of such financial instruments – some devoted explicitly to promoting industrial development.Footnote8 Industrial Development Bonds (IDBs), for example, have been used as a vehicle to promote investment in new industries in non-traditional industrial regions in the US, such as those in Florida or Alabama. Through the 1950s and 1960s, under the stimulus of federal taxation exemptions, these states and the municipalities within them issued IDBs that proved to be extremely effective as means of advancing the industrial development of these regions. According to Thompson Citation(1968), the state of Alabama recorded 250 separate issues of IDBs in the period 1958 to 1967, so that such vehicles accounted for nearly a quarter of all investment in Alabama, creating 25 000 manufacturing jobs directly and another 35 000 to 50 000 jobs indirectly – against the strong competition for investment from established states such as Massachusetts in the northeast or Michigan in the north-central region. In Thompson's words, ‘the industrial expansion induced with IDBs has meant the difference between a vibrant, expanding economy and one in serious distress’ (1968:101).

These IDBs flourished under the impetus of tax exemptions granted by federal legislation. They have evolved to the point where they are now called ‘private activity bonds’ and are a form of finance favoured not just by local governments but also by small and medium-sized firms that are often reluctant or unable to access the mainstream stock markets with all their formidable bureaucracy and the expenses involved in any new stock issue. Recent reports by the Congressional Research Service indicate that this continues to be a thriving form of developmental finance in the US (Maguire, Citation2006; Maguire & Negley, Citation2007). According to Maguire & Negley Citation(2007), approx US$55 billion in new private activity bond volume was created between the years 2001 and 2005 by states in the US, using federal tax exemption arrangements. Most of these private activity bonds were what are called in the US ‘industrial development bonds’, i.e. municipal and corporate bonds that finance small-scale local investment projects through aggregation, pooling multiple projects into a bond financing package that can be taken to the large bond markets.

Note that these IDBs in the US are not concerned with climate-friendly investments (except indirectly where such investments might be seen as attractive industrial options). But we view the aggregation involved in packaging IDBs as working on the same principle that we envisage for climate bonds, or bonds that can be used to finance multiple climate-friendly development projects largely in developing countries. The US state-level IDB laws (such as Florida's Industrial Development Bond Financing Act, analysed by Scholl & Jimenez, Citation1984) provide a precedent for the kind of financing instrument we are discussing. These instruments gain their tax exemption from US Congressional approval.

4. Common features of Green Bonds issued to date

Experience with green bonds issued to date (and with similarly targeted instruments such as US Industrial Development Bonds) indicates that scaled-up financial instruments for renewable energy development should have certain basic structural features.Footnote9 We take it as a given that for a ‘climate bonds’ market to flourish all participants need to make a return, and should meet levels of risk no greater than those of conventional government and corporate bond markets. This means that assets backing the bond issues, and government guarantees, must be carefully structured, and the payments (whether coupon interest or tax credits) must be regular and founded on relatively certain income streams deriving from the energy projects themselves. These are fundamental and irreducible elements without which no financial instrument can be expected to succeed.

Given this background, how do we see a climate bonds market developing? We consider this question from the perspective of the bonds themselves (and their issuing institutions), in other words in terms of the kind of intermediation that is feasible.

First, the climate bonds are designed as an intermediary between wholesale (institutional) investors and desirable low-carbon investment projects such as wind farms, solar photovoltaic (PV) farms, biofuels projects and the firms that contribute to these developments, such as wind turbine and PV solar panel manufacturers. The point is that the institutional investors cannot be expected to know the profit potential of a wide range of such investment outlets – so they need a financial aggregating vehicle to provide the bridge. The climate bond is intended as just such a bridge, and is designed to attract primarily institutional investors such as pension funds.Footnote10

Second, the bonds are intended to be ‘asset-backed’ to the extent that they channel funds into real investment projects that generate real assets based on low-carbon industrial activities. These activities are intended to generate the income stream required by the bond-issuing institution to meet its coupon-payment obligations on the bond. But in case of failure guarantees must be provided – by the government that stands behind the issuing institution, or by multilateral institutions such as the Multilateral Investment Guarantee Agency of the World Bank, or both.Footnote11

Third, the maturity of the climate bonds needs to be extended as far as is practicable, to give the underlying renewable energy projects time to move from loss-making to making better profits than fossil fuel energy projects. We note that World Bank Green Bonds issued to date have maturity dates extending from five to seven and even 10 years. UK government ‘gilts’ have maturities of up to 30 years, reflecting the reasonable certainty that the British government will not default on its loans. There is an inherent trade-off here: the longer the time to maturity, the more risk perceived by the investor, but from the point of view of the energy project promoter, the longer the time to maturity, the greater the prospects for revenues to overtake up-front costs.

Fourth, in a field as novel as renewable energy project financing, the debt instruments need to be as closely modelled on existing ‘vanilla’ bonds as possible. Specific innovations and assorted ‘bells and whistles’ (such as varying interest repayments) need to be minimised, in the interests of appealing to as wide a class of institutional investors as possible. Thus it would seem to be counterproductive to attempt to make a link between climate bonds as A grade investment vehicles and carbon credits, to be traded on existing or future carbon exchanges. The carbon credits market is one thing, and attracts participants who wish to offset their carbon emissions; this is a very different clientele from the institutional investors likely to be attracted to climate bonds issued in large denominations.Footnote12

Given these four fundamentals, we envisage climate bonds as being issued in a variety of forms. The UK Green Investment Bank Commission envisages three such forms in its initial report: 1) single project bonds, which provide exposure to specified projects that are aligned with a transition to a low-carbon economy (such as wind farms); 2) bonds whose proceeds are invested directly in asset portfolios (such as onshore and offshore wind farms); and 3) secondary project finance loans that are bought from commercial banks and bundled by asset class into new bond issues (GIBC, 2010:20–1). Bonds issued by development banks from developing countries, probably in association with leading investment banks in the developed countries, would also have to be framed to assuage other concerns, for example by reducing the risk premium attached to developing country investments.

The security that underpins the climate bond concept is provided by assured revenues coming from investments in sound energy systems over the long term. This is the fundamentally attractive feature of renewable energy investments – whether they be investments in biofuel farms in Angola or Mozambique (linked to Brazilian know-how) or concentrated solar power grids emanating from such regions as North Africa as an extension of a smart grid encompassing Europe, or offshore wind farms in China.Footnote13

An unfortunate negative feature is that many such potential investments never go ahead, for any number of plausible reasons. One of these is diseconomies of scale associated with multiple small projects. Many renewable energy projects, such as local wind or solar installations, are conceived as small-scale. While this small scale can encourage experimentation and innovation, it retards implementation and system transformation as a whole. The finance raised by climate bonds would enable an issuing institution or government to aggregate many such initiatives and thereby equip them for commercial scale operation much earlier than would be achieved without such assistance. Many renewable energy projects are rendered uncompetitive not because of technical inadequacies but because funding sources are limited to loans from very conservative banks.

Climate bonds, as generalisations of green bonds issued to date, could help by aggregating smaller projects into larger ones. We know this can be done because private institutions already issue bonds designed to aggregate and standardise economic activities such as provision of infrastructure. The Australian Macquarie Bank devised such a scheme in which it aggregated infrastructure assets up to the point where they could be used to underpin the issuance of a new fund that would attract investments from private investors. This was done initially with toll roads, then with airports, then with fast-growth forests, and so on.

So, given these considerations, how would climate bonds actually work? How would they differ from existing government-backed securities?

5. How climate bonds are likely to work

Most climate bonds are likely to be issued by private sector players or supported by commitments from private players. Their distinguishing feature would be backing by governments or utilities in the form of contractual commitments to phase in renewable energies rapidly. To take a hypothetical example from Brazil, let us say that the Brazilian National Development Bank (BNDES) floats a one billion US dollar ‘climate bond’ on the NY and Tokyo bond markets, with backing from the Brazilian Government.

When discussing ordinary government securities, such as treasury certificates, the government backing the issue commits to repaying investors out of its revenue streams, usually taxation. In the case of a climate bond, a different kind of commitment would be needed, in relation both to sources of revenue (e.g. from revenues accruing to providers of renewable energies) and to specified actions to mitigate the negative effects of climate change or help with adaptation to the change (e.g. ‘ring-fencing’ the funds raised by the bond for climate-related activities). These commitments would have to be clearly visible to investors and be backed by guarantees and audit reviews, to ensure that the funds will actually be expended as advertised. After all, investors are interested in a return commensurate with the risk they are prepared to take. ‘Ring-fencing’ the investments to be made out of the proceeds raised by the bond would provide investors with some degree of certainty that the funds would not be disbursed on irrelevant projects that might not meet their environmental goals or match their risk perceptions.

One way forward would be for the Brazilian Government to attach an agreement, or contractual commitment, from an energy provider in Brazil, to the prospectus issued in connection with the bond. Let us say that the agreement is with the state-owned oil and biofuels company Petrobras, to raise the proportion of biofuels in its fuels mix by, say, 5% over a period of 10 years. Such an agreement would require Petrobras to make the necessary investments in growing, processing and purchasing biofuels in addition to whatever other investments it was contemplating. The agreement with Petrobras would make the climate bond issued by BNDES, with backing from the Brazilian Government, credible to investors in the New York and Tokyo bond markets. The funds raised by the bond could then be allocated by BNDES to Brazilian companies that are in the biofuels value chain, to enable them to make the needed investments, as well as to Petrobras itself. These funds would be made available by BNDES at a level of interest at least comparable to that available for other development investments, and probably at a better rate because of the aggregation effects achieved by the bond itself. The on-lending interest rate should of course be related to the cost of international borrowing, including the exchange rate risk, the options to cover such risk, and other factors. Thus individual projects related to raising the level of biofuels in the national fuels mix that might otherwise be rendered unachievable through high interest charges would become feasible when financed out of the proceeds of the bond.

As an alternative, the climate bond issued by BNDES with backing from the Brazilian Government might be supported by an agreement with the country's electricity distributor, Eletrobras, where again there might be a commitment to enhance the national electric power grid with further electrical supplies from renewable sources, including hydro, wind and solar. (We recognise that Brazil already has substantial hydroelectric resources used in generating electric power.) Again these commitments from Eletrobras could be attached to the prospectus through which the bond is issued. And again, Eletrobras would need to invest in renewable energy sources in order to fulfil these commitments, and the funds raised by the bond could be used precisely to make these investments, channelled to Eletrobras and renewable energy companies and suppliers of equipment by the development bank BNDES. Yet again, this would provide a means to overcome diseconomies of scale, allowing small projects to go ahead (through aggregation), whereas they might be frustrated if pursued individually through, say, ordinary bank loans or equity investments.

The same hypothetical scenario could be played out in Angola, or Mozambique, or South Africa, as the following examples demonstrate.

6. Potential for novel financing forms in South Africa and southern Africa

Under the Clean Technology Fund established by the multilateral development banks (and coordinated by the World Bank) a number of clean technology projects have been identified in South Africa that would be eligible for (limited) CTF funding in the first instance, but where we could envisage more extensive funding based on climate-bonds-style financial instruments. South Africa has an official goal of producing 4% of the nation's electricity from renewable sources by 2013 and improving energy efficiency by 12% by 2015 (see IEA, Citation2011). So far, CTF funding to a level of $500 million has been approved for renewable energy projects encompassing grid-connected solar thermal power, wind power and energy efficiency projects in both the industrial and commercial sectors. It is envisaged that these initial funds would leverage a further billion US dollars from bilateral and multilateral finance sources as well as the private sector. The following are some projects that could benefit from such financing.

Concentrated Solar Power (CSP) facility. Eskom has proposed a 100-MW CSP facility to be built at Upington, the first of its kind in sub-Saharan Africa. In April 2010 it was announced that the World Bank had provided development financing for the CSP project, along with US$3.05 billion for the completion of a 4800-MW coal-fired power station (making this World Bank financing decision a source of much controversy).

Utility-scale wind power project. At the same April meeting of the World Bank, a loan of US$260 million to help with financing of a 100-MW wind power project was also announced. This is Phase 1 of Eskom's Western Cape Province Wind Energy facility. The World Bank funding under the CTF umbrella is designed to give momentum to wind energy projects and help create an industrial infrastructure for manufacturing wind turbines in southern Africa.

Solar water heaters programme. The South African Government has a target of converting one million households from electric to solar water heating over the next five years, and CTF funding is helping to realise half this goal by providing assistance to municipalities and the private sector.

Energy efficiency projects. CTF financing is also designed to catalyse the expansion of bank lending to the commercial and industrial sectors and create lines of credit to commercial banks, in association with energy service companies.

We view the demonstration potential of such CTF-financed projects as being highly significant. Eskom estimates the potential of concentrated solar power in South Africa alone as being close to 40 GW, and replication of this in Namibia and Botswana could double the potential. Biofuel and bioenergy projects in tropical African countries have enormous potential, particularly if supplied with capital and know-how by Brazilian investors. It is unrealistic to see the CTF itself (or World Bank loans) as meeting the financial needs of such projects, and therefore some instrument such as the climate bond discussed in this paper will be needed to spur further involvement by private investors. The CTF-funded projects in South Africa provide the test and demonstration projects, to be followed by more conventional funding of both equity and debt investment in further, more expansive projects. The generalised green bonds, or climate bonds, can be expected to accelerate this process, by reducing risks and aggregating smaller projects into a larger one, thus overcoming diseconomies of scale and enhancing economic development itself.

7. Concluding comments: The attractiveness of climate bonds

Financing initiatives designed to raise funds internationally for infrastructure projects in developing countries (dams, railways, water works) have traditionally run into the problem of the risk spread needed to attract investors. There have been so many risks associated with lending to underdeveloped countries – uncertain rule of law, wild currency fluctuations, illiquid securities markets, absence of insurance coverage, corruption at various levels of government – that risk spreads sometimes become prohibitive, without government guarantees and in particular multilateral guarantees. But the basic problem is that the developing countries are soliciting funds to do things that wealthy countries have already done for themselves – things for which fundamental incentives are lacking.

When it comes to climate bonds, however, the situation is rather different. Now it is investors in the developed world looking to find ways to invest in what are viewed as ‘safe’ and ‘sustainable’ energy projects. Long-term investors would rather see their funds going to energy projects based on wind and sun rather than to increasingly problematic sources such as coal, oil and gas. These fossil fuels are subject to too many political risks (e.g. OPEC countries in the Gulf, unpredictable Latin American regimes, Iran), too many economic risks (wildly fluctuating prices and projected increases as fossil fuels reach the peak of their supply curves), and too many environmental risks (particularly global warming from rising carbon dioxide levels). They are thus becoming less attractive for long-term investment, while low-carbon and renewable energy projects in the developing countries are becoming correspondingly more attractive.

Under these circumstances, the developing countries actually have something to offer that is not available in the developed world. Brazil, or southern Africa, for example, have sunshine, rainfall and land on which biofuels can be grown, sufficient sunny and windy locales where renewable energy may be generated, and an abundance of farmers and businesses willing and able to put their land at the disposal of such energy generating activities. This match between the demand for ‘safe’ investment outlets from the developed world and the supply of renewable energy options in the developing world provides the rationale for climate bonds.

We view climate bonds then as the financial instrument of choice in channelling funds from the vast investment pool represented by institutional investors in the developed world to the equally impressive array of attractive, low-carbon investment projects in the developing world. In doing this, the bonds play the role that financial instruments have always played – channelling funds from where they are pooled to the projects where they are needed. The climate bonds proposal simply adapts and updates this old idea to the new situation. The world is searching for climate-friendly and low-carbon investment projects in the developing world, and development banks in emerging markets want to play a positive role in the financial intermediation of such projects.

Before embarking on the course outlined here, and scaling up the financing needed for renewable energy projects, developing countries will of course want to be sure they know the risks as well as the benefits of issuing climate bonds. The bond markets, as they have matured over hundreds of years, are buttressed by a range of provisions designed to reduce investor risk, and which raise costs for the countries issuing the bonds. But what investors fear most is default, and this is why countries that do fall into default – such as Mexico in 1982 or Argentina in 2001 – are severely punished by the markets, and suffer from high ‘risk premiums’ for years thereafter. We do not wish to see the Development Bank of Southern Africa, or any other development bank, falling into such a trap. This is why any climate bond issued will need to be backed by solid agreements with energy providers and distributors that will ensure a continuous flow of revenues that can be used to meet the claims of investors, while leaving some margin of profit for the energy firms involved in opening up the new energy options and for the country's energy consumers themselves.

Notes

1All bonds are issued with a ‘coupon’ or designated interest rate payable, stated on the bond certificate.

2The World Bank maintains a webpage devoted to the Green Bonds, with the latest information: http://treasury.worldbank.org/cmd/htm/WorldBankGreenBonds.html

3The estimated totals (CTF allocation plus co-financing) for the 13 currently endorsed CTF Investment Plans (in US$ billions) were: Colombia (2.9), Egypt (1.9), Indonesia (3.1), Kazakhstan (1.3), Mexico (6.2), Morocco (1.9), the Philippines (2.8), South Africa (2.3), Thailand (4.3), Turkey (2.1), Ukraine (2.6), Vietnam (3.4) and the regional Middle East and North Africa concentrated solar power plan covering Algeria, Egypt, Jordan, Morocco and Tunisia (5.6). For a discussion of how the various climate funds might work together, see World Bank Citation(2010).

4See for example Doornbusch & Knight (2008), especially the discussion of climate bonds in paragraphs 71, 72 and 73, and UNFCC (2008); as well as calls for greater involvement by the financial system by Avato & Coony Citation(2008), Doornbusch et al. (2008), Spratt Citation(2009) and Ward et al. Citation(2009).

5The IEA further estimates that cumulative investment of $46 trillion between 2006 and 2050 would halve carbon emission by mid-century (IEA, Citation2010).

6Some other terms used are ‘green bonds’, ‘environment bonds’ and, in a similar vein, ‘development bonds’ or in some specific instances, ‘rainforest bonds’. We consider ‘climate bonds’ the most suitable label for what promises to be a very broad category of financial instrument.

7Under the umbrella of the United Nations Environmental Program (UNEP), the Global Environment Facility and CarbonRe, an insurance consortium known as insurance4renewables has been established, bringing together CarbonRe, RSA Insurance Group and Munich Re to provide financial risk management for renewable energy projects around the world. The World Bank Group also offers insurance on sovereign risk for development projects under the Multilateral Investment Guarantee Agency.

8See sources such as Davis & Steil Citation(2004) or Eckhart & Mullen (Citation2005) for comprehensive reviews.

9See Veys Citation(2010) for a useful overview of the experience of the UK bonds market and prospects for green bonds.

10The world's largest 300 retirement funds grew 10.9% in 2010 to a record US$12.5 trillion, according to an annual survey conducted by Pensions & Investments and Towers Watson & Co (P&I/Towers-Watson, Citation2011). See a summary of the report online: www.pionline.com/specialreports/towers-watson-300

11UNEP/SEF Alliance Citation(2010) provides a discussion of the role of publicly-backed guarantees as a means of promoting investment in clean energy projects.

12IETA (Citation2010) makes such a link between carbon credits and green bonds.

13We refer here to the Desertec project, which envisages solar power generation facilities in North Africa being linked via high-voltage direct current lines to the European electric grid, forming a single transcontinental super-grid powered by renewable energy. For a discussion, see Battaglini et al. Citation(2009).

References

  • Avato , P and Coony , J . 2008 . “ Accelerating clean energy research, development and deployment: Lessons from non-energy sectors ” . In World Bank Working Paper No. 138 , Washington, DC : World Bank .
  • Battaglini , A. , Lilliestam , J , Haas , A and Patt , A . 2009 . Development of SuperSmart Grids for a more efficient utilisation of electricity from renewable sources . Journal of Cleaner Production , 17 : 911 – 18 .
  • Davis , E P and Steil , B . 2004 . Institutional Investors , Cambridge, MA : MIT Press .
  • Doornbosch , R and Knight , E . 2008 . “ What role for public finance in international climate change mitigation? ” . Round Table on Sustainable Development, Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development (OECD) Paper SG/SD/RT (2008) 3. www.oecd.org/dataoecd/20/26/41564226.pdf Accessed 28 February 2012
  • Doornbosch, R, Gielen, D & Koutstaal, P, 2008. Mobilising investments in low-emission energy technologies on the scale needed to reduce the risks of climate change. Round Table on Sustainable Development, Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development (OECD) Paper SG/SD/RT (2008) 1. http://www.oecd.org/dataoecd/0/29/40825955.pdf
  • Eckhart, M & Mullen, JE, 2005. Global development bonds. Working paper, World Business Council for Sustainable Development. www.wbcsd.org/web/projects/sl/gdb.pdf Accessed 28 February 2012.
  • Ferguson , N . 2008 . The Ascent of Money: A Financial History of the World , London : Allen Lane .
  • GIBC (Green Investment Bank Commission) . 2010 . Unlocking Investment to Deliver Britain's Low Carbon Future: Report by the Green Investment Bank Commission , London : GIBC .
  • IEA (International Energy Agency) . 2010 . Energy Technology Perspectives 2010: Scenarios and Strategies to 2050 , Paris : IEA .
  • IEA (International Energy Agency) . 2011 . Clean Energy Progress Report. IEA input to the Clean Energy Ministerial , Paris : IEA . http://iea.org/papers/2011/CEM_Progress_Report.pdf Accessed 28 February 2012
  • IETA (International Emissions Trading Association) . 2010 . “ Green sectoral bonds: Draft concept note for review and discussion. Discussion paper ” . London : IETA . www.ieta.org/ieta/www/pages/getfile.php?docID=3466 Accessed 28 February 2012
  • Klein, M, 2009. Tax credit bonds. CitiBank Investment Management Review 11, June.
  • Maguire , S . 2006 . “ Private activity bonds: An introduction ” . In CRS Report for Congress RL31457 , Washington, DC : Congressional Research Service .
  • Maguire , S and Negley , H . 2007 . “ Private activity bonds: An analysis of state use 2001–2005 ” . In CRS Report for Congress RL34159 , Washington, DC : Congressional Research Service .
  • Mathews , J A , Kidney , S , Mallon , K and Hughes , M . 2010 . Mobilizing private finance to drive an energy industrial revolution . Energy Policy , 38 : 3263 – 5 .
  • P&I/Towers-Watson . 2011 . The World's 300 Largest Pension funds , London : Pensions & Investments and Towers Watson & Co . www.pionline.com/specialreports/towers-watson-300 Accessed 28 February 2012
  • Scholl , D and Jimenez , M D . 1984 . The Florida Industrial Development Bond Financing Act: The need for judicial consistency . Florida State University Law Review , 12 ( 1 ) : 31 – 58 .
  • Spratt , S . 2009 . “ Assessing the alternatives: Financing climate change mitigation and adaptation in developing countries ” . In A report for Stamp Out Poverty , London : New Economics Foundation . www.oxfam.org.uk/resources/policy/climate_change/downloads/assessing_alternatives_climate_change_nef.pdf Accessed 28 February 2012
  • Stern , N . 2006 . Stern Review on the Economics of Climate Change , London : HM Treasury .
  • Sturzenegger , F and Zettelmeyer , J . 2007 . Debt Defaults and Lessons from a Decade of Crises , Cambridge, MA : MIT Press .
  • Thompson , A A . 1968 . The social benefits of tax-exempt industrial development bonds . Financial Analysts Journal , 24 ( 6 ) : 99 – 103 .
  • UNEP/SEF Alliance . 2010 . “ Publicly backed guarantees as policy instruments to promote clean energy ” . United Nations Environment Program/Sustainable Energy Finance (SEF Alliance), Nairobi, Kenya. www.unep.fr/energy/finance/pdf/guarantees_web.pdf Accessed 28 February 2012
  • UNFCCC (United Nations Framework Convention on Climate Change) . 2008 . Investment and Financial Flows to Address Climate Change , Germany : UNFCCC, Bonn . http://unfccc.int/resource/docs/2008/tp/07.pdf Accessed 28 February 2012
  • Veys , A . 2010 . The Sterling Bonds Markets and Low-carbon or Green Bonds , London : E3G .
  • Ward , M , Garibaldi , J A , Hampton , K , Höhne , N , Jung , M , Bakir , A and Gray , S . 2009 . “ Scaling up investment in climate change mitigation activities ” . In Paper prepared for Carbon Finance Unit , Washington, DC : World Bank . http://wbcarbonfinance.org/docs/Scaling_up_investment_in_Climate_mitigation_and_CPF.pdf Accessed 28 February 2012
  • World Bank . 2010 . “ Beyond the sum of its parts: Combining financial instruments for impact and efficiency ” . In Development, Climate and Finance Issues Brief No. 3 , Washington, DC : The World Bank Group .
  • Zervos , S . 2004 . “ The transaction costs of primary market issuance: The case of Brazil, Chile, Mexico ” . In World Bank Policy Research Working Paper 3424 , Washington, DC : World Bank .

Reprints and Corporate Permissions

Please note: Selecting permissions does not provide access to the full text of the article, please see our help page How do I view content?

To request a reprint or corporate permissions for this article, please click on the relevant link below:

Academic Permissions

Please note: Selecting permissions does not provide access to the full text of the article, please see our help page How do I view content?

Obtain permissions instantly via Rightslink by clicking on the button below:

If you are unable to obtain permissions via Rightslink, please complete and submit this Permissions form. For more information, please visit our Permissions help page.