678
Views
11
CrossRef citations to date
0
Altmetric
Articles

Farm households' participation in rural non-farm employment in post-war Rwanda: Drivers and policy implications

(PhD student) , (Impact Assessment Specialist) & (Senior Lecturer)

Abstract

Despite the post-war government's unprecedented efforts to stimulate growth of the rural non-farm (RNF) sector in Rwanda, evidence suggests that participation in this sector remains low compared with other developing and transition economies. This study investigates the micro and meso-level factors defining farm household's capacity and incentives to participate in RNF employment in the post-war Rwanda. Based on the household's time allocation theory, this study employs household survey data collected in Gisagara District in a double-hurdle regression. The results reveal that female-headedness, labour availability, education, social networks, access to finance and rural towns increase the probability of participating in RNF activities, whereas for participating households, the time allocated to RNF activities tends to decrease with age, land productivity, distance to market and dispersed settlements. The article concludes with key implications for rural development policies such as basic education and umudugudu settlements.

1. Introduction

Rural economic transformation through livelihood incomes diversification remains a challenge for developing countries, particularly in Africa (Davis et al., Citation2010; Winters et al., Citation2010). The recent decades were marked by increasing emphasis by development researchers and policy-makers on the role of the rural non-farm (RNF) sector in spurring development at meso and micro levels. For resource-limited and agriculturally backwards regions, the thrusts in promoting RNF sectors are expected to generate multiple benefits, including absorption of the unemployed or underemployed labour force in agriculture and slowing down rural–urban migration (Clay et al., Citation1990; Elbers & Lanjouw, Citation2001; Gordon & Craig, Citation2001; Lanjouw & Lanjouw, Citation2001; Knight & Song, Citation2003; de Janvry et al., Citation2005; Zhu & Luo, Citation2006; Haggblade et al., Citation2010). At the micro level, particularly for resource-limited households, promotion of the RNF sector is a pathway to food security in the face of low farm productivity and shocks, and to serve as a risk management strategy or safety net in the face of dysfunctional credit and insurance markets (Reardon, Citation1997; Schneider & Gugerty, Citation2011).

This consideration underscores the relevance of RNF sector promotion for the development of countries with largely subsistence-oriented agricultural economies such as Rwanda. The country is characterised by galloping population growth (Wali et al., Citation2011) on a small arable land surface (Jayne et al., Citation2010). Currently, the country's primary agriculture employs around 80% of the population and contributes to the overall gross domestic product to a level of 36% (World Bank, Citation2011). This performance of the agricultural economy is realised in spite of low and declining farm size, coupled with issues of overreliance on highly variable rainfall, largely hilly terrains, and declining soil fertility caused by soil erosion and overexploitation of arable lands as indicated by previous studies (Clay, Citation1995; Byiringiro & Reardon, Citation1996; Clay et al., Citation1998), and hence the growing number of people engaged in mostly subsistence farming. These problems are exacerbated by several factors, including the tenure insecurity, the weak agricultural research base and extension system, the lack of agricultural finance services, the missing or failing agricultural markets, and the poor rural infrastructure, causing little technological progress (Reardon et al., Citation1995; Musahara & Huggins, Citation2005; Musahara, Citation2006; Jayne et al., Citation2010; Pritchard, Citation2013).

Analyses of labour productivity in rural Rwanda unveiled low and declining farm labour productivity, suggesting that, from a static microeconomic viewpoint, the poor have better opportunities in off-farm employment. Byiringiro & Reardon (Citation1996) found that the marginal value product of farm labour among the poor households was below the off-farm labour market wage. They also showed that diversified households were less poor. Dabalen et al. (Citation2004) further found that RNF employments generate higher returns compared with other off-farm activities, and farm households diversifying their income-generation strategy into the RNF sector are less likely to be poor and have higher consumption levels compared with specialised farm households. These findings imply that poor farmers should spend more of their labour time in RNF employments. This in turn, as argued by Clay et al. (Citation1995), would increase incomes and facilitate investment in soil fertility and land improvement, and ultimately household income.

The deepening of poverty among farming communities and the low labour productivity in agriculture have led Rwandan policy-makers to design new policies and strategies aimed at reducing rural poverty. Under its Vision 2020 that sets out to transform the country from an agrarian to a knowledge-based middle-class economy (Republic of Rwanda, Citation2000), the country has adopted a two-pronged rural development strategy, focusing on both farm and non-farm sectors. The former focuses on increasing the performance of the agricultural sector through targeted interventions (Republic of Rwanda, Citation2009). On the other hand, an unprecedented attention has been given to the promotion of the RNF sector to ease the pressure on agriculture as a major employer. Policies such as the umudugudu (i.e. agglomerated) settlements (Isaksson, Citation2011), small-scale agro-based industry development (Republic of Rwanda, Citation2011), rural financial services development (Papias & Ganesan, Citation2010; Republic of Rwanda & DFID, Citation2011), and the labour-intensive local development programmes (Republic of Rwanda, Citation2008) underscore this strategic intent.

Theoretically, both market and policy-level incentives are expected to generate increased participation rates in the RNF sector among farm households. However, empirical evidence reveals a noteworthy discrepancy between the pre-war and post-war eras. When Clay et al. (Citation1990) investigated the emergence of non-farm employment in Rwanda using the 1988 Nonfarm Strategy Survey, they found that close to 32% of Rwandan farm households engage in non-farm employment. However, studies conducted in the post-war era by Dabalen et al. (2004), Strode et al. (Citation2007), and NSIR (Citation2011), using the 2004, 2007, and 2010 Integrated Rwanda Household Living Conditions Survey (EICV), respectively, found that only around 20% of farm households are employed in the RNF sector, with a minimal rate of expansion. This rate of participation in RNF employment is among the lowest in developing and transition countries.

The authors have argued simplistically that this discrepancy could be due to the 1994 war and genocide that destroyed the social and economic base of the country. This assertion is simplistic and disregards the unprecedented efforts made by the post-war government of Rwanda to revitalise the rural economy through promotion of the RNF sector. It overlooks the potential influences that certain micro and meso-level factors exert on RNF employment participation, leaving a vacuum in the understanding of other confounding factors. This study aims at addressing this knowledge gap by primarily examining capacity factors conditioning farm households' participation in RNF employment in the post-war Rwanda at the current market and policy incentive levels.

The remainder of this article is organised into three sections. The subsequent section elicits the theoretical underpinning of the study, as well as the empirical model and data collection technique adopted. This is followed by a section discussing the results of the econometric estimation. Lastly, a concluding section outlines the major policy implications.

2. Methods

2.1 Theoretical framework

This study is based on household's non-farm labour supply theory, as developed by Huffman (Citation1980) and Gebauer (Citation1988). The basic concept of non-farm employment participation decisions is the trade-off between leisure (all non-work activities) and consumption goods for individuals in a farm household. Farm household members are assumed to maximise a unitary household utility function (U) (with consumption goods and leisure as arguments, and exogenous preferences structures, human capital and household's locational characteristics), subject to time, income, and farm production constraints, as follows:Footnote4

After simple mathematicalFootnote5 simplifications of the constraints, theFootnote6 model becomes:

The correspondingFootnote7 Lagrangian function can be written as follows:

Solving the set of first-order conditions of Equation (6), an interior solution for the optimal allocation of time between leisure, farm and/or non-farm work is determined by:

The non-farm market-wage rate should in optimum be equal to the marginal rate of substitution of leisure and consumption. is the value of marginal productivity of labour on-farm. Optimal labour use in agriculture requires that this value is equal to the non-farm wage rate; that is, the opportunity cost of family labour. A farm household will choose to work more on farm if marginal productivity of labour on-farm is above the non-farm market wage rate (). If marginal productivity of labour in on-farm work is less than the wage rate, then the household will work more non-farm hours. This participation decision rule can be summarised as follows:

2.2 Empirical model

To estimate empirically the participation decision rule in Equation (8) as well as the intensity of participation thereof, this study adopts a double-hurdle econometric technique (Blundell et al., Citation1987; Matshe & Young, Citation2004; Moffatt, Citation2005; Ground & Koch, Citation2008; Paul et al., Citation2008). Under this econometric technique, a farmer has to cross two hurdles to become participant in RNF employment. A farmer may be a potential participant after crossing the “first hurdle”. Given that a farmer is a potential participant, the socio-economic scenario will lead to actual participation. This is termed the “second hurdle”. The double-hurdle model is aFootnote8 two-equation framework:

where:

The log-likelihood function for the double-hurdle model is:

The analysis of marginal effect helps to assess the impact of the exogenous variables on the dependent variables. To do so, the unconditional mean is decomposed into the effect on the probability of participating and the effect on the conditional level of participation and differentiating these components with respect to each explanatory variable. The unconditional mean can be written as:

The probability of participation and the work hours conditional on participation are:

and

For the discrete or categorical variables, the marginal effects are used to calculate percentage changes in the dependent variable when the variable shifts from zero to one, ceteris paribus.

In this study, the regression analysis of the decision to participate (Equation (12)) is estimated using probit regression and the second stage (Equation (13)) is calibrated using a truncated regression.

2.3 Data

The household-level data used in this study were collected in Gisagara District of the Southern Province (see ) from May to June in 2009. The purposive selection of Gisagara District was based on its diversely rich demographic, agro-climatic, and economic characteristics, which could be representative of other rural regions of the country. It is one of the districts making up the Southern Province. The district is classified as a rural district by the Rwanda National Institute of Statistics, based on population density and indicators of remoteness. Gisagara District is also one of Rwanda's smallest districts, with a surface area of 816.4 square kilometres (km2) and a population of 267,161 inhabitants. It is one of the districts with the highest population densities in Rwanda (more than 320 inhabitants per km2), although this density is not equally distributed across its administrative sectors, with some recording up to 550 inhabitants per km2, reflecting the problem of acute land scarcity and environmental degradation. Around 54% of the Gisagara District population is female.

Figure 1: Map of Gisagara District

Source: District's official website (www.gisagaradistrict.gov.rw).
Figure 1: Map of Gisagara District

With an altitude ranging between 1600 and 1800 metres and a bi-modal rainfall regime, the district cuts across two agro-ecological zones: the Dorsale Granitique zone characterised by soil with sandy-clay loam texture and high gravel content; and the Plateau Central with similar soil texture but lower gravel content (Steiner, Citation1998). The relief is marked with slope inclinations ranging from 13 to 25%, and soil erosion defines the micro-scale soil suitability for key crops such as maize, sorghum, beans, potatoes, cassava, soy and banana (Steiner, Citation1998).

Although the majority of community members farm at a subsistence level, the district has some well-organised commercial farmers such as rice and coffee growers. Coffee and (to some extent) rice are the only cash crops grown in the district. Agricultural processing (coffee-washing stations and rice-processing factory) is the major agro-industry found in the district. Small-scale coltan and cassiterite mining activities are also found in the area. The tertiary sector is mainly comprised of retail commerce, transport services, construction, and artisanship.

Although the habitat of the district is predominantly dispersed settlements, the umudugudu (or conglomeration) settlements as well as rural towns are common in some sectors. The district possesses a dense road network, even though the majority is rough roads. Access to infrastructure such as electricity is limited to areas near roads, especially the highway and major rough roads. Only three out of the 13 sectors in Gisagara District have access to electricity. Commercial centres (shops, banks, businesses) are also located in areas served by country roads and the electricity.

Data were collected from a random cross-section of 241 farm households, generated using a multistage stratified sampling technique, where stratification was based on differences in area's non-farm labour market potentiality. From a review of the literature, the potentiality is portrayed by population density and proximity to rural and urban towns. In total, 498 adult members (i.e. in the official age of employment and not currently attending full-time studies) of the selected households were interviewed using a structured questionnaire. Details of the sample design can be found in .

Table 1: Sampling design

The dependent variable was generated using the typology shown in . It is based on the definition of RNF employment proposed by Barrett et al. (Citation2001); that is, all income-earning activities outside the primary agricultural sector, regardless of location or function. In most cases, a household has one distinct occupation that it considers primary, and to which more labour time is allocated, relative to other activities. Stylised questions depicting time allocation to various activities in a typical day/week (Bryant et al., Citation2004) were employed to measure household's labour time allocation.

Figure 2: Structural diagram for rural employment participation

Source: Authors’ typology.
Figure 2: Structural diagram for rural employment participation

A detailed description of the dependent variable in reveals that although agriculture remains the major employer in Gisagara District, 18.5% of interviewed farm household members (25% of the households) engage in some form of non-farm employment. Low-skilled labour dominates among self-employment and wage employment. The Pearson chi-square statistic suggests that among Gisagara farmers the preference for secondary jobs tends to vary according to sex. Females prefer to undertake low-skilled non-farm activities as their secondary source of income, whereas men go for own farming as their secondary job. This shows that there is division of labour among surveyed household members.

Table 2: Sectoral distribution of individual activities by gender

presents the distribution of individuals within participating households by field and gender. It shows that when the members of farm households seek non-farm employment, it is most commonly in restaurant and accommodation services, retail commerce, and construction works. The remaining non-farm time is spent in textile and straw manufacturing, transport and education. indicates that Gisagara women exhibit more preference for retail trade and manufacturing activities.

Table 3: Distribution of non-farm activities by sub-sector and gender

2.4 Independent variables and theoretical expectation

In the presence of fixed-cost market entry and unemployment, two groups of individuals will record zero hours of work (Blundell et al., Citation1987): a group consisting of those who do not want to work at their market wage; and another group consisting of those who want to work but remain unemployed. For the first group of farmers, the first hurdle reflects the proxies of fixed (time and money) costs of entry causing individuals not willing to work below a minimum number of work hours, commonly referred to as reservation hours (Cogan, Citation1981). The size of discontinuity depends on the individual's preference function, as defined by gender, education, labour availability and opportunity cost (Cogan, Citation1981).

Moreover, the first hurdle introduces local demand factors directly into the labour market model, reflecting the observable unemployment factors for individuals wishing to work (Blundell et al., Citation1987). Such demand variables affect P(Yi > 0) directly through their effect on the probability of finding employment or indirectly through their effect on wage rates. The impact of these factors over time and regions provides useful information on the degree to which zero hours of work reflect unemployment as opposed to desired non-participation (Blundell et al., Citation1987).

In the second hurdle, observable and unobservable factors constrain the farmers' time allocation choice set. For example, if the two discrete hours' packages (part-time, full-time) are all that is available, then household labour supply decisions will reflect this and will depend on the actual discrete labour market outcomes rather than the underlying latent hours' variables (Blundell & Smith, Citation1994).

For this study, the variables indicating the micro-level and regional factors are presented in . These variables are drawn from the conceptual literature review by Barrett et al. (Citation2001) and Reardon et al. (2007), and were selected based on the log-likelihood ratio test (Wooldridge, Citation2002). These variables are arranged in accordance with the scale level, from micro-level assets towards meso-level factors (Reardon et al., Citation2007).

Table 4: Description of independent variables used in the double-hurdle regression model

presents the key descriptive statistics and results of tests of differences in means between participants in RNF employment and non-participants. The table suggests that most participating households are headed by women. Participating households have more than two adults. Education levels among interviewed households also differ significantly between the two groups, suggesting that households with more schooled members are likely to participate in RNF employment.

Table 5: Descriptive statistics of variables used in the econometric model

Descriptive statistics also show significant differences in farm characteristics between participants in RNF employment and their counterparts. Participating households have significantly more non-land assets and lower agricultural income than their counterparts. Among institutional factors, there is significant difference in density of group membership between participating and non-participating households, suggesting that participants are those households with good access to social networks. There are also statistically significant differences between participants and non-participants with regard to access to microfinance institutions. For economic and demographic factors, there is a statistically significant difference with regard to population density.

3. Results and discussion

The results of the double-hurdle regression technique are presented in and . The goodness of fit was tested using a log-likelihood ratio test (Wooldridge, Citation2002), and the test results indicated that the variables used in the chosen models give the best fit. The results of the examination of the correlation coefficients of the variables used in the quantitative models suggest that multicollinearity in not a serious problem. To curb potential heteroscedasticity, this study used the heteroscedasticity-robust standard errors for parameter estimates. To measure and correct the possible sample selection bias in this model, the probit model in the first stage was used to generate a sample selection correction term referred to as the inverse Mills ratio (IMR), and then used as an explanatory variable in the truncated model (Wooldridge Citation2002).

Table 6: Determinants of farm household participation in RNF employment: results estimated using probit regression

Table 7: Determinants of time allocation to RNF employment: results estimated using truncated regression

3.1 Determinants of the decision to participate in RNF employment

The results from the probit regression model (first hurdle) are presented in . Based on the marginal effects, household-specific factors turn out to be major drivers of RNF participation decisions through reduced reservation hours. These results show that female-headedness adds significantly 5.3% chance of engaging in RNF jobs, ceteris paribus, implying that farm households that become female-headed reduce their reservation hours. These results can be explained by the congruence of childcare responsibilities and other social expectations that limit women's mobility, forcing them into home-based non-farm works (Haggblade et al., Citation2010). Although these results corroborate empirical findings of studies in neighbouring countries such as Uganda (Canagarajah et al., Citation2001) and Kenya (Lay et al., Citation2008), the peculiarity of the Rwanda case is that the exclusion from land inheritance on females imposed by the pre-war constitution could have forced those who become head of households to seek ways of earning a livelihood outside agriculture.

The results also show the number of adult workers living in a farm household is a strong predictor of household participation in the RNF sector. One extra adult adds 13.2% probability of engaging in RNF activities, suggesting a sort of intra-household division of labour created particularly when the available manpower exceeds on-farm labour requirements. As Rosenzweig & Wolpin (Citation1985) explain, family extension facilitates occupational diversification and thus serves to reduce income risk. This in turn reduces farm household's reservation hours in the RNF labour markets.

As expected, education also turns out to be a significant socio-economic capacity driver of the decision to take up RNF works. This suggests that households with educated people are likely to possess the skills needed to participate in the RNF sector either as self-employed entrepreneurs or as wage workers, such as the ability to manage a business, process-relevant information, adapt to changing demand patterns, and liaise with public and private service providers (Wandschneider, Citation2003). Although the response of the RNF labour supply to education levels in farm households is lower due to the fact that education and experience increases managerial efficiency in both farm and non-farm activities (Rosenzweig, Citation1980), Sadoulet et al. (1998) demonstrate that only unskilled labour would respond positively to shadow the farm wage rise. Therefore, education increases farmers' confidence and aspiration towards working off their farms (Reardon, Citation1997). This finding corroborates the evidence that the returns to education are higher in the off-farm labour market than on the farm (Fafchamps & Quisumbing, Citation1999).

With regard to social capital, the regression results indicates that, all other factors remaining constant, joining one more community organisation group increases significantly the probability of participating in RNF employment by 3.2%. This finding suggests that positive participation decisions are constrained by the congruence of fixed transaction costs, as explained by Traikova et al. (Citation2007). Fixed transaction costs (mainly pertaining to imperfect information) force farm households to defer their market participation decisions (Key et al., Citation2000). Information networks therefore play a critical role in job search (e.g. through referrals) (Ioannides & Loury, Citation2004). This finding implies that farm households who have access and claims to a wider social networks are more likely to take advantage of their informational supports to reduce the extent of transaction costs they face in the RNF labour markets (Fafchamps & Minten, Citation1998; Zhang & Li, Citation2003; Traikova et al., Citation2007).

On local economic and demographic characteristics, the results show that the distance to the nearest microfinance organisation negatively predicts the decision to engage in RNF activities. These results suggest that longer distances to financial organisations constrain farmers' access to financial resources needed to draw labour out of the farms to become RNF entrepreneurs (Deininger et al., Citation2007; Papias & Ganesan, Citation2010). As Khandker et al. (Citation2013) demonstrate, inadequate access to finance constitutes a disincentive to the RNF enterprise through reduced profitability.

The results also indicate that the population density significantly affects the likelihood of engaging in RNF activities, suggesting that, on one hand, high population density may put pressure on agricultural land available to a household, creating the impetus to seek employment in RNF sector; or, on the other hand, high population may create a derived demand for non-farm goods and services that increases the scope of jobs and business opportunities in the non-farm sector (Reardon et al., Citation1998). This finding corroborates the evidence that high returns to RNF activities are more concentrated around urban agglomerations (Deichmann et al., 2009). These meso-level factors therefore define the extent of unemployment among farm households willing to work in the RNF sector.

3.2 Determinants of the intensity of participation in RNF employment

For the truncated regression model, the self-selection bias is corrected for by generating the IMR for each household using the probit model. The IMR is then included as an explanatory variable in the subsequent truncated regression. Since both hurdles do not have equal vectors of explanatory variables due to the exclusion of three variables (group membership, trust, and distance to microfinance organisation) in the intensity model, the IMR cannot be correlated with the vector of explanatory variables in the truncated regression model (Wooldridge, Citation2002). The results are presented in . The coefficient of the IMR turns out to be statistically insignificant in the truncated model, indicating that self-selection was not an issue.

On household-specific characteristics, the regression results show that the mean age of a household member affects negatively the time allocated in the non-farm sector, suggesting that, given positive participation decision, time allocation choice sets reduces with the mean age of an adult in the household. As Leinbach & Smith's (1994) model (based on the Chayanovian model) demonstrates, younger households with higher consumer-to-labour ratio tend to participate more in off-farm works due to higher demand for family labour and labour shortage, and this trend falls as the household moves to later stages of the demographic lifecycle. This result supports the view that labour flexibility and risk-taking decrease over the lifecycle (Bodie et al. Citation1992).

Unexpectedly, the sign of the slope position turns out to be negative and significant, suggesting that the time allocated to RNF activities decreases with increasing scope of soil erosion uphill. A plausible explanation is that, although the erosion process is highly pronounced at the convex slopes uphill, these parts of the landscape generally remain relatively undeveloped and more productive than the concavities downhill often characterised by deeply weathered parent materials (Steiner, Citation1998). Therefore, the results imply that higher implicit farm wages uphill tend to lower RNF employment efforts (Goodwin & Mishra, Citation2004).

With regard to regional factors, the results indicate that the distance to the nearest market and shopping centres reduces the amount of household labour time allocated to the RNF activities. This result reflects a von Thünen-like model, suggesting that even though the demand for RNF activities could be more pronounced in remote areas, the effect of (proportional) transaction costs such as transport cost outweigh the positive RNF response to reduced land values in remote areas (Jones, Citation1984), creating underemployment in this sector.

Finally, the results show that population density positively influences the time allocated to the RNF activities. This finding suggests that conglomerated settlement increases the time allocation choice sets available to farm households willing to participate in RNF activities, thereby reducing the extent of underemployment in the RNF sector. This finding corroborates the empirical evidence showing that RNF employment declines quickly as one leaves urban areas and moves into the hinterland (Fafchamps & Shilpi, Citation2003).

4. Conclusion

From the analysis of the results reported in the previous section, one can conclude that the ability to take advantages or respond to the RNF employment opportunities brought about by the market and policy incentives in post-war Rwanda has been confounded by differential access to livelihood assets (human, social, natural, and financial assets) coupled with regional economic and demographic circumstances. The double-hurdle econometric estimation results suggest that female-headedness, labour availability, education and social networks reduce the RNF work reservation hours, thereby increasing the probability of positive participation decision. They also suggest that age and land productivity reduce farmers' time allocation choice sets. Furthermore, the positive influence of regional factors such as access to finance and population density on the participation decision implies a certain scope of underemployment among farm households willing to work in the RNF sector, whereas the effect of market access and population on the labour supply reflects the scope of underemployment.

These empirical results raise several issues pertaining to farm households' integration into the RNF sector, if poor households are to take full advantage of expanding economic opportunities offered by economic growth in post-war Rwanda. The first challenge revolves around human capital formation in rural areas of Rwanda. The finding that human capital conditions the ability to participate in RNF employment calls for increased investment of resources in village schools and other vocational and adult educations. The Government of Rwanda and its development partners need to allocate more efforts in raising education funds for the most vulnerable strata of Rwandan society such as women and the poor. Therefore, the results of this study strongly support the free primary education policy launched in 2004. Drawing parallels with the recommendations of Yabiku & Schlabach (Citation2009), the present study recommends that this policy should not only emphasise enrolment, but also completion.

The second challenge lies within the balancing of sectoral development strategies. The finding that farm-specific characteristics do influence the farmers' income diversification strategy implies that policy-makers should recognise the complementarities of agriculture and non-agricultural activities in the development of rural economies and hence in sustaining livelihoods in rural areas of Rwanda. Focusing on both sectors (i.e. farm and non-farm) has the advantage of generating forward–backward production linkages and rural–urban linkages that can promote simultaneous development of the two sectors.

The third challenge relates to development of local institutions and organisations. The finding that participation in local organisation such as farmers' groups, microfinance, and so forth, increases farm household's likelihood of participation in RNF employment implies that local institutions and organisation have a significant say in rural poverty alleviation through access to non-farm employment resources and markets. This calls on the necessity to devise a social capital development strategy relevant to war aftermaths, a strategy that should focus more on bridging than on bonding ties to ensure that beneficial organisations thrive around them. Furthermore, the government will need to empower local organisation through direct actions (such as capacity-building, leadership training) and/or indirect actions (such as creating a democratic, open and corruption-free environment).

The fourth challenge resides in stimulating services and infrastructure in rural settlement schemes and rural areas in general. The findings of this study support the microfinance revolution underway in Rwanda which extends the financial services to historically underserved areas such as Umurenge (administrative sector) Savings and Credit Cooperatives. The finding that access to the market allows greater integration of farm households into the RNF sector strongly supports the local economic development approach based on collaborative efforts by the public sector, private entrepreneurs and the local communities in the identification and facilitation of local competitive edges for locally based, self-reliant markets.

Lastly, the finding that rural towns promote RNF employment opportunities and social networks determine the ability to take up such opportunities strongly supports the ongoing agglomeration (umudugudu) settlements policy in Rwanda. This strategy evolved from a post-genocide resettlement programme consisting of closely spaced dwellings meant for genocide survivors and returnees, which became compulsory relocation and villagisation policy, aiming at community welfare and social cohesion through social networking (Bruce, Citation2007).

Attention should therefore be given to these micro and meso factors during the design and implementation of the strategies aiming at rural economic transformation in post-war Rwanda.

Acknowledgement

The authors are grateful to the African Economic Research Consortium (AERC) for the award of the scholarship grant which made this study possible.

Notes

4Definitions: C, consumption goods; D, leisure; XM, quantity of market goods; XC, quantity of home-grown goods; T, total time available; HF, on-farm work hours; HN, non-farm work hours; L, leisure; E, exogenous preferences structures; H, human capital; G, household's locational characteristics; WF, farm wage; WN, non-farm wage; V, unearned income; PQ, the anticipated price of farm outputs; PZ, price of non-labour variable inputs; PM, price of marketed goods; Z, quantity of non-labour variable inputs; WF, on-farm wage rate; L, hired labour hours; LD, labour demand; Q, farm output; K, farm specific characteristics.

5 and .

6 LD = HF + L.

7Assuming competitiveness in inputs and output markets, and were simplified into P.

8The diagonality of the covariance matrix shows that the two error terms are assumed to be independently distributed; is the binary choice variable in Equation (8); Z is a vector of capacity factors explaining the decision to participate in RNF employment, whereas α represents their respective influences; the second forumla of Equation (9) explains the factors affecting the extent of participation ( is the latent variable that reflects farmer's time allocation in RNF employment), X, and β being the vector of factor explaining the intensity of participation and their influences respectively; and the observed variable, Yi, is determined as .

References

  • Barrett, CB, Reardon, T & Webb, P, 2001. Nonfarm income diversification and household livelihood strategies in rural Africa: Concepts, dynamics, and policy implications. Food Policy 26, 315–31. doi: 10.1016/S0306-9192(01)00014-8
  • Bittman, M, England, P, Sayer, L, Folbre, N & Matheson, G, 2003. When does gender trump money? Bargaining and time in household work. American Journal of Sociology 109, 186–214. doi: 10.1086/378341
  • Blundell, R & Smith, R.J, 1994. Coherency and estimation in simultaneous models with censored or qualitative dependent variables. Journal of Econometrics 64, 355–73. doi: 10.1016/0304-4076(94)90069-8
  • Blundell, R., Ham, J & Meghir, C, 1987. Unemployment and female labour supply. The Economic Journal 97, 44–64. doi: 10.2307/3038229
  • Bodie, Z., Merton, RC & Samuelson, WF, 1992. Labor supply flexibility and portfolio choice in a life-cycle model. NBER Working Paper No. 3954, National Bureau of Economic Research, Cambridge, MA.
  • Bruce, JW, 2007. Returnee land access: Lessons from Rwanda. Humanitarian Policy Group Background Briefing, London, UK.
  • Bryant, WK, Hyojin, K, Cathleen, DZ & Anna, YC, 2004. Measuring housework in time use surveys. Review of Economics of the Household 2, 23–47. doi: 10.1023/B:REHO.0000018021.36768.37
  • Byiringiro, F & Reardon, T, 1996. Farm productivity in Rwanda: Effects of farm size, erosion, and soil conservation investments. Agricultural Economics 15, 127–36. doi: 10.1016/S0169-5150(96)01201-7
  • Canagarajah, S, Newman, C & Bhattamishra, R, 2001. Non-farm income, gender, and inequality: Evidence from rural Ghana and Uganda. Food Policy 26, 405–20. doi: 10.1016/S0306-9192(01)00011-2
  • Chowdhury, SK, 2010. Impact of infrastructures on paid work opportunities and unpaid work burdens on rural women in Bangladesh. Journal of International Development 22, 997–1017. doi: 10.1002/jid.1607
  • Clay, D, 1995. Fighting an uphill battle: Population pressure and declining land productivity in Rwanda. Research in Rural Sociology and Development 6, 95–122.
  • Clay, D, Byiringiro, F, Kangasniemi, J, Reardon, T, Sibomana, B, Uwamariya, L & Tardif-Douglin, D, 1995. Promoting food security in Rwanda through sustainable agricultural productivity: Meeting the challenges of population pressure, land degradation, and poverty. Food Security International Development Papers No. 6, Michigan State University, East Lansing, MI.
  • Clay, D, Kampayana, T & Kayitsinga, J, 1990. Inequality and the emergence of nonfarm employment in Rwanda. In Johnson, NE & Wang, C (Eds.), Changing Rural Social Systems: Adaptation and Survival. Michigan State University Press, East Lansing, MI, 93–110.
  • Clay, D, Reardon, T & Kangasniemi, J, 1998. Sustainable intensification in the highland tropics: Rwandan farmers’ investments in land conservation and soil fertility. Economic Development and Cultural Change 46, 351–78. doi: 10.1086/452342
  • Cogan, JF, 1981. Fixed costs and labor supply. Econometrica 49, 945–63. doi: 10.2307/1912512
  • Dabalen, A., Paternostro, S & Pierre, G, 2004. The returns to participation in the nonfarm sector in rural Rwanda. World Bank Policy Research Working Paper No. 3462, The World Bank, Washington, DC.
  • Davis, B, Winters, P & Carletto G, 2010. A cross-country comparison of rural income generating activities. World Development 38, 48–63. doi: 10.1016/j.worlddev.2009.01.003
  • Deichmann, U, Shilpi, F & Vakis, R, 2009. Urban proximity, agricultural potential and rural nonfarm employment: Evidence from Bangladesh. World Development 37, 645–60. doi: 10.1016/j.worlddev.2008.08.008
  • Deininger, K, Jin, S & Sur, M, 2007. Sri Lanka's rural non-farm economy: Removing constraints to pro-poor growth. World Development 35, 2056–78. doi: 10.1016/j.worlddev.2007.02.007
  • de Janvry, A, Sadoulet, E & Zhu, N, 2005. The role of nonfarm incomes in reducing poverty and inequality in China. CUDARE Working Paper 1001, University of California, Berkeley, CA.
  • Elbers, C & Lanjouw, P, 2001. Intersectoral transfer, growth, and inequality in rural Ecuador. World Development 29, 481–96. doi: 10.1016/S0305-750X(00)00110-8
  • Fafchamps, M & Minten, C, 1998. Returns to social capital amongst traders. arkets and Structural Studies Division Discussion Paper No. 23, IFPRI, Washington DC.
  • Fafchamps, M & Quisumbing, A, 1999. Human capital productivity and labor allocation in rural Pakistan. Journal of Human Resources 34, 369–406. doi: 10.2307/146350
  • Fafchamps, M & Shilpi, F, 2003. The spatial division of labour in Nepal. Journal of Development Studies 39, 23–66. doi: 10.1080/00220380312331293577
  • Fernandez-Cornejo, J, Mishra, AK, Nehring, RF, Hendricks, C, Southern, M & Gregory, A, 2007. Off-farm income, technology adoption, and farm economic performance. Economic Research Report No. 36, United States Department of Agriculture, Washington, DC.
  • Gebauer, RH, 1988. Nonfarm labour supply: Theory and estimation. Staff Papers Series No. 88-34, University of Minnesota, Minneapolis, MN.
  • Gibson, J & Olivia, S, 2010. The effect of infrastructure access and quality on non-farm enterprises in rural Indonesia. World Development 38, 717–26. doi: 10.1016/j.worlddev.2009.11.010
  • Goodwin, BK & Mishra, AK, 2004. Farming efficiency and the determinants of multiple job holding by farm operators. American Journal of Agricultural Economics 86, 722–9. doi: 10.1111/j.0002-9092.2004.00614.x
  • Gordon, A & Craig, C, 2001. Rural nonfarm activities and poverty alleviation in sub-Saharan Africa. Policy Series No.14, Natural Resources Institute, University of Greenwich, UK.
  • Ground, M & Koch, S, 2008. Hurdle models of alcohol and tobacco expenditure in South African households. South African Journal of Economics 76, 132–43. doi: 10.1111/j.1813-6982.2008.00156.x
  • Haggblade S, Hazell, P & Reardon, T, 2010. The rural non-farm economy: Prospects for growth and poverty reduction. World Development 38, 1429–41. doi: 10.1016/j.worlddev.2009.06.008
  • Huffman, WE, 1980. Farm and off-farm work decisions: The role of human capital. The Review of Economics and Statistics 62, 14–23. doi: 10.2307/1924268
  • Ioannides, YM & Loury, LD, 2004. Job information networks, neighborhood effects, and inequality. Journal of Economic Literature 42, 1056–93. doi: 10.1257/0022051043004595
  • Isaksson, AS, 2011. Manipulating the rural landscape: Villagisation and income generation in Rwanda. Working Papers in Economics No. 510, University of Gothenburg, Sweden.
  • Jayne, TS, Mather, D & Mghenyi, E, 2010. Principal challenges confronting smallholder agriculture in sub-Saharan Africa. World Development 38, 1384–98. doi: 10.1016/j.worlddev.2010.06.002
  • Jones, DW, 1984. Farm location and off-farm employment: An analysis of spatial risk strategies. Transactions of the Institute of British Geographers 9, 106–23. doi: 10.2307/621870
  • Key, N, Sadoulet, E & De Janvry, A, 2000. Transactions costs and agricultural household supply response. American Journal of Agricultural Economics 82, 245–59. doi: 10.1111/0002-9092.00022
  • Khandker, SR, Samad, HA & Ali, R, 2013. Does access to finance matter in microenterprise growth? Evidence from Bangladesh. World Bank Policy Research Working Paper No. 6333, World Bank, Washington, DC.
  • Knight, J & Song, L, 2003. Chinese peasant choices: Migration, rural industry, or farming. Oxford Development Studies 31, 123–47. doi: 10.1080/13600810307427
  • Lanjouw, JO & Lanjouw, P, 2001. The rural nonfarm sector: Issues and evidence from developing countries. Agricultural Economics 26, 1–23. doi: 10.1111/j.1574-0862.2001.tb00051.x
  • Lay, J, Mahmoud, TO & M'Mukaria, GM, 2008. Few opportunities, much desperation: The Dichotomy of non-agricultural activities and inequality in western Kenya. World Development 36, 2713–32. doi: 10.1016/j.worlddev.2007.12.003
  • Leinbach, TR & Smith, A, 1994. Off-farm employment, land, and life cycle: Transmigrant households in South Sumatra, Indonesia. Economic Geography 70, 273–96. doi: 10.2307/143994
  • Matshe, I & Young, T, 2004. Off-farm labour allocation decisions in small-scale rural households in Zimbabwe. Agricultural Economics 30, 175–86. doi: 10.1111/j.1574-0862.2004.tb00186.x
  • Moffatt, PG, 2005. Hurdle models of loan default. Journal of the Operations Research Society 56, 1063–71. doi: 10.1057/palgrave.jors.2601922
  • Musahara, H, 2006. Improving tenure security for the rural poor: Rwanda – country case study. Legal Empowerment of the Poor (LEP) Working Paper No. 7, Food and Agriculture Oorganization , Rome, Italy.
  • Musahara, H & Huggins, C, 2005. Land reform, land scarcity, and post-conflict reconstruction: A case study of Rwanda. In Huggins, C & Clover, J (Eds.), From the Ground Up: Land Rights, Conflict and Peace in sub-Saharan Africa. African Centre for Technology Studies & Institute for Security Studies, Nairobi and Pretoria, 269–346.
  • NISR (National Institute of Statistics of Rwanda), 2011. The Third Integrated Household Living Conditions Survey (EICV3): Main Indicators Report. NISR, Kigali, Rwanda.
  • Papias, MM & Ganesan, P, 2010. Financial services consumption constraints: Empirical evidence from Rwandan rural households. Journal of Financial Services Marketing 15, 136–59. doi: 10.1057/fsm.2010.11
  • Paul, S, Saha, B & Chaudhuri, K, 2008. Repeated borrowing and default: A double hurdle model approach. Paper presented at 42nd Canadian Economic Association Conference, Vancouver, Canada.
  • Pritchard, MF, 2013. Land, power and peace: Tenure formalization, agricultural reform, and livelihood insecurity in rural Rwanda. Land Use Policy 30, 186–96. doi: 10.1016/j.landusepol.2012.03.012
  • Reardon, T, 1997. Using evidence of household income diversification to inform study of rural nonfarm labor market in Africa. World Development 25, 735–47. doi: 10.1016/S0305-750X(96)00137-4
  • Reardon, T, Crawford, E & Kelly, V, 1994. Links between nonfarm income and farm investment in african households: Adding the capital market perspective. American Journal of Agricultural Economics 76, 1172–6. doi: 10.2307/1243412
  • Reardon, T, Crawford, E, Kelly, V & Diagana, B, 1995. Promoting farm investment for sustainable intensification of African agriculture. International Development Paper No. 18, Michigan State University, East Lansing, MI.
  • Reardon, T, Stamoulis, K, Balisacan, A, Cruz, ME, Berdegué, J, & Banks, B, 1998. Rural non-farm income in developing countries. In The State of Food and Agriculture. Food and Agriculture Organization of the United Nations, Rome, Italy, 283–356.
  • Reardon, T, Berdegue, JA, Barrett, CB & Stamoulis, K, 2007. Household income diversification into rural nonfarm activities. In Haggblade, S, Hazell, PBR & Reardon, T (Eds.), Transforming the Rural Nonfarm Economy: Opportunity and Threats in the Developing World, Johns Hopkins University Press, Baltimore, MD, 115–40.
  • Republic of Rwanda, 2000. Rwanda Vision 2020. Ministry of Finance and Economic Planning, Kigali, Rwanda.
  • Republic of Rwanda, 2008. Community Development Policy. Ministry of Local Development, Kigali, Rwanda.
  • Republic of Rwanda, 2009. Strategic Plan for the Transformation of Agriculture in Rwanda – Phase II. Ministry of Agriculture and Animal Resources, Kigali, Rwanda.
  • Republic of Rwanda, 2011. National Industrial Policy. Ministry of Trade and Industry, Kigali, Rwanda.
  • Republic of Rwanda & Department for International Development, 2011. Rural and Agricultural Financial Services Strategy. Ministry of Agriculture and Animal Resources, Kigali, Rwanda.
  • Rosenzweig, MR, 1980. Neoclassical theory and the optimizing peasant: An econometric analysis of market family labor supply in a developing country. Quarterly Journal of Economics 94, 31–55. doi: 10.2307/1884603
  • Rosenzweig, MR & Wolpin, KI, 1985. Specific experience, household structure, and intergenerational transfers: Farm family land and labor arrangements in developing countries. The Quarterly Journal of Economics 100, 961–87. doi: 10.1093/qje/100.Supplement.961
  • Sadoulet, E, De Janvry, A & Benjamin, C, 1998. Household behavior with imperfect labor markets. Industrial Relations: A Journal of Economy and Society 37, 85–108.
  • Schneider, K & Gugerty, MK, 2011. Agricultural productivity and poverty reduction: Linkages and pathways. The Evans School Review 1, 56–74. doi: 10.7152/esr.v1i1.12249
  • Steiner, KG, 1998. Using farmers' knowledge of soils in making research results more relevant to field practice: Experiences from Rwanda. Agriculture, Ecosystems & Environment 69, 191–200. doi: 10.1016/S0167-8809(98)00107-8
  • Strode, M, Wylde, E & Murangwa, Y, 2007. Labour Market and Economic Activity Trends in Rwanda: Analysis of the EICV2 Survey. Oxford Policy Management, Oxford, UK.
  • Traikova, D, Möllers, J, Fritzsch, J & Buchenrieder, G, 2007. Some conceptual thoughts on the impact of social networks on nonfarm rural employment. Joint EAAE-IAAE Seminar Paper, Budapest, Hungary.
  • Wali, A, Ntubabare, D & Mboniragira, V, 2011. Mathematical modeling of Rwanda's population growth. Applied Mathematical Sciences 5, 2617–28.
  • Wandschneider, T, 2003. Determinants of access to rural nonfarm employment: Evidence from Africa, South Asia and transition economies. NRI Report No. 2758, Natural Resource Institute, Chatham.
  • Winters, P, Essam, T, Zezza, A, Davis, B & Carletto, C, 2010. Patterns of rural development: A cross-country comparison using microeconomic data. Journal of Agricultural Economics 61, 628–51. doi: 10.1111/j.1477-9552.2010.00265.x
  • Wooldridge, JM, 2002. Econometric Analysis of Cross Section and Panel Data. MIT Press, Cambridge, MA.
  • World Bank, 2011. Rwanda Economic Update. Seeds for Higher Growth. The World Bank, Washington, DC.
  • Yabiku, ST & Schlabach, S, 2009. Social change and the relationships between education and employment. Population Research Policy Review 28, 533–49. doi: 10.1007/s11113-008-9117-2
  • Zhang, X & Li, G, 2003. Does Guanxi matter to nonfarm employment? Journal of Comparative Economics 31, 315–31. doi: 10.1016/S0147-5967(03)00019-2
  • Zhu, N & Luo, X, 2006. Nonfarm activity and rural income inequality: A case study of two provinces in China. World Bank Policy Research Working Paper No. 3811, The World Bank, Washington, DC.

Reprints and Corporate Permissions

Please note: Selecting permissions does not provide access to the full text of the article, please see our help page How do I view content?

To request a reprint or corporate permissions for this article, please click on the relevant link below:

Academic Permissions

Please note: Selecting permissions does not provide access to the full text of the article, please see our help page How do I view content?

Obtain permissions instantly via Rightslink by clicking on the button below:

If you are unable to obtain permissions via Rightslink, please complete and submit this Permissions form. For more information, please visit our Permissions help page.