888
Views
12
CrossRef citations to date
0
Altmetric
Articles

Dealing With Endogeneity in Threshold Models Using Copulas

, &
Pages 166-178 | Published online: 29 Aug 2019
 

Abstract

We suggest a new method dealing with the problem of endogeneity of the threshold variable in structural threshold regression models based on copula theory. This method enables us to relax the assumption that the threshold variable is normally distributed and to capture the dependence structure between the threshold regression error term and the threshold variable independently of the marginal distribution of the threshold variable. For Gaussian and Student’s t copulas, this dependent structure can be captured by copula-type transformations of the distribution of the threshold variable, for each regime of the model. Augmenting the threshold model under these transformations can control for the endogeneity problem of threshold variable. The single-factor correlation structure of the threshold regression error term with these transformations allows us to consistently estimate the threshold and the slope parameters of the model based on a least squares method. Based on a Monte Carlo study, we show that our method is robust to nonlinear dependence structures between the regression error term and the threshold variable implied by the Archimedean family of copulas. We illustrate the method by estimating a model of the foreign-trade multiplier for seven OECD economies.

ACKNOWLEDGMENTS

We thank the editor (Todd Clark), an associate editor, two anonymous referees, Stelios Arvanitis, Yiannis Bilias, George Kapetanios, Dimitris Karlis, Andros Kourtelos, Andrew Patton, Peter Phillips, and Thanasis Stengos for comments on an earlier version of the article.

Notes

1 Threshold models have recently been gained growing interest (see Teräsvirta, Tjøstheim, and Granger Citation2010 for a survey). Applications include studies on business cycles (e.g., Potter Citation1995), the debt-growth relationship (e.g., Reinhart and Rogoff Citation2010; Kourtellos, Stengos, and Tan Citation2013), financial markets and volatility (see Tsay Citation2010 for a survey), monetary policy models (e.g., Davig and Leeper Citation2007; Kazanas and Tzavalis Citation2015).

2 To mitigate the effects of this assumption on the threshold parameter estimates, Kourtellos et al. (Citation2017) suggested a semiparametric estimator.

3 For a concise overview of applications of copula theory to economic and financial data, see, for example, Patton (Citation2006, Citation2012) and Fan and Patton (Citation2014). Recently, this theory has been applied to capture contemporaneous dependence between the error terms of two time series modeled separately, by the self-exciting threshold autoregressive model using as threshold variables lagged values of these series (see, e.g., Wong et al. Citation2017).

4 Note that, if δ = 1, then C1(Fu1(u1,t),Fz(z)δ) becomes C1(Fu1(u1,t),Fz(z)), 0Fz(z)1 , which gives the joint distribution of (u1,t,zt) for ztZ1Z2 , which is the set of real numbers R. Analogously, we can obtain C2(Fu2(u2,t),Fz(z)), 0Fz(z)1 , when δ = 0.

5 Note that, as in Heckman’s approach (1979), the selectivity bias correction terms in Lee’s (Citation1983) model are given by the inverse Mills ratios of the transformed distribution of the selection equation error term, truncated at the condition function values of the selection equation.

6 For instance, note that, apart from the Gaussian and Student’s t copulas, a closed form solution of E(ui,t|Zi) , i = 1, 2, can also be derived for the case that Ci is the Farlie–Gumbel–Morgenstern (FGM) copula frequently used in practice, which assumes nonlinear dependence between ui,t and zt. As shown in Crane and Van Der Hoek (Citation2008), this can happen under the assumptions that ui,tN(0,σi2) and ztN(0,1). Then, we have,

E(ui,t|Zi)=θiπσi(1Φ(zt|Zi)),θi[1,1],i=1,2.

7 A similar problem appears in binary choice selectivity models (see Vella Citation1998 for a survey). Note that, for nonnormal distributions of xkt, the nonlinear pattern of the transformation Φ1(Fxk(xkt)) , or Tv1(FxK(xkt)) , reduces the correlation between xkt and xkt. For instance, if xktU(0,1) , where U is the uniform distribution, we can easily see that

xkt=Φ1(FxK(xkt))=Φ1(xkt)=2erf1(2xkt1),

where 2erf1(2p1),p(0,1) , is the inversion function of the standard normal distribution. Based on a Maclaurin series expansion of erf1(2xkt1) around 2xkt1=0 (i.e., xkt=12 ), xkt can be written as

xkt=2(12(2xkt1)+π24(2xkt1)3+7π224(2xkt1)5+).

The last relationship shows more clearly that the degree of correlation between xkt and xkt is also determined by the higher order terms in the above expansion of xkt which mitigates the problem of multicollinearity.

8 The discontinuity structure of distribution of zt, at zδ , adds extra randomness which, in a nonparametric framework of estimating model (1), also helps to identify the slope coefficients of the model across its two regimes (see Yu and Phillips Citation2018).

9 Note that this approach is different from that of Hansen (Citation2000)—see also Gonzalo and Pitarakis (Citation2002) and Kourtelos et al. (2016)—assuming that the threshold effects vanish with T, that is, β2β10 as T.

10 Note that this approach is different from that of Hansen (Citation2000)—see also Gonzalo and Pitarakis (Citation2002) and Kourtelos et al. (2016)—assuming that the threshold effects vanish with T, that is, β2β10 as T.

11 Note that similar results are obtained if we set the value of zδ at the 1st quantile of the distribution of zt.

12 Similar performance to the nonparametric method of estimating Fx2(x2t) and Fz|Zi(zt|Zi),i=1,2, has also found for the ECDF method.

13 Kraay (2012) used a similar relationship, without threshold effects, to obtain estimates of the government spending multiplier.

14 In particular, REER is calculated from the nominal effective exchange rate (NEER) and a measure of the relative price of country i and its trading partners j, for all ji (e.g., Darvas Citation2012): REERit=NEERit×CPIitCPIit , where NEERit=Njisit(j)wij is the geometric mean of the nominal bilateral exchange rates of a country i with its trading partners j, wij is the weight of trading partner j, CPIit is the consumer price index of country i, and CPIit=NjiCPIjwij is the geometric mean of the CPI’s of trading partners j.

15 Our earlier working paper version of this article (European Central Bank Working Paper No. 2136) shows graphs of the variables and lists their summary statistics. These are suppressed here for reasons of space.

16 Note that Canada can reject the linear relationship at a 15% level.

17 As shown by Roth (Citation2013) and Ding (2016) for the multivariate case, T2,v+1 is also a Student’s t distribution. See also Kotz and Nadarajah (Citation2004).

18 Note that a column of this matrix also contains the values of the quantile Φ1 , or Tv1 , based transformed variable of regressor x˜t dealing with its possible endogeneity.

Log in via your institution

Log in to Taylor & Francis Online

PDF download + Online access

  • 48 hours access to article PDF & online version
  • Article PDF can be downloaded
  • Article PDF can be printed
USD 61.00 Add to cart

Issue Purchase

  • 30 days online access to complete issue
  • Article PDFs can be downloaded
  • Article PDFs can be printed
USD 123.00 Add to cart

* Local tax will be added as applicable

Related Research

People also read lists articles that other readers of this article have read.

Recommended articles lists articles that we recommend and is powered by our AI driven recommendation engine.

Cited by lists all citing articles based on Crossref citations.
Articles with the Crossref icon will open in a new tab.