3,036
Views
43
CrossRef citations to date
0
Altmetric
Original Articles

Knowledge and innovation: The strings between global and local dimensions of sustainable growth

&
Pages 441-455 | Published online: 23 Jul 2009

Abstract

The modern growth literature pays much attention to innovation and knowledge as drivers of endogenous developments in a competitive open economic system. This paper reviews concisely the literature in this field and addresses in particular micro- and macro-economic interactions at local or regional levels, based on clustering and networking principles, in which sustainability conditions also play a core role. The paper then develops a so-called knowledge circuit model comprising the relevant stakeholders, which aims to offer a novel framework for applied policy research at the meso-economic level.

1. Introduction

The phenomenon of economic growth – in terms of driving forces, distributional effects and competitive consequences – has puzzled economists over decades. Harrod (Citation1939) and Domar (Citation1946) pointed at the rate of savings, population growth and capital-output ratio as exogenous determinants able to explain the long-term growth of an economy. Even when instabilities result from divergences in the steady-state growth path (excess of capital supply, excess of labour supply or underutilization of the productive capacity of the economy), then according to those authors growth would take place as a result of production of technology with constant returns to scale. However, the major importance of technological change has been stressed after the pioneering work of Solow (Citation1956) and Swan (Citation1956) (see also Pitchford Citation2002), who investigated the growth of output in the USA using a neoclassical economic growth model. Their major conclusions demonstrated that the increases in the country's rate of savings generate increases in per capita real income, but its continuous growth should result from technological progress, exogenously determined. The continuity of long run growth was questioned, except in the presence of permanent change, and in this vein various new theoretical insights were offered.

Milestones in such insights have been, for example, the improvement of the initial Solow model by: (1) Arrow (Citation1962) when introducing learning-by-doing as a determinant of technological development; (2) Lucas (Citation1988) by including the growth rate of human capital as a factor of technical change and long run growth; or (3) Romer (Citation1986, 1990) considering technical change as endogenously determined by research and training. The spillover effects resulting from such improvements were presented in the so-called Marshall-Arrow-Romer model, as discussed by Acs and Audretsch (Citation1984, 2002) and Acs (Citation2002). For these authors technological innovation output is perceived as the product of knowledge generating inputs; consequently, technology and entrepreneurship play a major role at the local or regional level in fostering and promoting growth. The concept of growth started moving from a macroeconomic phenomenon to a microeconomic issue and subsequent to this conceptual transition, the determinants were to be found at the level of the enterprise. Grupp (Citation1998) has reviewed a series of contributions given to the earlier growth discussion, putting the emphasis on the crucial aspect of technological change, namely the process of innovation.

The simplified empirical formulation, initially pointed out by Harrod, Domar, and Solow, has taken decades of discussion and produced many different inputs in the history of economic thought, although the systemic and dynamic nature of the economic complexity has remained consensual. Hence, it is not surprising that there has been broad acceptance of various analytical methods inspired by the basic rules of the natural sciences as a platform for economic understanding, particularly when economists were searching for an overall view on the complexity of economic reality. We can go back far into the history of economics (Hetherington Citation1983) and find Adam Smith's inspiration in Newton, or Marx's approach to socio-economic evolution stimulated by Darwin's view (Heyer Citation1982), or in the past century Von Neumann and Morgenstern (Citation1944) applying essentially a Nash equilibrium to find business solutions for economic conflicts. More recently, we can find new endeavours, for example, the use of percolation theoryFootnote1 which has gained prominence in the field of network systems.Footnote2

In general, several studies about the complexity of economic systems have been provided, mainly by authors who were critics of the classic and neoclassical schools of economic thought. Therefore, simultaneously with the many efforts made to outline and model economic growth, different trails emerged to address the variety of determinants of the dynamics of economic systems. Two recent examples are the emphasis put by Fisher (2006) into networking and knowledge spillovers and the interest of Stimson and Stough (Citation2006), on strategies for regional economic development.

In the context of growth theory, the multiple modelling efforts, developed at a macroeconomic level, have been accompanied by empirical observations leading to an improved theoretical understanding of how the innovative processes could stimulate economic activity over the course of the history of mankind. Hence, what innovation is about and how it drives the growth and prosperity of nations and localities in the long run (Schumpeter Citation1934; Freeman Citation1987; Fagerberg Citation2003), has become the centre of many debates. Among these, two different approaches (it may be questionable whether or not they are convergent) led by different schools (the regulatory and the evolutionary) have emerged in the area of the social sciences.Footnote3 Certainly, common elements of both schools have served in the last 20 years to contribute to the construction of a general theory of the dynamic behaviour of the capitalist economy (Di Matteo, Goodwin, and Vercelli Citation1989), helping to find a compromise between institutions and regulations (e.g. environmental constraints) in the discussion related to growth and the role of innovation in this process. Schumpeter (Citation1934) made a key move to a better understanding of the determinants of economic growth. He was persuaded not only by Marx's works but also by Liszt (Citation1841), who emphasized the role of science, technology and human capital in explaining how different social and institutional frameworks enable national systems to grow.

In the same vein, Rosenberg and Frischtak (Citation1986) have focused on Schumpeter's view of technological innovation and how it can be at the centre of both cyclical instability and economic growth, with the direction of causality moving clearly from fluctuations in innovation to fluctuations in investment, and from that to cycles in economic growth. These authors questioned the causal links of Schumpeter's argument that innovations may cluster in certain points in timeFootnote4 just ‘when entrepreneurial perception of risk and returns justifies innovative commitments. These clusterings, in turn, lead to long cycles by generating periods of acceleration (and eventual deceleration) in aggregate growth rates’ (p. 7). The authors’ view, expressed about 20 years ago,Footnote5 when innovation was understood within a concept of linear causality represents a macroeconomic justification for the perception of the complexity existing in any updated interactive model of innovation.Footnote6

Despite the extensive number of different perspectives linking innovation to growth, it seems to be commonly accepted that one way to describe the progression of change is to interpret dynamics as a continuous production of new products or processes. However, the mechanism presupposes a simultaneous adjustment of society to new needs or requirements, engaging most of the attention of those theorists who try to recognize the extent of informational flows and interchanges that this reciprocal movement represents. Furthermore, economic growth is increasingly positioned in a force field of global competition and need for sustainable development.

The subsequent demanding endeavour to combine, in the production chain, innovation with the co-ordination capacity of organizations, presents much more than a theoretical challenge, but rather a social reshaping. In this sense, the cognitive sciences (particularly, psychology, sociology, and organizational management) are slowly but gradually participating in the construction of a new multidisciplinary view which should be useful to improve the understanding of sustainable growth, development and social awareness, as well as their respective links.

This study is centred on the complexity of the global/local paradox that arises with the contribution of knowledge and innovation for sustainable growth. The complexity of this paradox is justified by the fact that, over time, the knowledge assets flow from the past into the global macroeconomic contexts of the present, in order to shape micro-economic conditions for local development. These should be positive contributions to reduce entrepreneurial risk and to encourage efficient entrepreneurship.

In line with the literature review, a model for the knowledge circuit in a process of sustainable growth has been developed in order to validate the following hypothesis: only a multilevel approach allows understanding of the complexity expressed by all the determinants of knowledge and innovation.

2. Embeddedness, proximity and learning as forms to reinforce trust and reduce entrepreneurial risk

Beginning with the works of Penrose (Citation1959) and Wernerfelt (Citation1984), the drivers of innovation may be better understood from the resource-based view of the firm, accepting its heterogeneous character. The approach uses the firm as the unit of analysis and studies its resources and capabilities in order to understand the firm's strategic behaviour (Knudsen Citation1995). In this context, knowledge is recognized as a key resource for firms and other economic agents, while both codified knowledge and tacit knowledge are pertinent aspects for innovation.

Although the first studies on knowledge assets emphasized the firm's own codified knowledge resulting from its internal R&D capacities, nowadays researchers accept the major role of external sources of knowledge in the firms’ capability to innovate (see amongst others, Nijkamp, van Oirschot, and Oosterman Citation1994; Albino, Garavelli, and Schiuma 1999; Nooteboom Citation1999). Considering that co-operation goes far beyond knowledge transfer,Footnote7 it is still questionable whether the co-operation between research institutes and industrial firms enhances innovation as argued by Antonelli and Calderini (Citation1999), or, on the contrary, whether such links are of minor importance, as defended by Diederen, van Meijl, and Wolters (Citation2000).Footnote8 In any case, it seems to be commonly accepted that the impact of the co-operation with research institutes is mainly sector-related. In general, high-tech firms tend to co-operate more often with research institutes than firms producing in low-technology areas.Footnote9 Now that the innovation literature has, besides a direct input, also identified a second role for R&D in the innovation process (Cohen and Levinthal Citation1989, 1990; Zahra and George Citation2002), namely a determinant of absorptive capacity, the firm's ability to assimilate and make use of external knowledge is more critical.

Additionally, some authors have stressed the key role of ‘good communication’ between industry and research institutes for the successful transfer of technological knowledge (Kaiser Citation2002). Sometimes, a certain lack of acceptance may partly explain why low-technology firms tend to be sceptical concerning partnerships with external researchers.Footnote10 Indeed, the strategic choice of low-tech firms with regard to innovation is highly influenced by vertical co-operation with suppliers and customers. In such cases, the development of new products or processes often takes into account, above all, the new demands, as well as the market changes.Footnote11

Moreover, in relation to firms’ attitudes towards the absorption of codified knowledge, it is important to underline that firms rely on the lessons from the success and failure of similar companies to improve their own strategic decisions, as signalled by Maskell (Citation2001). However, if firms are small, they will lack the means to carry out exhaustive cost-benefit analyses, and cannot pay for innovations with high-risk profiles (Senker Citation1998; Senker and Faulkner Citation2001).

A novel contribution was made by Van Geenhuizen and Nijkamp (Citation1997), when detecting the spatially heterogeneous technology acceptance resulting from spatial irregularities in the receptivity of firms to new technologies. In their study, this was partly explained by organizational and strategic distances among actors, but it remains to be seen whether this situation is not the result of different integration levels of firms into the respective environmental contexts (embeddedness), giving rise to asymmetrical assimilation of tacit knowledge. Indeed, after Nelson and Winter's (Citation1982) first discussions on the particularities of tacit knowledge, many other contributions have proved its importance as a component of the innovation process (Nonaka and Takeuchi Citation1995; Dosi Citation1997; Johannessen, Olsen, and Olaisen Citation1999; Nonaka, Toyama, and Konno Citation2000). According to Nightingale (Citation1998) and Kaiser (Citation2002), tacit knowledge is not a mobile resource, deriving from lifetime experience, practice, perception and long-term learning. Instead, tacit knowledge should be perceived as a common asset and a positive contribution for productive processes that are spatially located.

Considering that firms easily absorb tacit knowledge when exposed to external links, proximity – a concept earlier associated with cost reduction – readdresses the innovation debate. Whether institutional or geographic, the stakeholders’ capacity to easily interact becomes a positive externality. Common traces such as language, codes of communication, conventions, personal contacts, past history, or successful informal interactions (Nightingale Citation1998; Gertler Citation2001; Gertler and Wolfe Citation2004) take place, therefore increasing trust and reducing risk. An allusion should be made to Bertuglia, Lombardo, and Nijkamp (Citation1997) who clarified how urban areas could become incubators of change once they decide to be centres for cultural opportunities and geographical connectivity. From this perspective, the region plays a critical role in innovative entrepreneurship.

The importance of spatial embeddedness for enterprises stems from the role that knowledge creation plays in innovation. While codified knowledge is losing part of its strength as a source of competitive advantage, tacit knowledge is reinforcing its significance as a means of adapting to new requirements and therefore, spatial proximity to sources of relevant knowledge creation is becoming central in current scientific attention (Arndt and Sternberg Citation2000). In small firms, particularly when they lack opportunities to be aware of new developments in ICTs or to organize information transfer over longer distances (Blundel Citation2002), proximity tends to be a significant advantage. A third example, which is currently very topical, is the role of the university in stimulating new booming research or service activities (Lester Citation2006).

Another aspect, also related to the advantages of proximity and embeddedness, concerns the involvement of the entrepreneur with local social structures. In this case, embeddedness may turn into an efficient mechanism to improve the use of local resources, market opportunities or advanced institutional structures, all very positive contributions to the enlargement of tacit knowledge. The notion of regional culture is important here as a facilitator of innovativeness.

In conclusion, we tend to agree with Lundvall and Johnson (Citation1994) who state that if knowledge becomes the most important resource for firms and organizations, the process of learning develops into one of its most important processes.

3. Creativity, clustering and networking as a contribution to productive and efficient entrepreneurship

Both creativity and innovation are major contributors to technological change and have been studied from multiple scientific angles. However, while innovation has been investigated from a macro- to a micro-perspective, as described earlier, creativity has only been examined as an individual output, but never as a social task or as a result of joint actions in a sequential process.

Amabile (Citation1996) proposed one of the most comprehensive models of creativity, by defining a combination of variables able to influence organizational creativity, at the level of the individual, of the group, and of the organization. As it does not address the question of how organizations may interact among themselves to generate new ideas, both innovative and useful, this model remains incomplete. In addition to this view of creativity as a capability, the literature also characterizes it as a process and as a product, but, so far, very few attempts have been made to analyse creativity as a phenomenon crossing organizational borders or emerging from more adequate facilitating environments.

One of the authors who has defined creativity as the product of complex interactions between the individual talent and the socio-cultural context was Csikszentmihalyi (Citation1999), adding an indispensable contribution to the study of creativity. Taking on Csikszentmihalyi's view, it is reasonable to accept that creativity – similarly to innovation – can occur within a network of organizations linked by common interests and acting within a network of common goals. Both creativity and innovation can be either fostered or blocked by the degree to which organizations share values, beliefs, and knowledge. This view reinforces the idea of networking.

The literature related to organizational theory has taken a different approach to the dilemma of networks. In fact, the writings on clustering have contributed to understanding the form and the reason for organizations and institutions to join and face competitive confrontations. Porter and Sölvell (Citation1998), for example, explained that a cluster offers an environment for the development of a common language, social bonds, norms, and values, i.e. social capital. Pouder and John (Citation1996) took a deeper view, and tried to understand the cognitive reasons behind the existence of a cluster. They explained that, in a cluster, managers and decision-makers share a wide range of values, cognitive references, perceptions, and experiences (called normative isomorphism), and hence they tend to establish connections and follow the same patterns of organizational behaviour (e.g. competing, collaborating, and so on), Porter (Citation1998). Furthermore, negative consequences of such isomorphism may emerge as well: since they all share a particular culture and a set of beliefs, there is a risk of strategic myopia, which reinforces imitating and non-innovative kinds of behaviours. This is also a very important argument to consider if, in terms of economic development, we aim to perceive possible negative externalities from excessive clustering.Footnote12

In practice, however, sharing a set of values and beliefs can be highly positive as far as creative and innovative activity is concerned. In fact, if all entities within the cluster share the same propensity for creating and innovating, and for risk-taking and change, then one can expect that the whole cluster will show such a pattern of creation and innovation. Therefore, networking for entrepreneurial efficiency is an important issue to be pursued.

Ménard (Citation1993, 2000) takes a different direction to explain – in a way closely related to the ideas developed by Coase (Citation1937), who redefined the nature of the institutional landscape of firms – that it is the asymmetric amount of information happening within inter-organizational relations that validates the need for networking. This author refutes Hayek's thesis (Citation1989), who trusted market organizations and individuals to transfer into prices all the required information to achieve equilibrium. Ménard's view is fully justified by the fact that heterogeneity is a frequent characteristic in information transactions but with an incomplete expression in market prices. This view is also strengthened by the neo-institutionalist argument that formal or informational transaction costs often represent very high expenditures to firms and organizations.

Arising from a completely different perspective, Forray and Aubin (Citation1998) also provided evidence to suggest that micro-behaviour tends to give rise to local clustering rules. Within the theory of networking systems, an organizational niche (which is a network structure) can easily integrate any technology of more complex structures. A particularity of this process was formulated by Bounmy et al. (Citation1995), in a model of technological choices with social learning as a determinant. The fact that he points out the speed in information acquisition to justify leadership in adopting new technologies clears up doubts that informational flows – and in our view knowledge flows too – can indeed be time- and cost-consuming, frequently encouraging convenient imitating attitudes if proximity amongst enterprises or networking systems is not present.

4. Integration of macro-, meso- and micro-determinants of growth in knowledge flows

As previously seen, knowledge creation, diffusion and its use are of great importance to keep the multiple determinants of growth contributing to permanent change and they reflect, based on microeconomic attitudes, the macroeconomic oscillations of global productive activity. Malhotra (Citation2002) felt challenged to discuss the models available to measure the amount of national knowledge assets, discussing their restrictions and proposing new indicators and methodologies. Several limitations have been perceived in his study, but the most relevant ones seem to be related to the cognitive nature of knowledge.

Apart from the fact that human-embodied knowledge is non-physical, not possible to contain, not directly measurable and incompatible with financial accounting (OECD 1996, 2001), knowledge assets can only be calculated if there is a clear understanding of their potential use in the economy. This means that a significant part of the actual value of knowledge may depend on the success of future results.

This phenomenon can be seen when valuable historical background knowledge of less privileged communities disappears over time, narrowing the respective knowledge bases while other prosperous communities are able to integrate past values of knowledge in their present successful performances in a process that may even overestimate the value of the respective present knowledge bases. In itself, the value of knowledge assets has been relative to the time period and the growth level. As a result of the existing efforts to develop rigorous criteria to measure knowledge assetsFootnote13 and, in spite of the multiple measurement models developed,Footnote14 most of the available indicators related to knowledge are pertinent for analyses of national performance in terms of global development.

It is often uncritically accepted that, for a better understanding and measurement, knowledge assets can exhibit a sequential model: , for which Inputs represent structural or financial investments for development purposes; Processes are to track the use of specific financial, structural and human capital inputs; Outputs stand for the effective use of the inputs, resulting in tangible and intangible outputs for the target users, and Outcomes correspond to precise results.

This linear model has merits, but alerts us also to the fact that the accounting of knowledge assets based on investments in inputs may not be a reliable proxy for the actual performance outcomes resulting from such investments.Footnote15 Clearly, further restrictions should be considered as well: (1) the first one related to finding adequate disaggregated data, which is a common problem related to many socio-economic indicators. Recent sampling and data mining techniques may be helpful to solve such a problem efficiently; (2) the next concern is the lack of certainty that investments made on the location of knowledge inputs will result in knowledge outcomes sited nearby, particularly in the case of codified knowledge. Because of its relative mobility, a gap could very easily occur; and (3) finally, the time lag between the investments made for inputs in knowledge and the accomplishment of outcomes is, certainly, unpredictable and may very well be quite long. Also, in this model, efficiency in knowledge management could be evaluated by addressing the institutional capacity to favour near values between the Inputs and the Outcomes of the model. Amongst others, the institutional proximity and the robustness and flexibility of the information systems should help to decrease hindrances to separate such values.

By abandoning new developments in the recent history of economic thought and being developed strictly on the basis of organizational management, the previous model is too limited to reflect the dynamic force of knowledge upon structural change and growth. Therefore, a new approach is warranted. An effort to surmount such a limitation is proposed in the following diagrammatic representation ().

Figure 1. Knowledge circuit in the process of sustainable growth.

Figure 1. Knowledge circuit in the process of sustainable growth.

A reflection of the knowledge circuit within a process of sustainable growth suggests a multilevel model able to improve the analytical tools required to better understand the complexity expressed by all the determinants of knowledge and innovation outlined earlier. This requires a transdisciplinary effort and represents a methodological challenge. shows an interactive and multilevel model for which knowledge assets are circulating simultaneously between the micro- and macro-levels of economic activity. An exterior cycle represents the global conditions for change related to the macroeconomic conditions for growth; an intermediary cycle reproduces the knowledge diffusion taking place at the mesoeconomic level, the level at which institutional relationships take place. The boundaries of economic effects are crossed by other relevant issues related to organizational management and the cognitive sciences; in a next, almost interior cycle, knowledge application happens through innovation which may only result in new products and processes. In a subsequent phase, shown by the centre of the representation, both microeconomic restrictions related to the strategic and technical decisions of firms, and local political choices driven by governance structures and environmental determinants, decide how the innovations should be used.

Observed from a more detailed perspective, we could speculate on a cyclical process of flows from the existing ‘path dependencies’, ‘competitive advantages’, ‘regulations’, ‘national innovation systems’ and framing ‘financial supports’ moving into a micro-economical context. This process is better explained in , which provides a complement to the previous description and illustrates how most of the knowledge flows occur at the meso-economic level representing for both regions and sectors continuity among knowledge creation, knowledge diffusion and knowledge use. In this circuit technological learning, networking in the institutional proximity, and embeddedness within the regional development conditions are the instruments used by institutions (we have addressed firms and regional policy agents) to absorb and transmit such flows. As earlier, here also innovation is signalled as a moment in which knowledge creation happens, while Firms and Other Stakeholders represent the circumstances in which knowledge use takes place.

Figure 2. Knowledge and innovation at the mesoeconomic level. Source: Vaz and Cesário (2007) © 2007 Inderscience.

Figure 2. Knowledge and innovation at the mesoeconomic level. Source: Vaz and Cesário (2007) © 2007 Inderscience.

The attitudes of firms and policy makers are represented in their behavioural patterns, allowing scientific measurement (Vaz, Cesário, and Fernando Citation2006), public intervention and strategic prediction, all of which foster novel prospects for a better understanding of the causality of growth. This scheme also contains strategic handles for innovation and entrepreneurship policy at local levels where networking and clustering is usually prominently present. In this regard, much literature has been devoted to the mechanisms facilitating the spillovers of knowledge from the producing source into the receptive market (Fischer Citation2006). Not without controversy, entrepreneurship seems to be one of the engines of such mechanisms (Mueller Citation2007).

5. Conclusion

Much of the past history of economic thought has been devoted to growth based on wealth creation. However, our present concerns are mostly related to sustainability restrictions resulting from a firm's need to increase production in terms of continuous uncontrolled consumption. This and other apparent contradictions regarding our global society call for a new understanding of growth (Stough, Nijkamp, and Vaz Citation2007): there is a change in the speed of destruction of natural resources and a loss of significance of non-skilled human capital, while the allocation of space offers competitive advantages resulting from new transportation systems. Long-term growth faces paradigms that require a shift of attention towards long-term sustainability.

In this paper we concentrate on those determinants of growth that may offer a positive contribution to sustainability. Our study reviews several concepts related to innovation and knowledge in order to justify that it is more appropriate to focus on sustainable growth, in particular if restrictive conditions impose a narrow equilibrium between production and consumption. Nowadays, there is little acceptance for efficiency losses and production waste, and awareness should be the self-regulator for those major determinants of growth such as investment, innovation, consumption and wealth. We believe that we have been able to validate our initial hypothesis about the need for a multilevel approach.

To develop the arguments put forward in our paper, we have assumed that knowledge is the key for sustainable growth. We accept it as a mobile asset able to generate advantages for wealth creation and productivity and to bring awareness about the macroeconomic conditions of growth and the micro-economic limits for production and consumption. This is because its impact on human capital increases the capacity to produce more and better and at the same time it creates responsiveness within the institutional context to the restrictions of a global but environmentally-fragile system. Our arguments focus on the meso-economic level, where actors appear to progress with different behavioural patterns to relate, co-operate and exchange all kinds of information. In the process, knowledge will flow and multiply, giving to the different actors, both at macro- and micro-economic levels, the opportunity to accumulate, share and use it. The ongoing global dynamics has from this perspective a multiplier effect that speeds up the intensity of flows and enlarges its spectrum to a world-wide proactive experiment.

The model presented here assumes that knowledge flows as regulators between the past (historical heritage or path dependencies), the present macro-economic conditions (the country's competitive advantages, international regulations and others) and the local existing forms (proximity, learning, embeddedness in local development conditions). The firms’ and other actors’ role is to use this context when innovating in order to produce efficiently. This will happen if the different social actors and policy makers transmit the exact information on the populations’ needs to consume, the firms’ capacities to produce, and the particular environmental restrictions they have to deal with.

The model aims to prompt further applied research and proper methods to measure the amount of circulating knowledge assets and their respective speed in producing information for sustainable growth. The empirical observation of such flows at a global level can be a hard task because of the data availability requirements. Eventually, observations made at a local dimension could permit us to identify specific restrictions that may, in the long term, better achieve local development targets or advances for the competitive advantage of firms and/or locals.

If the previous reasoning sounds policy-oriented, we nevertheless believe that questions driven by managerial goals could find adequate answers derived from the foregoing discussions in this paper. For example: How can economic agents feel stimulated to invest and innovate when permanently confronted with restrictive conditions? Or, which attributes do firms require in order to continue to be productive and efficient? Knowledge flows promote learning, encourage proximity, and induce embeddedness, and these are all forms which reinforce trust and reduce entrepreneurial risk. In order to encourage innovation, the firms’ most important strategic choices should be based upon creativity, clustering, and networking as a contribution to productive and efficient entrepreneurship in a global and open economy where competitive forces and sustainability requirements are present at the same time.

Acknowledgements

The authors are thankful to three anonymous reviewers whose comments were valuable contributions to improve the quality of this study.

Notes

Notes

1. For a better presentation and understanding, see Grimmett (Citation1997).

2. Cohendet (Citation1997) analyses ‘the conditions of emergence and the properties of irreversibility on a network of economic agents facing technological choices among competing technologies’ (p. 93).

3. What nowadays distinguishes the evolutionary from the regulatory perspective is the different emphasis put on innovation and institutions as engines of growth. For the former, the expansion periods are related to the introduction and diffusion of new methods and products strictly related to product life cycles, whereas for the latter, growth is a result of how power in institutions sustains the capitalist market system.

4. Also, do not forget space. Several arguments along these lines have been formulated by Davelaar and Nijkamp (Citation1997).

5. We are left without a precise knowledge of what are the necessary and sufficient changes in the environment which, even conceptually, can bring out a bandwagon-like diffusion of some number of basic innovations. In other words, there is no well-specified set of elements that effectively link and elucidate the direction of causality between the basic innovations, the ‘general level of profitability and business expectations’, and their diffusion in the form of a swarm of new products and processes. More generally, nowhere in the literature is there to be found an unambiguous treatment of causality, within a neo-Schumpeterian framework, which establishes the precedence of innovation clusters over investment outlays and aggregate movements in the economy’ (p. 8).

6. See, for example, the arguments in the context of innovation policy instruments given by Christensen, Cornett, and Philipsen (Citation2003).

7. For instance, the university provides skilled workers and training opportunities for staff, as well as public spaces (Lester and Piore Citation2004; Lester Citation2005).

8. Most probably, this should be the consequence of both the sectorial links and the embeddedness level of the firm.

9. The explanation for this is that R&D-based innovations, which typify high-tech firms, often result from co-operation with research institutes, whereas innovations that are primarily experience-based, as is the case in small low-technology firms, seldom require this type of co-operation.

10. The proliferation of many private or public/private partnerships devoted to create interfaces among industry and universities illustrates this view.

11. The case of innovation in the food industry is doubtless an important example of innovation in the context of small low-tech firms deeply rooted in their environments, as pointed out by, amongst others, Galizzi and Venturini (Citation1996).

12. This issue has not been a frequently addressed (Gerlach, Ronde, and Stahlm Citation2004).

13. We refer here to the World Bank's Knowledge Assessment Methodology and Scorecards (World Bank Institute Citation2002), or the many specificities and conceptual contributions from OECD to reconcile knowledge assets and human and social capital (OECD 1996, 2001).

14. Annex 1 summarizes most of the existent models on knowledge flows.

15. For example, there is increasing evidence to question the relation between ICTs and business performance.

References

  • Acs , Z . 2002 . Innovation and the growth of cities , Cheltenham : Edward Elgar .
  • Acs , Z and Audretsch , DB . 1984 . Small business in industrial economics: The new learning . Revue d'Economie Industrielle , 7 : 21 – 39 .
  • Albino , V , Garavelli , AC and Schiuma , G . 1999 . Knowledge transfer and inter-firm relationships in industrial districts: The role of the leader firm . Technovation , 19 : 53 – 6 .
  • Amabile , TM . 1996 . Creativity in context , Boulder, CO : Westview Press .
  • Antonelli , C and Calderini , M . 1999 . “ The dynamics of localised technological change ” . In The organization of economic innovation in Europe , Edited by: Gambardell , A and Malerba , F . 158 – 76 . Cambridge : Cambridge University Press .
  • Arndt , O and Sternberg , R . 2000 . Do manufacturing firms profit from intraregional innovation linkages? An empirical based answer . European Planning Studies , 8 : 465 – 85 .
  • Arrow , KJ . 1962 . The economic implication of learning by doing . Review of Economic Studies , 29 : 155 – 73 .
  • Audretsch , D . 2002 . The innovative advantages of US cities . European Planning Studies , 10 : 165 – 76 .
  • Bertuglia , CS , Lombardo , S and Nijkamp , P . 1997 . “ An interpretative survey of innovative behaviour ” . In Innovative behaviour in space and time , Edited by: Bertuglia , CS , Lombardo , S and Nijkamp , P . 1 – 17 . Berlin : Springer .
  • Blundel , R . 2002 . Network evolution and the growth of artisanal firms: A tale of two regional cheese makers . Entrepreneurship & Regional Development , 14 : 1 – 30 .
  • Bounmy , K , Vergnaud , J-C , Willinger , M and Ziegelmeyer , M . 1995 . “ Information externalities and learning with sequential interactions ” . In The economics of networks , Edited by: Cohendet , P , Llerene , P , Stahn , H and Umdhauer , G . 307 – 24 . Berlin : Springer .
  • Christensen , PR , Cornett , A and Philipsen , K . 2003 . “ Coherence of innovation policy instruments ” . In Regional innovation policy for small-medium enterprises , Edited by: Asheim , B , Isaksen , I , Nauwelaers , C and Tödling , F . 166 – 90 . Cheltenham : Edward Elgar .
  • Coase , RH . 1937 . The nature of the firm . Economica , 4 : 386 – 405 .
  • Cohen , W and Levinthal , D . 1989 . Innovation and learning: The two faces of R&D . Economic Journal , 99 : 569 – 96 .
  • Cohen , W and Levinthal , D . 1990 . Absorptive capacity: A new perspective on learning and innovation . Administrative Science Quarterly , 35 : 128 – 52 .
  • Cohendet , P . 1997 . “ Network, interactions between economic agents and irreversibilities: The case of the choice among competing technologies ” . In The economics of networks , Edited by: Cohendet , P , Llerene , P , Stahn , H and Umdhauer , G . 93 – 121 . Berlin : Springer .
  • Csikszentmihalyi , M . 1999 . “ Implications of a systems perspective for the study of creativity ” . In Handbook of creativity , Edited by: Sternberg , R . 312 – 35 . Cambridge, MA : Cambridge University Press .
  • Davelaar , EJ and Nijkamp , P . 1997 . “ Spatial dispersion of technical innovation: A review ” . In Innovative behaviour in space and time , Edited by: Bertuglia , CS , Lombardo , S and Nijkamp , P . 1 – 17 . Berlin : Springer .
  • Di Matteo , M , Goodwin , RM and Vercelli , A eds . 1989 . Technological and social factors in long term fluctuations , Berlin : Springer .
  • Diederen , P , van Meijl , H and Wolters , A . 2000 . Eureka! Innovatieprocessen en Innovatiebeleid in de Land- en Tuinbouw , Den Haag : LEI .
  • Domar , ED . 1946 . Capital expansion, rate of growth, and employment . Econometrica , 14 : 137 – 47 .
  • Dosi , J . 1997 . Opportunities, incentives and the collective patterns of technological change . The Economic Journal , 107 : 1530 – 47 .
  • Fagerberg , J . 2003 . Schumpeter and the revival of evolutionary economics: An appraisal of the literature . Journal of Evolutionary Economics , 13 : 125 – 59 .
  • Fischer , MM . 2006 . Innovation, networks, and knowledge spillovers , Berlin : Springer-Verlag .
  • Foray , D and Aubin , J-P . 1998 . “ The emergence of network organizations in processes of technological choice: A viability approach ” . In The economics of networks , Edited by: Cohendet , P , Llerene , P , Stahn , H and Umdhauer , G . 283 – 90 . Berlin : Springer .
  • Freeman , C . 1987 . Technology policy and economic performance: Lessons from Japan , London : Pinter .
  • Galizzi , G and Venturini , L . 1996 . “ Product innovation in the food industry: Nature, characteristics and determinants ” . In Economics of innovation: The case of the food industry , Edited by: Galizzi , G and Venturini , L . Heidelberg : Physica-Verlag .
  • Gerlach , HA , Ronde , T and Stahlm. , K . 2004 . Project choice and risk in R&D, CIE Discussion Paper 2004-01 , Centre for Industrial Economics, Institute of Economics, University of Copenhagen .
  • Gertler , MS . 2001 . Tacit knowledge and the economic geography of context or the undefinable tacitness of being . Paper presented at the DRUID Summer Conference . June 12–15 2001 , Aalborg. Denmark
  • Gertler , MS and Wolfe , DA . 2004 . Local social knowledge management: Community actors, institutions and multilevel governance in regional foresight exercises . Futures , 36 : 46 – 5 .
  • Grimmett , G . 1997 . Percolation and disordered systems , Berlin : Springer .
  • Grupp , H . 1998 . Foundations of the economics of innovation , Cheltenham : Edward Elgar .
  • Harrod , RF . 1939 . An essay in dynamic theory . Economic Journal , 49 : 14 – 33 .
  • Hayek , F . 1989 . Law, legislation and liberty , New York : The Free Press .
  • Hetherington , NS . 1983 . Isaac Newton's influence on Adam Smith's natural laws in economics . Journal of the History of Ideas , 44 : 497 – 505 .
  • Heyer , P . 1982 . Nature, human nature and society: Marx, Darwin, biology and the human science , Westport, CT : Greenwood Press .
  • Johannessen , J-A , Olsen , B and Olaisen , J . 1999 . Aspects of innovation theory based on knowledge management . International Journal of Information Management , 19 : 121 – 39 .
  • Kaiser , U . 2002 . Measuring knowledge spillovers in manufacturing and services: An empirical assessment of alternative approaches . Research Policy , 31 : 125 – 44 .
  • Knudsen , C . 1995 . “ Theories of the firm, strategic management and leadership ” . In Resource-based and evolutionary theories of the firm , Edited by: Montgomery , C . 179 – 217 . Boston : Kluwer .
  • Lester , R . 2005 . Universities, innovation, and the competitiveness of local economies, MIT Industrial Performance Centre Working Paper 05-010 , Cambridge, MA : Industrial Performance Centre, Massachusetts Institute of Technology .
  • Lester , R . 2006 . Prospects for local innovation systems, Seminar held in September 2006 at the Department of Economics , Galway : National University of Ireland .
  • Lester , R and Piore , M . 2004 . Innovation: The missing dimension , Cambridge, MA : Harvard University Press .
  • Liszt , F . 1841 . The national systems of political economy , London : Longman English Edition .
  • Lucas , RE . 1988 . On the mechanics of economic development . Journal of Monetary Economics , 22 : 3 – 42 .
  • Lundvall , BA and Johnson , B . 1994 . The learning economy . Journal of Industry Studies , 1 : 23 – 42 .
  • Malhotra , Y . 2002 . “ Why knowledge management systems fail? Enablers and constraints of knowledge management in human enterprises ” . In Handbook of knowledge management , Edited by: Holsapple , CW . 577 – 600 . Heidelberg : Springer .
  • Maskell , P . 2001 . Towards a knowledge-based theory of geographical cluster . Industrial and Corporate Change , 10 : 921 – 943 .
  • Ménard , C . 1993 . L’Economie des Organization , Paris : Éditions La Decouverte .
  • Ménard , C . 2000 . “ Ronald H. Coase and the emergence of a new approach to economics ” . In Institutions, contracts and organizations , Edited by: Ménard , C . 54 – 8 . Cheltenham : Edward Elgar .
  • Mueller , P . 2007 . Exploiting entrepreneurial opportunities: The impact of entrepreneurship on growth . Small Business Economics , 28 : 355 – 62 .
  • Nelson , R and Winter , S . 1982 . An evolutionary theory of economic change , Cambridge, MA : Harvard University Press .
  • Nightingale , P . 1998 . A cognitive model of innovation . Research Policy , 27 : 689 – 709 .
  • Nijkamp , P , van Oirschot , G and Oosterman , A . 1994 . “ Knowledge networks, science parks and regional development: An international comparative analysis of critical success factors ” . In Moving frontiers: Economic restructuring, regional development and emerging network , Edited by: Cuadrado-Roura , JR , Nijkamp , P and Salva , P . 225 – 46 . Aldershot : Ashgate .
  • Nonaka , I and Takeuchi , H . 1995 . The knowledge creating company , Oxford : Oxford University Press .
  • Nonaka , I , Toyama , R and Konno , N . 2000 . SECI, Ba and leadership: A unified model of dynamic knowledge creation . Long Range Planning , 33 : 5 – 34 .
  • Nooteboom , B . 1999 . Innovation and inter-firm linkages: New implications for policy . Research Policy , 28 : 793 – 805 .
  • Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development [OECD] . 1996 . Measuring what people know: Human capital accounting for the knowledge economy , Paris : OECD .
  • Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development [OECD] . 2001 . Science, technology and industry scoreboard , Paris : OECD .
  • Penrose , ET . 1959 . The theory of the growth of the firm , New York : John Wiley .
  • Pitchford , JD . 2002 . Trevor Swan's 1956 economic growth ‘seminar’ and notes on growth . The Economic Record, The Economic Society of Australia , 78 : 381 – 87 .
  • Porter , M . 1998 . Clusters and the new economics of competition . Harvard Business Review , 76 November–December : 77 – 90 .
  • Porter , M and Sölvell , O . 1998 . “ The role of geography in the process of innovation and the sustainable competitive advantage of firms ” . In The dynamic firm: The role of technology, strategy and regions , Edited by: Chandler, , D Jr , Hagstrom , P and Sölvell , O . 440 – 58 . Oxford : Oxford University Press .
  • Pouder , R and John , C . 1996 . Hot spots and blind spots: Geographical clusters of firms and innovation . Academy of Management Review , 21 : 1192 – 225 .
  • Romer , PM . 1986 . Increasing returns and long-run growth . The Journal of Political Economy , 94 : 1002 – 37 .
  • Romer , PM . 1990 . Endogenous technical change . The Journal of Political Economy , 98 : 71 – 102 .
  • Rosenberg , N and Frischtak , CR . 1986 . “ Technological innovation and long waves ” . In Design, innovations and long cycles in economic development , Edited by: Freeman , C . 5 – 26 . London : Frances Pinter .
  • Schumpeter , J . 1934 . The theory of economic development , Cambridge, MA : Harvard University Press .
  • Senker , J . 1998 . “ The contribution of tacit knowledge to innovation ” . In Exploring expertise: Issues and perspectives , Edited by: Williams , R , Faulkner , W and Fleck , J . 223 – 44 . Basingstoke : Macmillan .
  • Senker , J and Faulkner , W . 2001 . “ Origins of public-private knowledge flows and current state-of-the-art: Can agriculture learn from industry? ” . In Knowledge generation and technical change: Institutional innovation in agriculture , Edited by: Wolf , S and Zilberman , D . 203 – 32 . London : Kluwer Academic .
  • Solow , RM . 1956 . A contribution to the theory of economic growth . Quarterly Journal of Economics , 70 : 65 – 94 .
  • Stimson , RJ and Stough , R . 2006 . Regional economic development: Analysis and planning strategy , Berlin : Springer-Verlag .
  • Stough , R , Nijkamp , P and Vaz. , MTN eds. 2007 . Urban knowledge and innovation policy . Special Issue of Environment and Planning C , 25 ( 5 ) : 633 – 7 .
  • Swan , TW . 1956 . A contribution to the theory of economic growth . Quarterly Journal of Economics , 70 ( 1 ) : 65 – 94 .
  • Van Geenhuizen , M and Nijkamp , P . 1997 . “ Diffusion and acceptance of new products and processes by individual firms ” . In Innovative behaviour in space and time , Edited by: Bertuglia , CS , Lombardo , S and Nijkamp , P . 276 – 90 . Berlin, Heidelberg, New York : Springer-Verlag .
  • Vaz , MTN and Cesário. , M . 2007 . Driving forces for innovation: Are they measurable? International Journal of Foresight and Innovation Policy, special issue: Entrepreneurship, Innovation and Economic Development: A Policy Framework 4, no 1–2 30 – 50 .
  • Vaz , MTN , Cesário , M and Fernando , S . 2006 . Interaction between innovation in small firms and their environments: An exploratory study . European Planning Studies , 14 : 95 – 117 .
  • Von Neumann , J and Morgenstern , O . 1944 . Theory of games and economic behaviour , Princeton : Princeton University Press .
  • Wernerfelt , B . 1984 . A resource-based view of the firm . Strategic Management Journal , 5 : 171 – 80 .
  • World Bank Institute. 2002. The knowledge assessment methodology and scorecards. Washington: World Bank
  • Zahra , S and George , G . 2002 . Absorptive capacity: A review, reconceptualization and extension . Academy of Management Review , 27 : 185 – 203 .

Reprints and Corporate Permissions

Please note: Selecting permissions does not provide access to the full text of the article, please see our help page How do I view content?

To request a reprint or corporate permissions for this article, please click on the relevant link below:

Academic Permissions

Please note: Selecting permissions does not provide access to the full text of the article, please see our help page How do I view content?

Obtain permissions instantly via Rightslink by clicking on the button below:

If you are unable to obtain permissions via Rightslink, please complete and submit this Permissions form. For more information, please visit our Permissions help page.