811
Views
18
CrossRef citations to date
0
Altmetric
Original Articles

Life beyond the Washington Consensus: An Introduction to Pro-poor Macroeconomic Policies

Pages 513-537 | Published online: 09 Oct 2007
 

Abstract

This article reviews the ‘pro-poor’ macroeconomic policy alternative to the Washington consensus. The pro-poor approach draws heavily on heterodox economic theory, and offers a compelling view of an alternative economic strategy oriented primarily to the satisfaction of the basic needs of the majority of the population, the equitable distribution of income, wealth and power, and the preservation of macroeconomic stability. These aims point to a specific set of fiscal, monetary, trade and exchange rate policies. The paper argues that such policies should be supported by social programmes designed to achieve the desired pro-poor outcomes as rapidly as possible.

Acknowledgment

The author is grateful to two anonymous referees for their generous comments on a previous version of this article. The usual disclaimers apply.

Notes

1This article treats the terms ‘poor’ and ‘developing’ countries as synonyms. These countries are disaggregated, when necessary, into ‘very poor’ and ‘middle-income’ countries. For an overview of the pro-poor policy literature, see Dagdeviren et al. Citation(2002), Kakwani (Citation2001, Citation2002), Kakwani & Pernia Citation(2000), McCulloch & Baulch Citation(1999), McKinley (Citation2001, Citation2003, Citation2004), Osmani Citation(2001), Palanivel Citation(2003), Pasha & Palanivel Citation(2004), Rao Citation(2002), UNDP Citation(2002), Vandemoortele Citation(2004) and Winters Citation(2002).

2The MDG include the eradication of extreme poverty and hunger, universal primary education, promotion of gender equality, reduction of child mortality, improvements in maternal health, combating HIV/AIDS, malaria and other diseases, environmental sustainability and the creation of a global partnership for development. Detailed quantitative targets are provided in all these areas, and the goals should be achieved by 2015. For a detailed description and assessment of progress towards the MDG, see http://www.un.org/millenniumgoals/, http://www.undp.org/mdg/ and http://www.developmentgoals.com/UNDG%20document_final.pdf.

3In what follows we shall not be concerned with the work of dissenting mainstream economists, such as Jeffrey Sachs and Joseph Stiglitz (for overviews of their recent contributions, see http://www.earthinstitute.columbia.edu/about/director/ and http://www.josephtiglitz.com; for a critique, see Fine & Waeyenberge, Citation2006, and Waeyenberge, Citation2006). Despite their significant contribution at the level of economic policy and their unrivalled capacity (among dissenting economists) to bring to the attention of the media the problems of poverty, environmental degradation and the limitations of the Washington consensus, Sachs' and Stiglitz's critiques of mainstream policies remain firmly based on neoclassical economic principles (see Fine et al., 2001).

4This aim is not only important in itself; it is also mandated by the United Nations through the Universal Declaration of Human Rights, the Declaration on the Right to Development, and the Millennium Development Goals.

5For an assessment of the relationship between growth and equity, see Bowman Citation(1997), Cornia Citation(2004), Cramer Citation(2000), Kanbur Citation(1998), Niggle Citation(1998) and Persson & Tabellini Citation(1994). The case of agriculture is examined by Karshenas Citation(2001) and Kay Citation(2002).

6The expansion of the economy always helps to alleviate poverty, except in a small number of perverse cases. This is hardly sufficient: the point is how to maximise the impact of growth on poverty over the long term (see Dagdeviren et al., Citation2002, p. 391).

7In this literature, the rationale for distribution draws heavily on the work of Kalecki; see, for example, Ghosh Citation(2005) and Kalecki (Citation1972, Citation1993).

8Basic poverty is due to the low levels of income and productivity in a country, and it tends to decline as the economy grows (‘a rising tide lifts all boats’). Market-generated poverty is due to the lack of access to productive assets.

9These examples are merely indicative. The impact of growth on poverty depends on the initial distribution of income and, especially, its distribution near the poverty line, as well as the occupational composition, skills and other features of the workforce.

10There is an extensive literature on industrial policy and the developmental state; for a critical survey, see Fine Citation(2005). The importance of the balance of payments constraint for growth and development is examined by Thirlwall Citation(2003).

11The suggestion that middle-income countries should rely primarily on domestic rather than foreign savings is supported by the pioneering work of Feldstein & Horioka Citation(1980) and by more recent research by Calvo et al. Citation(1993). For a compelling heterodox interpretation of these findings, see Palma Citation(1998).

12For a heterodox assessment of the importance of fiscal policy for the current (neoliberal) period, see Arestis & Sawyer Citation(2003). Pro-poor fiscal policy is reviewed by Kakwani & Son Citation(2001) and Roy & Weeks Citation(2003).

13Even the prospect of policy change can trigger economic instability. This was the case in Brazil in 2002, when the impending election of President Lula led to capital flight and a severe exchange rate crisis (see Saad-Filho & Morais, Citation2003).

14According to Philip Arestis, ‘Sweden, Norway, Australia and Austria are the best examples in this respect’ (cited in Sicsú, Citation2001, p. 676).

15See, for example, Chang Citation(2003), Chang & Grabel (Citation2004, ch. 9), Eichengreen Citation(2003), Epstein et al. Citation(2003), Grabel Citation(2004), Helleiner Citation(1996), Kaplan & Rodrik Citation(2001) and MacEwan Citation(2003).

16Moderate exchange rate undervaluation finds strong support in the literature on trade and industrial policy; see Agosín & Tussie Citation(1993), Chang Citation(1994) and Gereffi & Wyman Citation(1990).

17Universal basic income (UBI) is the only type of non-targeted cash transfer. However, it is unaffordable for most very poor countries, and this is hardly the best use for the scarce resources of the middle-income countries. UBI is also vulnerable to most criticisms of cash transfers listed above.

18For example, Vandemoortele (Citation2004, p. 12) notes that user fees can ‘aggravate gender discrimination. … Since the mid-1990s, school fees have been abolished in Malawi and Uganda and more recently in Kenya. That pro-poor policy was followed by a surge in enrolment in all three countries—with girls being the prime beneficiaries. These positive experiences illustrate that even a small nominal fee can be a formidable obstacle for poor families.’

Log in via your institution

Log in to Taylor & Francis Online

PDF download + Online access

  • 48 hours access to article PDF & online version
  • Article PDF can be downloaded
  • Article PDF can be printed
USD 53.00 Add to cart

Issue Purchase

  • 30 days online access to complete issue
  • Article PDFs can be downloaded
  • Article PDFs can be printed
USD 625.00 Add to cart

* Local tax will be added as applicable

Related Research

People also read lists articles that other readers of this article have read.

Recommended articles lists articles that we recommend and is powered by our AI driven recommendation engine.

Cited by lists all citing articles based on Crossref citations.
Articles with the Crossref icon will open in a new tab.