2,802
Views
5
CrossRef citations to date
0
Altmetric
research

Energy-related standards and UK speculative office development

ORCID Icon

ABSTRACT

Non-domestic buildings have great potential for energy-related emission reductions in response to climate change. However, high-specification office buildings in the UK demonstrate that regulation, assessment and certification (‘standards’) have not incentivized the development of lower-energy office buildings as expected. Making use of the concepts of ‘qualculation’ and ‘calculative agency’, qualitative case studies of 10 speculatively developed office buildings in London, UK, provide new insight into why this is the case. Interview data (n = 57) are used to illustrate how ‘market standards’ substitute for user needs, and ratchet up the provision of building services to maximize marketability competitively. The examples of energy modelling and the market’s (mis)use of British Council for Offices guidelines are used to explain how such standards perversely bolster energy-demanding levels of specification and building services, and militate against lower-energy design, in the sector researched. The potentials for alternative, performance-based standards and new industry norms of quality are discussed. It is concluded that at least the London speculative office market by its very constitution and operation, including the reliance on standards, continues to create increasingly energy-demanding buildings.

Introduction

In the context of the UK’s Climate Change Act’s 2008 commitment to reduce greenhouse gas (GHG) emissions by at least 80% from a 1990 baseline by 2050 (HM Government, Citation2008), the decarbonization of all sectors of the economy and society is a pressing task. Energy use in buildings is estimated to account for 42% (Skea, Citation2012), with commercial sector buildings responsible for 8% (Committee on Climate Change, Citation2016), of the UK’s carbon dioxide emissions. This paper reports on research on a particular subset of non-domestic commercial sector buildings: ‘Grade A’ speculatively developed offices built or refurbished in London, 2010–15. Commercial office space is estimated to be growing twice as quickly as other non-domestic sectors (Green Construction Board, Citation2013), and its energy use and emissions are therefore especially significant.

In the commercial office sector, attention has been drawn to the ‘unnecessarily’ high energy demands (compared with known alternatives) and therefore environmental impacts of offices built to what is described as an institutional specification (Guy, Citation1998), investment quality (Guertler, Pett, & Kaplan, Citation2005), or more simply over-specification (Pinder, Schmidt, & Saker, Citation2013; Van de Wetering & Wyatt, Citation2011; Wade, Pett, & Ramsay, Citation2003). In the UK’s dominant mode of speculative office building development (Deloitte Real Estate, Citation2014; Pellegrini-Masini & Leishman, Citation2011), where buildings are built in advance of securing tenants, such buildings have historically been ‘over-specified in order to make them more attractive to institutional investors [and] … easier to let to suitable tenants’ (Van de Wetering & Wyatt, Citation2011, p. 32) This has particularly required the ‘over-specifying’ of:

small-power provision and comfort cooling services … promoted by property agents … even though the specification did not bear any resemblance to what most occupiers actually needed from their office buildings. … This misguided attempt at designing in redundancy … resulted in more expensive and more energy intensive office buildings. (Pinder et al., Citation2013, p. 442; see also Guy, Citation1998, pp. 268–271)

The subsector of prime or ‘Grade A’ office buildings therefore holds great technical potential (Moezzi & Janda, Citation2014) for energy or carbon savings.

In the UK, a number of different regulatory and voluntary assessments of office buildings (guidelines, labelling and certification schemes) operate as energy efficiency or performance ‘standards’ in that they define acceptable, expected, normal, legitimate and uniform features and performance of buildings (Faulconbridge, Cass, & Connaughton, Citation2017). These include building regulations and building environmental assessment mechanisms (BEAMs) (Cole, Citation2005; Goulden, Erell, Garb, & Pearlmutter, Citation2015), the analysis of which has focused ‘on technical features and building performance, with little emphasis on the questions of how and why they are used in practice’ (Goulden et al., Citation2015, pp. 1–2; also Schweber, Citation2013). Together their use standardizes office designs, enabling the comparison of buildings as products in a market.

This is particularly the case in speculative development where standards (of various types) are classically used to provide for unknown users, just as they enable markets to operate by providing standard and homogeneous commodities (Carruthers & Stinchcombe, Citation1999; Timmermans & Epstein, Citation2010). Given that several such ‘standards’ were intended to put a ceiling on energy-intensive quality specifications (British Council for Offices guidance – BCO), energy waste (energy performance certificates – EPCs) and unsustainability and carbon emissions (Building Research Establishment Environmental Assessment Method – BREEAM), this paper considers how it is that such ‘standards’ do not deliver low-energy office buildings.

This involves moving beyond narrow economistic understandings of standards/labels as unambiguous market signals. Here it proposed that qual/cal-culation (Callon & Law, Citation2005; Callon & Muniesa, Citation2005; Cochoy, Citation2002) is used as a way of thinking about (1) the role of standards within a market environment, subsuming judgements and calculations of value, price etc.; and (2) ‘calculative agency’ as the ability to define which features of a product are paramount in the market.

From this perspective, the key questions are about how standards are used, ‘perform’ and make market exchanges possible. These questions were explored empirically in case studies of 10 London offices and semi-structured interviews with 57 actors in the buildings’ design teams and the wider speculative development world. The results illustrate how processes of qualculation in action have the perverse effect of escalating rather than containing energy demand, at least in the speculative office development market in London.

(Not) delivering speculatively built lower-energy offices

A better understanding of the energy efficiency of specifically commercial office buildings has previously been identified as a research gap (Axon, Bright, Dixon, Janda, & Kolokotroni, Citation2012; Nicholls, Citation2014; Oreszczyn & Lowe, Citation2009), although recent studies have contributed much to knowledge, focusing particularly on benchmarking (Hsu, Citation2014), the performance gap (Cohen & Bordass, Citation2015; De Wilde, Citation2014; Fedoruk, Cole, Robinson, & Cayuela, Citation2015; Lewry, Citation2015; van Dronkelaar, Dowson, Spataru, & Mumovic, Citation2016), the accuracy of building assessment methods (see below), effects on rent and sale values (Kontokosta, Citation2013) and behavioural influences and interventions (Hong & Lin, Citation2014; Mulville, Jones, Huebner, & Powell-Greig, Citation2016; Tetlow, van Dronkelaar, Beaman, Elmualim, & Couling, Citation2015).

To justify the selection of the case study buildings, Schiellerup and Gwilliam (Citation2009, p. Citation812) suggest the commercial property market is:

an important test case for society’s capacity for change in the face of the challenges of climate change if for no other reason than the enormous economic value embodied in it and the comparatively large potential for savings.

London contains 26% of the UK’s office floor space and 48% of its rateable value (Guertler et al., Citation2005). The London office market has its unique features, particularly the City of London sub-market (Lizieri, Baum, & Scott, Citation2000), very short leases and the high stress on exchange rather than use value in comparison with European design (Guy, Citation1998). However, in terms of the internationalization of building design and development practices (Faulconbridge & Grubbauer, Citation2015; MacLaran, Citation2014) and of property (real estate) values over longer timescales, London office markets have been seen to function similarly to other global cities (Hendershott, Lizieri, & Matysiak, Citation1999), making it a suitable sample to study. Other studies of energy performance and standards have similarly compared across global samples (Cole & Valdebenito, Citation2013; Roderick, McEwan, Wheatley, & Alonso, Citation2009). The findings presented apply specifically to the London sample and context, but the specific analysis of the processes of operation of a Grade A office building speculative development market could be generalizable to other comparable global cities. This confirmation is beyond the purview of the paper.

In looking at the failure to deliver lower-energy offices it must be acknowledged that ‘[w]hat constitutes a lower energy office, given a widely variable office typology, is not easily defined’ (Guertler et al., Citation2005, p. 295). This paper defines a lower-energy office as one designed to minimize the amount of energy required in normal operation. This is not to deny the existence or importance of the ‘performance gap’ (Fedoruk et al., Citation2015) as an explanation of how energy performance can fail to manifest. It is clearly important that many energy demanding processes are unregulated, and that the ways in which tenants occupy buildings can be responsible for much energy use (Arup, Citation2013; Fedoruk et al., Citation2015; Menezes, Cripps, Bouchlaghem, & Buswell, Citation2012). Instead it is important to push similar enquiries into the design processes. Certain aspects of lower-energy offices are known and identifiable, including, for example, form, structural features and servicing arrangements that favour passive design and, therefore, allow passive or natural rather than mechanical heating, ventilation and air-conditioning (HVAC) (Bordass, Citation2000). As an example, displacement ventilation supplanted at the perimeters could provide lower energy cooling whilst satisfying the subsector’s demand for fresh air volumes for productivity and wellbeing (Seppänen, Fisk, & Lei, Citation2006). Numerous institutions issue guidelines on prioritizing low-energy features in design (Energy Efficiency Office, Citation2000; RIBA, Citation2009; Wade, Pett, Ramsay, & House, Citation2003; Westminster Sustainable Business Forum & Carbon Connect, Citation2013). However, taken together such features also including narrow and shallow floor-plates and high ceilings have been described as reflecting a (northern) European genre of office design based on ‘use’ value and known user needs backed by regulation, rather than an Anglo-Saxon or American mode focused on ‘exchange value’ and unknown future user needs (Duffy & Powell, Citation1997; Guy, Citation1998) dominant in the UK.

The origins of the various formal standards used in the UK are evidence of attempts to use regulation and market signals to incentivize the construction of more energy-efficient buildings. The rationales for and effects of the use of voluntary or market-based instruments per se are not the focus here, but have been analysed elsewhere (Van der Heijden, Citation2016). BREEAM is a credits-based voluntary certification scheme of broad ‘sustainability’ rather than energy performance, with ‘Energy’ being one category of nine in which buildings can score assessment credits. However, since its inception in 1990 it has been used successfully to convey ‘green’ value on buildings (Schiellerup & Gwilliam, Citation2009). Arising from a, now fully privatized, quasi-autonomous non-governmental organization, the Buildings Research Establishment, its use has successfully internationalized from the UK to the world (Cole & Valdebenito, Citation2013). EPCs are a UK-specific regulatory requirement of rating the modelled energy efficiency of a building, and provided the UK’s compliance with the European Union’s Energy Performance of Buildings Directives of 2002 and 2010 (Economidou, Citation2012), although they do not set absolute performance targets, instead relying on modelled comparisons with a ‘reference’ building, in a similar way to the UK’s mandatory energy-efficiency building regulation, ‘Part L’ or properly Part L2A of the Building Regulations 2010. Their role is being transformed from a rating to a benchmark (i.e. legal minimum) standard, as from 2018 buildings must score A–F to be rented or sold. ‘Part L’ addresses the ‘conservation of fuel and power in new buildings other than dwellings’ (HM Government, Citation2013), and requires demonstrated improvements on the performance of a modelled building against a reference (Raslan & Davies, Citation2010). Increasing expectations of improvements mean the regulation should act as a ratchet of increased performance. The BCO’s guidelines on office specification differ in their origin as a ‘trade organization’ of office building developers whose interest is primarily in issues of quality benchmarking, to ensure comparability of products that achieve compliance. It has no specific energy focus, but was instituted to avoid an ‘arms race’ in energy-demanding ‘prime’ specifications, as explained by an interviewee: ‘something was needed to stop this ridiculous Dutch auction where more was always better even when manifestly it wasn’t’ (consultant).

The question that this paper seeks to address, then, is why, given that the efficacy and desirability of known features of a lower-energy office buildings are enshrined in governmental and professional advice (as well as the suite of ‘standards’ explored here), have they not been more widely incorporated?

One explanation focuses on a ‘cycle of blame’ (Bordass, Citation2000) in which investors, developers, designers, landlords and tenants are all said to be disincentivized from producing a lower-energy office building by lack of demand from the other actors. The commercial property world seems to subscribe to a model (Brown, Malmqvist, & Wintzell, Citation2016) in which markets provide information and choices amongst alternatives, and policy assists such decision-making through ‘building codes and engineering standards, information and technical assistance, and financial incentives’ (Biggart & Lutzenhiser, Citation2007, p. 1077). In short, the paucity of low-energy offices is taken to be an example of market correction failure. The correctives prescribed are better pricing and valuing, and establishing a premium for energy-efficient buildings; in the UK, primarily through using BREEAM as an indication of ‘greenness’ (Bordass, Citation2000; Schiellerup & Gwilliam, Citation2009). EPC ratings were also intended to fulfil a similar function as they:

allow a differentiation in the market in terms of the energy performance of buildings … address an information market failure and therefore permit … the integration of energy performance into the market for buildings. (Schiellerup & Gwilliam, Citation2009, p. 802)

Another potential explanation is then that investors and developers might see no financial incentive to do so, as ‘customers’ (i.e. building investors, managers and tenants) might not pay a ‘green premium’ or avoid a ‘grey discount’ (De Jong & Parkinson, Citation2013; Elliott, Bull, & Mallaburn, Citation2015; Kontokosta, Citation2013; Oyedokun, Jones, & Dunse, Citation2015; Surmann, Brunauer, & Bienert, Citation2015). The link between energy efficiency or green certification and higher rents is, however, taken for granted in the industry and evidenced as a ‘willingness to pay’ for a certified ‘eco-label’ (Fuerst & van de Wetering, Citation2015). Such forms of green certification have indeed been found globally to correlate with a (small) rental price premium (Fuerst & McAllister, Citation2011a; Wiley, Benefield, & Johnson, Citation2010) used to support this model (Axon et al., Citation2012; Fuerst, van de Wetering, & Wyatt, Citation2013). This willingness to pay is potentially self-fulfilling, with the most recent meta-analysis of US data (Fuerst, Gabrieli, & McAllister, Citation2017) finding that ‘eco-investors’ pay the most for environmentally certified properties. It might also be self-correcting, as its mainstreaming reduces the differentiation value (Chegut, Eichholtz, & Kok, Citation2013). These two qualities display that the market is ‘performative’, i.e. the world of ‘green building value’ is brought into being through the enacting (and study) of this market differentiation (Callon, Citation2007). The existence of a ‘green premium’ linked specifically to EPCs and BREEAM certification in the UK has, however, been questioned (Fuerst & McAllister, Citation2008), and in the absence of performance data being required in certification, the premiums identified may not reflect performance as ‘the presence of an environmental label and superior environmental performance are not necessarily synonymous’ (Fuerst & McAllister, Citation2011, p. 1220).

However, actual energy consumption of office buildings has been found to vary significantly across all EPC ratings of buildings in the UK (Better Buildings Partnership, Citation2012) and Leadership in Energy and Environmental Design (LEED)-certified buildings abroad (Newsham, Mancini, & Birt, Citation2009). It has also been suggested that using such voluntary ‘green labels’ as LEED/BREEAM is strongly correlated with already high-value buildings, meaning that the ‘added value’ or price signals conferred by such assessments and badging exercises are confounded and do not incentivize low-energy buildings (Chegut et al., Citation2013; Fuerst & McAllister, Citation2011b). Although common in business and policy, this economic framing of standards and labels as effective and unambiguous price signals represents a narrow understanding of how standards function in society and in markets (Timmermans & Epstein, Citation2010), and how they are situated in a landscape of cultural, market, institutional, technical and organizational influences that bear on this specific regime of speculative office building design and servicing. The multilevel perspective of socio-technical transitions (Gertz, Citation2005; Markard, Raven, & Truffer, Citation2012) is one alternative framing through which to view the mainstreaming of a ‘niche’ market such as low-energy offices, in the context of an established regime of dominant interests.

UK office over-specification can also be seen as involving specific market features, organizational characteristics, shortening lease lengths, changing office typologies, space rationalization etc. (Biggart & Lutzenhiser, Citation2007). Such an historical, context-specific understanding of different actors co-constructing offices as ‘desirable space’ (Schiellerup & Gwilliam, Citation2009) helps explain how key ‘standards’ such as Part L building regulations, EPCs, BCO guidance and BREEAM are used to translate, assume, anticipate and, thus, institutionalize understandings of user ‘needs’ whose satisfaction perpetuates conservative networks of design (Guy, Citation2002). In speculative modes of development these understandings become particularly powerful in producing homogeneous designs stressing marketability, flexibility, performance and quality, which together characterize desirable office space. Achieving these characteristics and displaying that this has been accomplished is achieved through adherence to, or exceeding, ‘market standards’ (Faulconbridge et al., Citation2017) often in ways that render lower-energy alternatives illegitimate and unacceptable. However, the process through which such standards operate is not merely a reflection of the historical context of the UK property market: it is also a consequence of how standards are embedded in markets and performed at different stages of design and marketing. In producing various calculations about the value of different aspects of a building’s design, those involved enact the conditions of a market of comparable goods, through drawing attention to their relevant qualities (MacKenzie, Muniesa, & Siu, Citation2007) through ‘qualculation’ and the exercise of ‘calculative agency’.

The concept of qualculation introduced by Cochoy (Citation2002) avoids the more limited understandings of calculations as being either the purely rational decision of agents in an economic model, or qualitative judgements, instead seeing these as extremes of a spectrum. The first understanding is well known, and Callon and Muniesa explain the latter as being a ‘sociological’ model of calculations as:

at best an ex post rationalization for choices grounded in other logics … a matter of pure judgement or conjecture or … something originating in institutions or cultural norms. (Callon & Muniesa, Citation2005, p. 1230)

Qualculation as a concept asserts that market calculations are a performative admixture of fact and value, making qualculation distinct from simple quantification seen as a tool of governance and management (Lippert, Citation2015).

Callon and Muniesa’s (Citation2005) explanation of calculation encompasses Cochoy’s qualculation, as they describe it as describing situations ‘in which the customer has to choose certain objects placed beforehand in the same spatial and temporal frame’ (Callon & Muniesa, Citation2005, p. 1232). This can be seen as a case of market calculation in general. They explain calculation’s role in enabling and enacting a market by suggesting that for a market to be possible, a three-part process takes place in which:

the entities taken into account have to be … arranged and ordered in a single space … then compared and manipulated on the basis of a common operating principle. … A third step is necessary … a result has to be extracted … that corresponds precisely to the manipulations effected … it has to be able to leave the calculative space and circulate elsewhere in an acceptable way. (p. 1231)

This means that ‘market calculations are disentanglements that secure calculability’ (Callon & Law, Citation2005, p. 722) – they extract specific aspects from a good in order to make the whole comparable with others, which inserts it into the market thus created. Such calculations happen at multiple points in the creation of a product or good as complex as a building. In different situations different qualities are drawn out for comparison, and others are obscured. In these simplifications, ‘because agents are faced with complicated tasks … they conceive of tools, create rules and routines or set up organizations to calculate for them’ (Callon & Muniesa, Citation2005, p. 1237). It is argued here that the standards, guidelines and assessment processes associated with designing office buildings are examples of such institutionalized calculations, distributed through time and space.

In essence the point is that ‘framing’ goods with others to which they can be compared:

is a process of classification, clustering and sorting that makes products both comparable and different. The consumer can make choices only if the goods have been endowed with properties that produce distinctions. (Cochoy, Citation2002)

Also known as ‘positioning’, this ‘linking up implies … quality labels or, more generally, quality standards – that measure and objectify certain properties’ (Callon & Muniesa, Citation2005, p. 1235). The ranking of different buildings against each other using chosen characteristics and matters of judgement is another such moment of qualculation. The power to position and compare goods in this manner is named ‘calculative agency’ by Callon and Muniesa and in this case it is distributed between design teams, developers, the institutions that produce standards and guidelines (including the state) and intermediaries who perform qualculations on behalf of these actors. However, the critical point of calculative agency is the moment of presenting a building (or design) as a product for valuation and comparison in a buying/letting market, drawing on its certifications, badges, and evidence of compliance with market standards; each themselves the product of other qualculations.

Understanding the assessment and marketing of office buildings in these terms promises to shed some light on the failure to deliver low-energy offices as the result of uneven and competing calculative agencies located across design and marketing, in which the rental market is the ultimately powerful calculation site towards which all other calculations are orientated.

Methods and research design

The research on which this paper draws worked with these ideas to understand the design of office buildings in London, built or refurbished between 2010 and 2015, and how their energy demand resulted from attempts to satisfy unknown users’ needs and expectations. These were defined and assumed through design processes. To address rising energy demand, it is crucial to examine how these ‘needs’ were constructed. The data-collection proceeded in three stages. Initial semi-structured interviews with highly influential consultants (n = 3), architects (n = 2) and building developers/managers (n = 6) to whom access was possible explored the key influences at play. These confirmed initial hypotheses that a variety of standards, guidelines, rules of thumb, assessments and regulations (hereafter ‘standards’) are powerful factors. The coding of these interviews provided the detailed inductive coding framework for the subsequent interviews. A decision was made to examine speculative developments as the dominant mode of office developments in the London (Deloitte Real Estate, Citation2014), and after discussion with key stakeholders including the BCO the research concentrated on a portfolio of 10 case study buildings to explore how these influences, and key within them, standards, play out across different buildings. The portfolio was selected on the basis of an interviewee suggestion in one case, the remainder being identified by desk research. The criteria for selection were the availability online of space plans and specifications, and the desire for a comparable sample of buildings differentiated on a number of key features, e.g. age, tenancy, development modes, location, size and HVAC systems. The sample of buildings, and therefore interviewees, was thus random enough to avoid the potential for interviewer confirmation bias (Roulston & Shelton, Citation2015), but it is unavoidably biased towards buildings that were advertised to a wider public (and therefore may have been struggling to let space). The intention to pursue a mixed-methods case study approach (Creswell, Citation2013) combined with advice from the initial interviews determined that in stage two, interviews with the actors most influential on design would help to interrogate the available documentary data. This determined that, at the least, interviews with the architects, mechanical and electrical (M&E) engineering consultants, and letting agents for each case building were required. Investors and (at the time of design, unknown) tenants were excluded as their influence on design in speculative developments is mediated through agents.

summarizes some of the building characteristics, and which stakeholders were interviewed for each of the 10 buildings. The interviews were designed to elicit how standards were used in design, and enacted certain understandings of user ‘need’ in the production of a marketable building. This involved comparing the specifications, standards etc. that shaped the end form and therefore designed energy demand into the buildings, elicited through questions about general influences on design, and interrogating aspects of the buildings’ specifications and features identified through documentary material.

Table 1. Case study building and interview summaries.

Towards the end of the interviews detailed in , meetings of the research team determined that the data collected were saturated for the three interviewer categories (Guest, Bunce, & Johnson, Citation2006), for example, as responses confirming exploratory interpretive analysis were consistently highlighted (Ponelis, Citation2015). However, the perspectives of developers, construction and real estate, and valuation actors had been characterized and considered important by the interviewees, but were not directly represented. This led to a decision to conduct follow-up interviews with further individuals selected to represent these categories. Thirteen individuals were chosen based on their membership of key stakeholder representative groups, and having multiple associations, i.e. they could talk about the perspective of their employer and of other stakeholder groups through their membership. Guarantees of anonymity prevent further explanation of sample-selection processes.

A total of 57 individuals were interviewed: 17 architects, 11 M&E engineers, eight letting agents, nine developers and 12 others, including stakeholder representatives, consultants and one occupier. The anonymised interview data are the basis of much of the following analysis. References to the data appear in parentheses in the analysis thus ‘(A)’ and refer to the lettered quotations given in and . The interviews were thematically coded by two researchers using NVivo qualitative analysis software, using a mixture of deductive and inductive codes (for a detailed explanation of the coding and analysis processes, see the Appendix below). This enabled the extraction of data segments coded with multiple relevant codes, which were used as the material for analysis. The use of software to perform such analytical refinements in an interpretive mode of analysis (Bazeley & Jackson, Citation2013, pp. 242–265) is, of course, only possible with a deep familiarity with the dataset as a whole, and the selections of themes for analysis proceeded on the basis of discussions with the whole research team. Interpretive qualitative research aims at producing a narrative that accurately reflects the meanings and understandings of the social world described, rather than statistical representation of views expressed.

Table 2. Design priorities of marketable buildings.

Table 3. Perverse effects of market standard compliance.

During the analysis, two key themes emerged. First, the processes through which compliance with standards were achieved; and second, the means by which the standards themselves function in the market, with implications for energy demand. The following sections elaborate on these themes, after an exploration of the main features of speculative office design through adherence to market standards.

Analysis

Speculative design for unknown future users

The speculative nature of the studied developments makes market standards an important means of substituting for known user needs. However, their use consequently reproduces numerous standard assumptions which have important effects on building design that lock-in higher energy demand. To give two examples of over-provision to satisfy assumed needs, firstly there is the almost universal use of use of four-pipe fan-coil unit air-conditioning systems in ‘Grade A’ offices (see below) to deal with large imagined potential cooling needs. This was not justified primarily in terms of ventilation and its link with productivity (lower-energy ventilation systems can anyway deliver adequate fresh air; Cao et al., Citation2014; Feige, Wallbaum, Janser, & Windlinger, Citation2013), but in terms of it providing ‘flexibility’ to unknown and therefore potentially high ‘needs’. Secondly, the provision of capacity for occupiers to extract large amounts of ‘small power’ (the UK term for plug loads, or power demanded by occupiers’ appliances and devices; Menezes, Cripps, Buswell, Wright, & Bouchlaghem, Citation2014) exceeds the loads regulated under the building’s EPC ratings (Arup, Citation2013), and has consistently exceeded users’ empirical needs (British Council for Offices, Citation2009, Citation2014).

In contrast to buildings commissioned by their occupants, speculatively developed offices are primarily built or refurbished to provide a return on investment; to be sold on immediately or let by the developer in order to recoup rents. This means that these buildings are financial or rental assets, ‘products’ whose designs must be marketable to potential owners or occupiers by letting agents. In the words of one architect interviewee, they ‘are investment vehicles, they are all about providing a return for a pension or for some sort of insurance policy’.

Different interviews revealed different lists of design considerations that were considered important to produce a marketable building design (, quotation A). The top-level market considerations were to: maximize net internal area (NIA – the leasable floor space; quotation B); be of high (enough) quality; meet market expectations and norms; and provide flexibility for all potential occupiers.

Historically, maximizing NIA has driven office design towards deep floor-plates arranged around a central services core in as high a building as permissible under, for example, planning regimes (Albrecht & Broikos, Citation2000, pp. 22–23). Multiple interviews confirmed that speculative developments in general were designed to ‘squeeze the [building services] core’ to maximize NIA. A letting agent stressed that with every project they ask ‘could we put two more floors on? … is there any way of squeezing something?’, and an M&E engineer explicitly suggested that:

the big reason a lot of developers from a speculative perspective wouldn’t go down [the route of lower energy] displacement [ventilation] is … the core area hit.

Two other engineers stressed that stated that maximizing NIA and ‘making the core as efficient as you possible can … applies to every building’, and that ‘the net lettable area … that’s what a spec[ulative] office developer wants to maximise’. Thus, lower-energy ‘mixed-mode’ HVAC options and displacement ventilation require more riser (horizontal) or floor-to-ceiling (vertical) space, both aspects that conflict with maximizing NIA.

Quality (often aesthetic) design expectations were said to manifest in: often glassy facades (quotation C); spacious lobbies, swift lifts, and marble toilets (quotation D); and an aesthetic of bright, light, airy openness (quotation E). All these features were common for the buildings in the sample, with double-height lobbies, for example, in seven out of 10 case buildings, and where they were not possible, heights were raised:

we created a much grander reception area … single storey but … it’s probably two, two and a half times the size of the previous reception. (M&E engineer).

These priorities of maximized NIA and quality contributed to market expectations and norms of what interviewees called ‘Grade A’ space. This specific phrase refers to a heuristic understanding of high-rental-value office space that has no strictly formal or institutional foundation: there is no explicit method of certifying a property as Grade A. However, it is a concept shared across the market, including internationally (Chung & Hui, Citation2009), and encompassing several specific features even though ‘there’s no definition, which is a strange one’ (West End Office Agents Society – WEOAS). Of 53 explicit mentions of Grade A features, 38 arose from letting agents and developers, displaying that the concept is rooted in marketing and valuation. Interviewees specified their understandings of a Grade A office in ‘their markets’ as comprising ‘an air conditioned, raised floor, suspended ceilings with LED lighting conforming to BCO guidance’ with:

a large grand impressive reception area … four pipe fan coil air conditioning … serviced in the basement by lockers, showers etc. and … clear open plan floorplates. (WEOAS)

Grade A features also include prime locations, certain levels and qualities of provision (e.g. of toilets, stairways and lifts) and (theoretical) performance. Such features as location and quality materials are undeniably linked with high-value buildings, but their influence is not the focus of this paper, which discusses buildings’ expected or modelled energy efficiency. It is in this area that the most detail regarding what have been treated elsewhere (Faulconbridge et al., Citation2017) as different institutionally legitimated ‘market standards’ could be found.

The most important of these ‘market standards’ in the area of ‘green performance’ can be seen as comprising a ‘tick-list’ (quotation F) of essential features for a marketable office, which were consistently listed as comprising:

  • EPC rating of A or B (quotation G)

  • BCO guidance compliance (quotation H)

  • a BREEAM rating of ‘Excellent’ (quotation I)

The quotations in show that the purpose of such ‘tick-lists’ is to produce an easily assessable building design in terms of inserting it into a rental market and letting it out quickly and easily. Schweber (Citation2013, p. 134) similarly describes BREEAM tick-lists as ‘a substitute for technical or more detailed knowledge’ for clients. The design priorities embedded in the lists are in turn based not primarily on a concern with energy efficiency per se, but the market requirement for flexibility, as a speculatively developed office building needs to have a form, fabric and structure capable of accommodating different potential uses, i.e. no building should be designed and serviced in a way that might potentially rule out its being let to anyone.

Interviews confirmed increasing ‘churn’ (owner or occupier turnover) in the London office market enabled by the steady shortening of leases and particularly of ‘break’ periods: the period of time, shorter than the lease length, after which the lease can be renegotiated or broken. All this means building design must be standardized (‘generic’ in quotation J) to allow any potential tenant to fit-out the building to their own needs. Again, particular forms (deep plan), fabrics (high-performance facade) along with four-pipe fan-coil unit HVAC systems are seen to provide this flexibility. A space with these features is seen as an idealized ‘blank canvas’ that potential tenants can move into and adapt for themselves (quotations K and L). This drive for flexibility results in designing for imagined tenants with the highest potential occupational densities and/or small power requirements; each of which drives up modelled heat gain peaks, and thus cooling requirements. As the BCO (Citation2013, p. 30) asks: ‘Should the optimum flexibility afforded by high specification, and required by a relatively small segment of the demand market, justify its blanket provision?’ Taking these forms of flexibility together, the building services and internal spatial organization of London’s Grade A office buildings are driven by ‘the market’ to an energy-demanding one-size-fits-all model: highly standardized offices brightly lit and air-conditioned with suspended ceilings and raised floors, and provided with small power capacity well above average needs.

The supervening consideration is achieving compliance with the set of market standards in the checklist given above. These are processes of calculation in which specific features of the designed building are foregrounded and manipulated as Callon and Muniesa (Citation2005) describe, making it possible to compare the modelled building with others. Calculative agency is involved in proving these essential compliances for inserting a building into the market. This makes meeting standards subject to strategic action in order to hit necessary targets, as explored below.

Strategies for meeting standards and demonstrating compliance

Historically, from 1994, the BCO’s guidelines represented an attempt to put a ceiling on ‘high specifications’ which were both expensive for developers and had undesirable environmental implications – specifically high energy use and CO2 emissions (Guy, Citation1998). In theory, compliance with it, together with achieving high ratings in performance standards, should result in buildings with lower energy consumption than might otherwise be the case, given that such standards demonstrate that the building should perform better in terms of reduced CO2 emissions (BREEAM) or energy efficiency through, for example, insulation and reducing solar gains (EPC) than a standard ‘reference’ building.

To take these aspects as examples, it is – ironically – possible to demonstrate that the designing of compliant and marketable buildings actually drives the designing of higher energy consumption into buildings. BREEAM has been analysed elsewhere for how its use resembles other multi-criteria sustainability assessments that have been found not to guarantee energy performance (Goulden et al., Citation2015; Newsham et al., Citation2009; Scofield, Citation2013). It has been further suggested that BREEAM functions as a design guide similarly to a tick-list (Ding, Citation2008), whose very flexibility in achieving compliance may explain its uptake as a model for other assessments internationally (Cole & Valdebenito, Citation2013; Ding, Citation2008). Its ‘Energy’ criterion is also primarily based on a building’s EPC. Therefore, the following analysis of how market standards fail to ensure energy performance focuses instead on how BCO guidance is used in building design, and first how energy modelling can be used strategically in achieving compliance through the exercise of calculative agency.

EPC ratings, Part L compliance and the dark art of modelling

A ‘performance gap’ has been identified between EPC ratings and real-world energy consumption data (Better Buildings Partnership, Citation2012; Cohen & Bordass, Citation2015; Menezes et al., Citation2012). This is ascribed to the behaviour of building occupants, and a ‘perception gap’ in which calculations do not refer to all the energy a building uses. The perception gap has been shown to result in, for example, underestimating cooling energy consumption by 44% (Arup, Citation2013). The interviews identified an additional issue of strategic action used to ensure that a building design achieves compliance with Part L and a high EPC rating. These strategic actions entail the exercise of calculative agency in creating a ‘fact’, the rating, whose ‘origins ha[ve] been “forgotten” once the fact was used as a “black box”’ (Latour & Woolgar, Citation1979, cited in Lynch, Citation1993, p. 94). The calculation itself is black boxed in the sense that only the output is considered – being fed into later calculations, particularly of rental value. Goulden et al. (Citation2015, p. 2) similarly describe the ‘interpretative flexibility’ of black-boxed BEAMs and note that such standards ‘do not necessarily excel in or emphasize energy-efficient design’ (p. 9).

The capacity to be strategic has several aspects. First, for designers/modellers there is the capacity to set the reference building (, quotation M), e.g. based on HVAC systems, as air-conditioned buildings have different targets in these models to lower energy naturally ventilated ones. Others include the strategic choices of modelling software (quotation N) approved by the National Calculation Methodology (NCM) of Part L2A and feeding into the ‘energy model’ model used in assessing the EPC, or of different levels of accuracy within these models (quotation O), in order to achieve the desired results primarily by adjusting models rather than the fabric or infrastructures of the building itself. The energy model can be adjusted to target different standards (quotation P), meaning that it ‘has become incredibly important because it drives the EPC, BREEAM compliance, all these things’ (architect). The variability of both baselines and improved building models allowed by the use of NCM permitted software in the UK has been previously identified (Raslan & Davies, Citation2010). Studies (e.g. on the use of standard assessment procedure modelling for UK residential buildings; Kelly, Crawford-Brown, & Pollitt, Citation2012) have also suggested that models and assessments may have perverse effects as ‘ill-conceived building performance and evaluation criteria may actually incentivise an increase in CO2 emissions in some circumstances’ (Kelly et al., Citation2013, p. 603). Expertise in these strategies builds knowledge of how to match inputs, parameters and models to fulfil a marketable building’s ‘tick box’ (quotation Q), within the marketability demands imposed by, for example, unique and distinctive architecture. Agents were said to demand that designers calculate:

how they can get big windows to work … we want big glass buildings … you need a wow factor to be able to get to that level of rent and that level of yield for your property. (consultant)

Thus, in our sample, strategic action achieves both standards compliance and ‘the wow factor’ (quotation R): two key ingredients of marketability in the most important qualculation of rental value.

These examples involve strategically achieving ‘badges’ of performance potential. In the next section, standards themselves are shown to increase assumptions of need and provision, and then to be (ab)used by market actors, in using voluntary guidelines in a competitive manner.

How standards lead to escalating energy demand: ‘BCO+’ and ratcheting

In addition to ‘gaming’ compliance processes, the example of the BCO’s guidance illustrates how ‘standards’ can be enacted with perverse consequences. The intended dampening nature of BCO guidance was transformed and arguably distorted in its use as a baseline: an example of calculative agency that again assesses certain qualities of the building to enable comparability and competition in the broader market.

BCO guidelines were cited as a baseline of provision against which both developers and potential tenants usually assess buildings; each being advised by agents. Aligning a building’s specification with BCO guidance was an element of the identified checklist explained above, which overrides other priorities such as environmental performance or occupier satisfaction:

a lot of it is a tick box exercise of ‘does this building comply with BCO?’ … whole life costs analysis might not be … as important. The occupiers’ enjoyment of the space perhaps isn’t of upmost important because … there’s greater reliance upon … benchmark industry standard for measuring the quality of the building. (M&E engineer)

This focus also leads to high specification and over-provision through ratcheting increases over time in minimum acceptable levels of some (energy demanding) services. Ventilation is a good example in which there is not only a ratcheting of the ‘standard’ (BCO 1994, 8– 12 litres of air/second/person, BCO 2014, 12–16 l/s/person; M. Pothitou, personal communication, 4 August 2015). Expectations exceed regulative (necessary) and normative (advisable) levels to satisfy cultural (essentially market) standards (quotation S) when developers demand supplements typically 10% above BCO guidance. This was described by numerous interviewees as ‘BCO+’:

BCO is the benchmark. But in London … you get a BCO+ … whatever the BCO says then the agents in London always want a little bit more. (M&E engineer; see also quotation EE).

Third, throughout discussion of specifications of, for example, small power capacity and fresh air there was a pervasive sense that that ‘more is better’. This was explained again as being driven by market priorities; provision for marketability. Anticipating that agents representing potential tenants will demand extra provision in negotiations as a ‘something for nothing’ (quotation T), developers feel obliged to provide it (quotation U). Lying behind all this is the anticipation of comparisons being made against other properties in the market, in qualculations of value: ‘If you’ve got more than the building next door, in whatever way … it makes it easy to sell’ (M&E engineer).

Fourth, in a ratcheting process one architect explicitly alleged is driven by letting agents (quotation V), where the BCO provides a range of potential values (e.g. ventilation 12–16 l/s/person), if the top end of the range is not provided, the building is suspected of being sub-standard: ‘You compare to the best of BCO’ (letting agent). In the case of cooling and ventilation, provided by air-conditioning ‘as standard’, needs are primarily constructed through modelling peak potential heat gains (quotation Z) that arise particularly from assumptions of small power usage and occupational densities. The BCO itself states (BCO, Citation2013, Citation2014) that in both areas empirical research has identified that the majority of buildings’ small power usage (quotation W) and ‘effective density’ (workplace space as occupied at different levels of utilization) are lower than their own guidance (quotation X).

On small power capacity, as and show, the BCO guidance of 15 W/m2 down from 25 W/m2 in the previous five guides, is being met and exceeded in the majority of the case buildings, which all provide 25 W/m2 with additional capacity, of about 15 W/m2, usually up to 40 W/m2, but up to 45–60 W/m2 in one case. As quotation W shows, the over-cooling of unrealistic power use levels is a trend that may worsen with more efficient device usage.

Table 4. British Council for Offices (BCO) guidelines on design occupational density.

Table 5. Occupancy density metrics used for each case building.

In the case of occupational densities – the key multiplier of heat gain and therefore cooling requirements – BCO guidance is that buildings should be designed assuming occupational density of one person per 10 m2 of NIA, flexible from 8–13 m2; a figure that has dropped slowly to represent increasing densities (). The BCO’s empirical research highlights average desk-space design densities from just under 1:10 to 1:13 m2, but note that when even unrealistically high assumptions of real-world utilization (70%; BCO, Citation2013, p. 25) (see also quotations X and AA) are applied, this equates to 95% of building space being occupied at densities of the guideline 1:10 m2 or lower. Buildings exceeding the guidance are essentially providing for less than 5% of likely occupation levels, a trend followed by the case buildings, as shown in . As quotation Y shows, designing office buildings with these extreme assumptions of occupation is again a matter of competitive comparison, anticipating potential tenant demands no matter how high or unlikely. Organizational rhythms further affect ‘diversity’ and the provision of services for absent workers (quotation T).

In terms of producing lower-energy offices, avoiding high levels of buildings services (e.g. excessive cooling or small power provision) or using passive or mixed-mode forms of ventilation are made almost impossible by this combination of competitive provision and unrealistic assumptions. Modelling heat gains and cooling requirements (in particular) using the upper values of competitive provision and in-built assumptions results in figures that cannot be satisfied with lower-energy systems or design options (quotation BB). The market ideal that equates quality with high levels of glazing, lighting, occupational density and small power capacities results almost inevitably in air-conditioned offices. Glazed facades’ solar gain can be mitigated through technical measures, meaning that small power, lighting and occupational densities are the main factors driving this ‘non-negotiable’ demand (quotation BB). This is a demand that some interviewees suggested does not reflect occupier preferences (quotation CC) and could be reduced in low-energy building designs (quotation DD).

The findings suggest that the BCO’s attempts to limit over-specification are trumped in our sample by maximizing and standardizing processes promoting competitive marketability above other considerations. BCO guidance’s upper limits are used not as a ceiling for provision but as a floor below which it is inadvisable to go (quotation G). BCO compliance, and now exceedance, was criticized as using it as a baseline of provision (quotation EE), and as a misuse of guidance for marketing purposes (quotation FF), in which guidance is used instead as a tick-box which does not result in ‘intelligent’ design (quotation GG). Many informants acknowledged that the BCO guide offered accurate and suitable guidance, but it was suggested that it was being misused as a prescriptive standard (see also Schindler, Citation2010, p. 334), a process of which the BCO says, by way of confirmation:

We are aware … that institutional purchasers of office buildings benchmark against similar properties … irrespective of occupier needs … favouring buildings with higher specification. The resulting higher value reinforces the cycle towards generally higher specification … the Guide has become, in reality, more of a prescriptive standard than a guide. (British Council for Offices, Citation2013, p. 30)

Although BCO guidance explicitly contains flexibility to allow fitting building specifications to diverse tenants, the speculative mode of development removes this possibility and instead applies market pressures for flexibility and marketability. The guidance is written collectively, but it was claimed that these calculative agencies of valuation have gained sway, and the expectations of the most demanding market have begun to be applied (quotation HH), out of step with not only low energy design but also allegedly occupier preferences (quotation II).

Summary

As the above has illustrated, speculative office building design is a matter of negotiating different processes of qualculation as a cultural and technical accomplishment. Aimed at the ultimate market-enacting calculations of rent/price valuations and ‘the deal’, buildings/designs/models have different aspects extracted, manipulated and compared in processes of qualculation to insert them into markets as comparable and competitive goods. As shown, achieving various ‘standards’ is considered unavoidable, and exceeding them has become advisable due to how such standards are embedded in building design practices and market exchanges. Thus strategic modelling and ratcheting provision as logical moves in qualculation exercises materialize certain qualities in office designs. Positioning buildings as goods in a speculative development market means that despite the existence of energy performance standards and specification guidelines, the very processes of market creation through qualculation drive competition to provide quality, flexibility and ever higher levels of building services, with predictable influences on designed-in energy demand.

The concepts of qualculation and calculative agency help to explain the puzzle of why ‘standards’ of various types fail to deliver lower-energy building designs in a competitive market. In the various modelling and evaluation processes of complying with ‘Part L’ and BCO, and achieving EPC A–B or BREEAM ‘Excellent’ the modelled performance of buildings is fluid and reacts to and determines changes in those designs. The target for modelled performance is known and calculative agency is the ability to foreground particular qualities and quantities and obscure others to make the hypothetical building comparable with others and competitive according to other sites of calculation, particularly the valuation checklists of agents. During the design process at least, the ability to manipulate building models and assessment processes such as BREEAM checklists is calculative agency insofar as it is fluid, the modelled building ‘never gives an accurate figure; because its figures are constantly undermining those that came before. … Instead, it’s about keeping things open’ (Callon & Law, Citation2005, p. 730). Strategic action enters into this space of openness until a target is reached and the means of achieving it can be black boxed away from sight: once BREEAM ‘Excellent’ has been reached, ‘nobody ever asks the question’ (quotation I).

At the end of the calculation processes through which the modelled building is made into a singular good and made marketable through its comparability and competitive ranking against others, the most important moment of calculation is the granting of ‘Grade A’ quality and the production of a rental value pegged against other similar and comparable properties and past deals. This calculative agency subsumes all previous instances of qualculation within itself, which explains the considerable power of agents acting for owners, and for potential or assumed tenants and sellers, as the ultimate arbiters of ‘Grade A’ assignation. As Callon and Muniesa (Citation2005) explain with reference to double-entry book-keeping, technologies of calculation such as the tools and institutions of market standards join with the actions of the calculators to produce ‘distributed calculative agency’. Between them, letting agents and the institutions have created the concept of environmental comparability, along with the broader currents of environmentalism, building design, legislation and modelling. These contribute to a whole network of measures which are mobilized for the primary purpose of stabilizing a smaller set of properties that can be clearly identified and then ‘sold’ in a market. From this perspective, the tick-list of marketable features is the ultimate technology both of calculation and of market creation.

This explanation for how standards operate perversely to produce less energy-efficient buildings in the UK speculative office market can then be thought of as comprising three types of work:

  • Achieving (regulatory) compliance with building regulations, linked to legal legitimacy for the building.

  • Achieving normative and cultural–cognitive legitimacy in the market (Scott, Citation2008) by providing a ‘quality’ building: defined through aesthetic, symbolic and taken-for-granted features in a ‘social production of desirable space’ (Schiellerup & Gwilliam, Citation2009).

  • Distribution and integration of different sites and exercises of calculative agency. Different technologies of evaluation and assessment (such as collecting BREEAM ‘points’) and manipulations of these features (e.g. altering software models of buildings to achieve a better EPC rating) are strategically used to construct a relatively stable set of ‘facts’ about the building. These, once established, close off debate or discussion about its comparative virtues, and do so in ways that confer market value.

The most important of these moments of calculative agency is that of establishing rental value or return on investment (ROI), and such valuations may be distributed in time throughout design and even construction in order to achieve the necessary calculations to justify continuing investment. A number of the case buildings were stalled for nearly a decade until the calculative agency to make the ROI figures stack up was re-obtained.

In summary, in this sample almost all aspects of speculative office design were strongly standardized through conformity to these sets of regulations, guidelines and norms, which can be called ‘market standards’ (Faulconbridge et al., Citation2017). These have cumulative consequences in that they interlock and are backed by three forms of institutional legitimacy (Scott, Citation2008), with regulative standards demanding legal ‘de minima’, frequently backing up normative expectations of, for example, the environmental performance implied but not guaranteed by EPCs and BREEAM, and the cognitive–cultural demands of ‘quality’ represented by particular aesthetics, but more concretely BCO compliance and exceedance.

Discussion and conclusions

The findings of this study are not intended to displace more quantitative research into the effects of ‘green certifications’ on building design. Internationally it is suggested that the ‘market leaders’ have been adopted and adapted for their ‘brand’ value (Cole & Valdebenito, Citation2013) and interpretive flexibility (Goulden et al., Citation2015) and to aid market transformation (Todd, Pyke, & Tufts, Citation2013). However, the efficacy of certification in producing energy-efficient buildings has been questioned (Newsham et al., Citation2009; Scofield, Citation2009, Citation2013). Taken together this body of work already suggests that ‘market standards’ such as these fail to deliver meaningful energy efficiency due to tensions with their other more market-facing roles, offering some qualified support for the findings presented here. The analysis above has spelt out how and why this occurs, in more qualitative detail.

The pursuit of stable ROI from reliable rental streams requires long-term attractiveness, flexibility and competitiveness, all of which are somewhat guaranteed through over-specification and energy-demanding building services provision. Investment decisions and rental deals both constitute and reflect ‘the market’ created through the qualculative processes described above. Tracing the ‘impact’ of various green certifications, assessments and regulations as ‘price signals’ in a classical market is an established area of literature (Chegut et al., Citation2013; Fuerst & McAllister, Citation2011; Fuerst & van de Wetering, Citation2015; Fuerst et al., Citation2013, Citation2017), which fails to capture fully the recursive effects of their use, along with less formal ‘standards’, in the creation of a market itself through calculations and deals (MacKenzie et al., Citation2007). Seeing decisions to invest in energy-efficient buildings as being solely incentivized by their market value premium (De Jong & Parkinson, Citation2013) ignores:

the powerful social processes shaping energy-related decisions which tend to lead development actors to make seemingly ‘irrational’ choices, building and buying energy-intensive offices beyond the ‘needs’ of actual occupiers. (Guy & Henneberry, Citation2000, p. 2409)

These are unintended outcomes. BCO guidance was introduced in part to put a ceiling on high specification with its environmental implications (Guy, Citation1998). EPCs were intended to incentivize highly energy-efficient buildings, but are undone by the ‘performance gap’. BREEAM’s central market position as an indicator of sustainability does not mean that certification necessarily guarantees energy performance (De Wilde, Citation2014), something predicted by the ‘Energy’ credits being based on EPC ratings (Roderick et al., Citation2009), and confirmed in like-for-like post-occupancy comparison (Haroglu, Citation2012; Sawyer, de Wilde, & Turpin-Brooks, Citation2008).

Taken together, these factors suggest that standards are not currently functioning as intended either as technical best practice or as price signals to promote energy-efficient designs and systems and therefore lower-energy offices (De Jong & Parkinson, Citation2013; Deloitte Real Estate, Citation2014). They might, however: if calculative processes such as modelling, compliance demonstration and performance assessment were based on real buildings and performance data, rather than prospective models; if cultural understandings of what a ‘high quality/value’ office looks and feels like changes; or if government or key market institutions converted more realistic performance ratings into a mandatory benchmark. The latter is a potential direction for UK legislation as seen by the use of mandatory minimum EPC ratings to drive improvements (Hamilton, Huebner, & Griffiths, Citation2016), but these are still only improvements to modelled performance.

The first possibility is acknowledged in other countries, e.g. in the National Australian Built Environment Rating System (NABERS) assessment scheme (Newell, MacFarlane, & Walker, Citation2014). Calls for UK green certification to be based on actual energy performance rather than models (Cohen & Bordass, Citation2015) are currently being explored through proposals for a change to ‘design for performance’ rather than for compliance through ‘commitment agreements’ where buildings’ assessments are conditional on achieving promised performance in occupation (Cohen, Citation2016). An anticipation of real performance testing is included in BREEAM 2014’s ‘Excellent’ rating’s minimum requirement for ‘seasonal commissioning’, where the building services are tested under peak and normal demand conditions and recommissioned.

The second issue is illustrated by the acknowledgement (by interviewees and stakeholders in a dissemination activity) of the market potential of Derwent London’s ‘White Collar Factory’ concept as a new model of a high quality yet (potentially) lower-energy office. The concept combines reuse or emulation of industrial spaces with a ‘cool aesthetic’ of exposed concrete and building services. These allow the exploitation of lower-energy features such as thermal massing, displacement/passive ventilation (Yu, Heiselberg, Lei, Pomianowski, & Zhang, Citation2015) and natural lighting allowed by higher ceilings (Gago, Muneer, Knez, & Köster, Citation2015). More than a technical innovation alone, this appears to be an example of tackling the more normative/cultural market standards that have reductively defined ‘Grade A’ value and perpetuated over-specification and high energy demand.

Thus, this paper has argued that the concepts of qualculation and calculative agency help make sense of why standards linked to energy performance do not deliver lower energy speculative offices in London. But it also raises potentials for such an analysis to be used to devise research and policy that exploits calculative agency to transform the market for lower energy buildings. Such transformations must attend to cultural and professional norms as much as technical advice or understandings that appear taken for granted in the market. Further research such as an ethnographic study of design, certification and assessment processes in operation might reveal the micro-sociological detail of qualculation taking place, impossible in a post-hoc study covering 10 case buildings.

What the above demonstrates is that the speculative development of lower-energy commercial offices in the UK is hindered by a number of factors that arise not simply from market failure, the lack of technical solutions or knowledge about them or from socio-economic ‘barriers’ to their uptake. Rather, we should understand that in this studied sector the production of unsustainable office spaces through design is structured by the perverse effects of a series of market standards. These standards appear to promise energy efficiency and sustainability, but instead deliver a form of marketability that relies on over-specification. Rather than functioning as pricing signals to make smooth the operation of an incentivized market for ‘green buildings’, the various standards at play have been utilized (sometimes) strategically by a constellation of actors to produce a ‘modelled, flexible, marketable building’ rather than the low-energy office that one might hope that they would deliver. These perverse effects have been arrived at through the processes of fluid qualculation enacted via black-boxed forms of assessment and modelling processes and through qualculative processes of valuation organized by checklists of foregrounded features.

Of course, the highly competitive nature of global cities’ prime property markets might be expected to privilege exchange value over environmental performance. Nevertheless the analysis presented has shown how processes of qualculation and the exploitation of calculative agency operate in the UK speculative market at least to reconcile the underlying pursuit of profit with an apparent satisfaction of international energy performance (EPC), sustainability (BREEAM) and quality (BCO) regulation and standards. Of course an analysis of a specific market enactment through qualculation and calculative agencies does not suggest that this is a necessary outcome, or that it applies to all markets, e.g. internationally. It merely states that it is through such processes that goods are created, valued and traded. These outcomes can be understood through opening the black boxes of individual standards, guidelines and assessment methods, and through understanding the specific nature of the market being analysed. In the case of London, this is a speculative investment and development market focused on high quality and value products in which certain design priorities (flexibility and quality) trump others (e.g. adaptability, energy efficiency). Nevertheless, such an analysis identifies where calculative agency lies, and how it is exercised, which is the first step to rethinking how it might operate in this and other contexts.

Acknowledgements

The author thanks the many research participants who kindly contributed their time and data; his colleagues James Faulconbridge and John Connaughton for their work on the research; and Elizabeth Shove for commenting on earlier drafts. The reviews and suggestions of the editor and three anonymous referees were also invaluable in shaping and sharpening the final version of the paper.

Disclosure statement

No potential conflict of interest was reported by the author.

Additional information

Funding

This work was supported by the Engineering and Physical Sciences Research Council (EPSRC) [grant number EP/K011723/1] and Électricité de France.

References

  • Albrecht, D., & Broikos, C. (2000). On the job: Design and the American office. New York: Princeton Architectural Press.
  • Arup. (2013). The performance gap: Causes & solutions. Arup. Retrieved from http://www.greenconstructionboard.org/images/stories/pdfs/performance-gap/2013-03-0420Closing20the20Gap_Final20Report_ISSUE.pdf
  • Axon, C. J., Bright, S. J., Dixon, T. J., Janda, K. B., & Kolokotroni, M. (2012). Building communities: Reducing energy use in tenanted commercial property. Building Research & Information, 40(4), 461–472. doi: 10.1080/09613218.2012.680701
  • Bazeley, P., & Jackson, K. (2013). Qualitative data analysis with NVivo. London, UK: Sage.
  • Better Buildings Partnership. (2012). A tale of two buildings: Are EPCs a true indicator of energy efficiency?. Retrieved from http://www.betterbuildingspartnership.co.uk/download/bbp-jll---a-tale-of-two-buildings-2012.pdf
  • Biggart, N. W., & Lutzenhiser, L. (2007). Economic sociology and the social problem of energy inefficiency. American Behavioral Scientist, 50(8), 1070–1087.
  • Bordass, B. (2000). Cost and value: Fact and fiction. Building Research & Information, 28(5–6), 338–352.
  • British Council for Offices. (2009). Small power use in offices. London. Retrieved from http://www.bco.org.uk/Research/Publications/Smallpowe2586.aspx
  • British Council for Offices. (2013). Occupier density study 2013. London. Retrieved from https://www.architectsjournal.co.uk/Journals/2013/09/10/c/y/n/BCO-Occupier-Density-Study---Final-report-2013.pdf
  • British Council for Offices. (2014). Desk power load monitoring. London: BCO.
  • Brown, N., Malmqvist, T., & Wintzell, H. (2016). Owner organizations’ value-creation strategies through environmental certification of buildings. Building Research and Information, 44(8), 863–874. doi: 10.1080/09613218.2016.1099031
  • Callon, M. (2007). Performative economics. In D. A. MacKenzie, F. Muniesa, & L. Siu (Eds.), Do economists make markets? On the performativity of economics. (pp. 311–357). Woodstock: Princeton University Press.
  • Callon, M., & Law, J. (2005). On qualculation, agency, and otherness. Environment and Planning D: Society and Space, 23(5), 717–733. doi: 10.1068/d343t
  • Callon, M., & Muniesa, F. (2005). Peripheral vision: Economic markets as calculative collective devices. Organization Studies, 26(8), 1229–1250.
  • Cao, G., Awbi, H., Yao, R., Fan, Y., Sirén, K., Kosonen, R., & Zhang, J. (2014). A review of the performance of different ventilation and airflow distribution systems in buildings. Building and Environment, 73, 171–186. doi: 10.1016/j.buildenv.2013.12.009
  • Carruthers, B. G., & Stinchcombe, A. L. (1999). The social structure of liquidity: Flexibility, markets, and states. Theory and Society, 28(3), 353–382. doi: 10.1023/a:1006903103304
  • Chegut, A., Eichholtz, P., & Kok, N. (2013). Supply, demand and the value of green buildings. Urban Studies, 0042098013484526
  • Chung, W., & Hui, Y. V. (2009). A study of energy efficiency of private office buildings in Hong Kong. Energy and Buildings, 41(6), 696–701. doi: 10.1016/j.enbuild.2009.02.001
  • Clark, D. (2013). What colour is your building: Measuring and reducing the energy and carbon footprint of buildings. London: R. Publ.
  • Cochoy, F. (2002). Une sociologie du packaging ou l’âne de Buridan face au marché. Paris: Presses Universitaires de France.
  • Cohen, R. (2016). Design for Performance: A scheme to guarantee new build energy performance. Edinburgh: CIBSE Technical Symposium.
  • Cohen, R., & Bordass, B. (2015). Mandating transparency about building energy performance in use. Building Research & Information, 43(4), 534–552. doi: 10.1080/09613218.2015.1017416
  • Cole, R. J. (2005). Building environmental assessment methods: Redefining intentions and roles. Building Research & Information, 33(5), 455–467. doi: 10.1080/09613210500219063
  • Cole, R. J., & Valdebenito, M. J. (2013). The importation of building environmental certification systems: International usages of BREEAM and LEED. Building Research & Information, 41(6), 662–676. doi: 10.1080/09613218.2013.802115
  • Committee on Climate Change. (2016). Meeting carbon budgets – 2016 progress report to Parliament. London. Retrieved from https://www.theccc.org.uk/publications/
  • Creswell, J. W. (2013). Research design: Qualitative, quantitative, and mixed methods approaches. London, UK: Sage.
  • Deloitte Real Estate. (2014). London office crane survey: Building momentum. London. Retrieved from https://www2.deloitte.com/content/dam/Deloitte/uk/Documents/real-estate/deloitte-uk-london-office-crane-survey-winter-2014.pdf
  • De Jong, R., & Parkinson, A. (2013). Green premium or grey discount? The value of green workplaces for commercial building occupiers in the UK. U. L. Institute. Retrieved from http://europe.uli.org/wp-content/uploads/sites/3/ULI-Documents/Green-Premium-Grey-Discount-Report-2013.pdf
  • De Wilde, P. (2014). The gap between predicted and measured energy performance of buildings: A framework for investigation. Automation in Construction, 41, 40–49. doi: 10.1016/j.autcon.2014.02.009
  • Ding, G. K. C. (2008). Sustainable construction—The role of environmental assessment tools. Journal of Environmental Management, 86(3), 451–464. doi: 10.1016/j.jenvman.2006.12.025
  • Duffy, F., & Powell, K. (1997). The new office. London: Conran Octopus.
  • Economidou, M. (2012, March). Energy performance requirements for buildings in Europe. REHVA Journal Retrieved from: http://www.rehva.eu/fileadmin/hvac-dictio/03-2012/energy-performance-requirements-for-buildings-in-europe.pdf.
  • Elliott, B., Bull, R., & Mallaburn, P. (2015). A new lease of life? Investigating UK property investor attitudes to low carbon investment decisions in commercial buildings. Energy Efficiency, 8(4), 667–680. doi: 10.1007/s12053-014-9314-2
  • Energy Efficiency Office. (2000). Energy consumption guide 19: Energy use in offices. London. Energy Efficiency Office Best Practice Programme. Retrieved from http://www.cibse.org/getmedia/7fb5616f-1ed7-4854-bf72-2dae1d8bde62/ECG19-Energy-Use-in-Offices-(formerly-ECON19).pdf.aspx
  • Faulconbridge, J., Cass, N., & Connaughton, J. (2017). How market standards affect building design: The case of low energy design in commercial offices. Unpublished, available from the authors.
  • Faulconbridge, J., & Grubbauer, M. (2015). Transnational building practices: Knowledge mobility and the inescapable market. Global Networks, 15(3), 275–287. doi: 10.1111/glob.12078
  • Fedoruk, L. E., Cole, R. J., Robinson, J. B., & Cayuela, A. (2015). Learning from failure: Understanding the anticipated–achieved building energy performance gap. Building Research & Information, 8–15. doi: 10.1080/09613218.2015.1036227
  • Feige, A., Wallbaum, H., Janser, M., & Windlinger, L. (2013). Impact of sustainable office buildings on occupant’s comfort and productivity. Journal of Corporate Real Estate, 15(1), 7–34. doi: 10.1108/jcre-01-2013-0004
  • Fuerst, F., Gabrieli, T., & McAllister, P. (2017). A green winner’s curse? Investor behavior in the market for eco-certified office buildings. Economic Modelling, 61, 137–146. doi: 10.1016/j.econmod.2016.11.007
  • Fuerst, F., & McAllister, P. (2008). Green noise or green value? Measuring the price effects of environmental certification in commercial buildings.
  • Fuerst, F., & McAllister, P. (2011). Eco-labeling in commercial office markets: Do LEED and Energy Star offices obtain multiple premiums? Ecological Economics, 70(6), 1220–1230. doi: 10.1016/j.ecolecon.2011.01.026
  • Fuerst, F., & McAllister, P. (2011a). Green noise or green value? Measuring the effects of environmental certification on office values. Real Estate Economics, 39(1), 45–69.
  • Fuerst, F., & McAllister, P. (2011b). The impact of energy performance certificates on the rental and capital values of commercial property assets. Energy Policy, 39(10), 6608–6614.
  • Fuerst, F., & van de Wetering, J. (2015). How does environmental efficiency impact on the rents of commercial offices in the UK? Journal of Property Research, 32(3), 193–216.
  • Fuerst, F., van de Wetering, J., & Wyatt, P. (2013). Is intrinsic energy efficiency reflected in the pricing of office leases? Building Research & Information, 41(4), 373–383. doi: 10.1080/09613218.2013.780229
  • Gago, E. J., Muneer, T., Knez, M., & Köster, H. (2015). Natural light controls and guides in buildings. Energy saving for electrical lighting, reduction of cooling load. Renewable and Sustainable Energy Reviews, 41, 1–13. doi: 10.1016/j.rser.2014.08.002
  • Gardiner & Theobald. (2014). BCO specification for offices quick guide to key criteria 2009–2014 comparison. Retrieved from: http://www.gardiner.com/publication-uploads/BCO-Specification-For-Offices.pdf
  • Gertz, R. (2005). Eco-labelling – a case for deregulation? Law, Probability and Risk, 4(3), 127–141.
  • Goulden, S., Erell, E., Garb, Y., & Pearlmutter, D. (2015). Green building standards as socio-technical actors in municipal environmental policy. Building Research & Information, 1–13. doi: 10.1080/09613218.2015.1116844
  • Green Construction Board. (2013). Low carbon routemap for the UK built environment. www.greenconstructionboard.org.
  • Guertler, P., Pett, J., & Kaplan, Z. (2005). Valuing low energy offices: The essential step for the success of the Energy Performance of Buildings Directive Proceedings of the 2005 ECEEE Summer Study on Energy Efficiency, 295–305.
  • Guest, G., Bunce, A., & Johnson, L. (2006). How many interviews are enough?: An experiment with data saturation and variability. Field methods, 18(1), 59–82.
  • Guy, S. (1998). Developing alternatives: Energy, offices and the environment. International journal of urban and regional research, 22(2), 264–282.
  • Guy, S. (2002). Developing interests: Environmental innovation and the social organisation of the property business. In S. Guy, & J. Henneberry (Eds.), Development & developers: Perspectives on property (pp. 247–266). Oxford: Blackwell.
  • Guy, S., & Henneberry, J. (2000). Understanding urban development processes: Integrating the economic and the social in property research. Urban Studies, 37(13), 2399–2416. doi: 10.1080/00420980020005398
  • Hamilton, I., Huebner, G., & Griffiths, R. (2016). Valuing energy performance in home purchasing: An analysis of mortgage lending for sustainable buildings. Procedia Engineering, 145, 319–326. doi: 10.1016/j.proeng.2016.04.080
  • Haroglu, H. (2012). The impact of BREEAM on the design of buildings. Proceedings of the Institution of Civil Engineers – Engineering Sustainability, 166(1), 11–19.
  • Hendershott, P. H., Lizieri, C. M., & Matysiak, G. A. (1999). The workings of the London office market. Real Estate Economics, 27(2), 365–387.
  • Hong, T., & Lin, H.-W. (2014). Occupant behavior: Impact on energy use of private offices. Retrieved from http://www.escholarship.org/uc/item/6jp5w8kn.
  • HM Government. (2008). Climate Change Act 2008. London: UK: HMSO.
  • HM Government. (2013). Conservation of fuel and power – Approved document L2A, L2A conservation of fuel and power in new buildings other than dwellings. London: HM Government.
  • Hsu, D. (2014). Improving energy benchmarking with self-reported data. Building Research & Information, 42(5), 641–656. doi: 10.1080/09613218.2014.887612
  • Hughes, T. P. (1987). The evolution of large technological systems. In W. E. Bijker, T. P. Hughes, & T. Pinch (Eds.), The social construction of technological systems: New directions in the sociology and history of technology (pp. 51–82). Boston, MA: MIT Press.
  • Hughes, T. P. (1993). Networks of power: Electrification in Western society, 1880–1930. Baltimore, MD: JHU Press.
  • Kelly, S., Crawford-Brown, D., & Pollitt, M. G. (2012). Building performance evaluation and certification in the UK: Is SAP fit for purpose? Renewable and Sustainable Energy Reviews, 16(9), 6861–6878. doi: 10.1016/j.rser.2012.07.018
  • Kelly, S., Shipworth, M., Shipworth, D., Gentry, M., Wright, A., Pollitt, M., … Lomas, K. (2013). Predicting the diversity of internal temperatures from the English residential sector using panel methods. Applied Energy, 102, 601–621. doi: 10.1016/j.apenergy.2012.08.015
  • Kontokosta, C. E. (2013). Is there a link between energy performance and investment performance? Evidence from New York city benchmarking data. New York. Retrieved from http://citeseerx.ist.psu.edu/viewdoc/download? doi: 10.1.1.391.5146&rep=rep1&type=pdf
  • Latour, B., & Woolgar, S. (1979). Laboratory life: The social construction of scientific facts. Beverley Hills, CA: Sage.
  • Lewry, A. (2015). Bridging the performance gap: Understanding predicted and actual building operational energy. Journal of Building Survey, Appraisal and Valuation, 3(4), 360–365.
  • Lippert, I. (2015). Environment as datascape: Enacting emission realities in corporate carbon accounting. Geoforum, 66, 126–135. doi: 10.1016/j.geoforum.2014.09.009
  • Lizieri, C., Baum, A., & Scott, P. (2000). Ownership, occupation and risk: A view of the city of London office market. Urban Studies, 37(7), 1109–1129. doi: 10.1080/00420980020080041
  • Lynch, M. (1993). Scientific practice and ordinary action: Ethnomethodology and social studies of science. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
  • MacKenzie, D. A., Muniesa, F., & Siu, L. (2007). Do economists make markets?: On the performativity of economics. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.
  • MacLaran, A. (2014). Making space: Property development and urban planning. Abingdon, UK: Routledge.
  • Markard, J., Raven, R., & Truffer, B. (2012). Sustainability transitions: An emerging field of research and its prospects. Research Policy, 41(6), 955–967. doi: 10.1016/j.respol.2012.02.013
  • Menezes, A. C., Cripps, A., Bouchlaghem, D., & Buswell, R. (2012). Predicted vs. actual energy performance of non-domestic buildings: Using post-occupancy evaluation data to reduce the performance gap. Applied Energy, 97, 355–364.
  • Menezes, A., Cripps, A., Buswell, R. A., Wright, J., & Bouchlaghem, D. (2014). Estimating the energy consumption and power demand of small power equipment in office buildings. Energy and Buildings, 75, 199–209.
  • Moezzi, M., & Janda, K. B. (2014). From ‘if only’ to ‘social potential’ in schemes to reduce building energy use. Energy Research and Social Science, 1, 30–40. doi: 10.1016/j.erss.2014.03.014
  • Mulville, M., Jones, K., Huebner, G., & Powell-Greig, J. (2016). Energy-saving occupant behaviours in offices: change strategies. Building Research & Information, 43, 1–14. doi: 10.1080/09613218.2016.1212299
  • Newell, G., MacFarlane, J., & Walker, R. (2014). Assessing energy rating premiums in the performance of green office buildings in Australia. Journal of Property Investment and Finance, 32(4), 352–370. doi: 10.1108/JPIF-10-2013-0061
  • Newsham, G. R., Mancini, S., & Birt, B. J. (2009). Do LEED-certified buildings save energy? Yes, but … . Energy and Buildings, 41(8), 897–905.
  • Nicholls, C. (2014). Energy use in non-domestic buildings: The UK government’s new evidence base. Building Research & Information, 42(1), 109–117. doi: 10.1080/09613218.2014.832484
  • Oreszczyn, T., & Lowe, R. (2009). Challenges for energy and buildings research: Objectives, methods and funding mechanisms. Building Research & Information, 38(1), 107–122. doi: 10.1080/09613210903265432
  • Oyedokun, T., Jones, C., & Dunse, N. (2015). The growth of the green office market in the UK. Journal of European Real Estate Research, 8(3), 267–284. doi: 10.1108/jerer-05-2015-0025
  • Pellegrini-Masini, G., & Leishman, C. (2011). The role of corporate reputation and employees’ values in the uptake of energy efficiency in office buildings. Energy Policy, 39(9), 5409–5419. doi: 10.1016/j.enpol.2011.05.023
  • Pinder, J., Schmidt, R., & Saker, J. (2013). Stakeholder perspectives on developing more adaptable buildings. Construction Management and Economics, 31(5), 440–459.
  • Ponelis, S. R. (2015). Using interpretive qualitative case studies for exploratory research in doctoral studies: A case of information systems research in small and medium enterprises. International Journal of Doctoral Studies, 10, 535–550.
  • Raslan, R., & Davies, M. (2010). Results variability in accredited building energy performance compliance demonstration software in the UK: an inter-model comparative study. Journal of Building Performance Simulation, 3(1), 63–85. doi: 10.1080/19401490903477386
  • RIBA. (2009). Climate change toolkit 03 principles of low carbon design and refurbishment. Retrieved from https://www.architecture.com/Files/RIBAHoldings/PolicyAndInternationalRelations/Policy/Environment/2Principles_LC_Design_Refurb.pdf
  • Roderick, Y., McEwan, D., Wheatley, C., & Alonso, C. (2009). Comparison of energy performance assessment between LEED, BREEAM and Green Star Eleventh International IBPSA Conference (pp. 1167–1176): Citeseer.
  • Roulston, K., & Shelton, S. A. (2015). Reconceptualizing bias in teaching qualitative research methods. Qualitative Inquiry, 21(4), 332–342.
  • Sawyer, L., de Wilde, P., & Turpin-Brooks, S. (2008). Energy performance and occupancy satisfaction: A comparison of two closely related buildings. Facilities, 26(13/14), 542–551. doi: 10.1108/02632770810914299
  • Schiellerup, P., & Gwilliam, J. (2009). Social production of desirable space: An exploration of the practice and role of property agents in the UK commercial property market. Environment and Planning C: Government and Policy, 27(5), 801–814.
  • Schindler, S. (2010). Following industry's LEED®: Municipal adoption of private green building standards. Florida Law Review, 61(2), 285–350.
  • Schweber, L. (2013). The effect of BREEAM on clients and construction professionals. Building Research & Information, 41(2), 129–145. doi: 10.1080/09613218.2013.768495
  • Scofield, J. H. (2009). Do LEED-certified buildings save energy? Not really … . Energy and Buildings, 41(12), 1386–1390.
  • Scofield, J. H. (2013). Efficacy of LEED-certification in reducing energy consumption and greenhouse gas emission for large New York City office buildings. Energy and Buildings, 67, 517–524. doi: 10.1016/j.enbuild.2013.08.032
  • Scott, R. W. (2008). Institutions and organizations: Ideas and Interests. London: Sage.
  • Seppänen, O., Fisk, W. J., & Lei, Q. (2006). Ventilation and performance in office work. Indoor air, 16(1), 28–36.
  • Skea, J. (2012). Research and evidence needs for decarbonisation in the built environment: A UK case study. Building Research & Information, 40(4), 432–445. doi: 10.1080/09613218.2012.670395
  • Star, S. L. (1999). The ethnography of infrastructure. American Behavioral Scientist, 43(3), 377–391. doi: 10.1177/00027649921955326
  • Surmann, M., Brunauer, W., & Bienert, S. (2015). How does energy efficiency influence the market value of office buildings in Germany and does this effect increase over time? Journal of European Real Estate Research, 8(3), 243–266. doi: 10.1108/jerer-04-2015-0018
  • Tetlow, R. M., van Dronkelaar, C., Beaman, C. P., Elmualim, A. A., & Couling, K. (2015). Identifying behavioural predictors of small power electricity consumption in office buildings. Building and Environment, 92, 75–85.
  • Timmermans, S., & Epstein, S. (2010). A world of standards but not a standard world: Toward a sociology of standards and standardization. Annual Review of Sociology, 36(1), 69–89. doi: 10.1146/annurev.soc.012809.102629
  • Todd, J. A., Pyke, C., & Tufts, R. (2013). Implications of trends in LEED usage: Rating system design and market transformation. Building Research & Information, 41(4), 384–400. doi: 10.1080/09613218.2013.775565
  • Van der Heijden, J. (2016). The new governance for low-carbon buildings: Mapping, exploring, interrogating. Building Research & Information, 44(5–6), 575–584.
  • Van de Wetering, J., & Wyatt, P. (2011). Office sustainability: Occupier perceptions and implementation of policy. Journal of European Real Estate Research, 4(1), 29–47. doi:10.1108/17539261111129452.
  • Van Dronkelaar, C., Dowson, M., Spataru, C., & Mumovic, D. (2016). A review of the regulatory energy performance gap and its underlying causes in non-domestic buildings. Frontiers in Mechanical Engineering, 1. doi: 10.3389/fmech.2015.00017
  • Wade, J., Pett, J., & Ramsay, L. (2003). Energy efficiency in offices: Motivating action. London: Association for the Conservation of Energy.
  • Wade, J., Pett, J., Ramsay, L., & House, W. (2003). Energy efficiency in offices: Assessing the situation. London: Association for the Conservation of Energy.
  • Westminster Sustainable Business Forum, & Carbon Connect. (2013). Building efficiency: Reducing energy demand in the commercial sector. Retrieved from http://www.policyconnect.org.uk/wsbf/sites/site_wsbf/files/report/403/fieldreportdownload/wsbfreport-buildingefficiencypdf.pdf
  • Wiley, J. A., Benefield, J. D., & Johnson, K. H. (2010). Green design and the market for commercial office space. The Journal of Real Estate Finance and Economics, 41(2), 228–243.
  • Yu, T., Heiselberg, P., Lei, B., Pomianowski, M., & Zhang, C. (2015). A novel system solution for cooling and ventilation in office buildings: A review of applied technologies and a case study. Energy and Buildings, 90, 142–155. doi: 10.1016/j.enbuild.2014.12.057

Appendix: A note on coding and analysis

The coding process that preceded the analysis was as follows. First, parent codes in the coding framework of influences on office building design were developed by the research team combining design guidance from the building industry (Clark, Citation2013; Energy Efficiency Office, Citation2000; Gardiner & Theobald, Citation2014) with a socio-technical focus on infrastructure (Hughes, Citation1987; Star, Citation1999). The codes were designed to allow an ‘Ethnography of Infrastructure’ (Star, Citation1999), interrogating why the features focused on came to be as they are. This treated the features in question as ‘cultural artefacts’ (Hughes, Citation1993) and sought to understand both their tangible effects on energy demand and their histories and relationships to rules, norms, cultures (i.e. institutions), knowledge, organizations, and economic and political interests. During coding of the first tranche of six interviews with nine key stakeholders, further sub-codes were developed inductively. In the main tranche of case study interviews, the ‘Inductive’ parent code was then used to hold sub-codes identified as important themes during coding, which were shared with the other coders, and used to refine coding of subsequent transcripts and to recode existing ones (by the research associate). The final coding structure contains too many sub-codes to list, but as an example, ‘User needs’ contained the following sub-codes: Comfort, Cooling, Evidence (of explicit user needs), Light, Noise, Occupier preferences, Productivity, Symbolic office spaces, and Well-being. Analysis for this and other pieces of writing began by extracting segments from the dataset based on relevant parent/sub-codes, and after reading through these large data samples, extracting smaller samples of segments based their being multiply coded for relevant themes.