8,643
Views
3
CrossRef citations to date
0
Altmetric
Introduction

Economic Inequality and Political Stability in Russia and ChinaFootnote

, &
This article is part of the following collections:
The Life and Works of Stephen Leonard White (1945–2023)

At the third BRICS summit on Hainan Island in 2011, Russian president Dmitri Medvedev claimed that the BRICS countries—with the addition of South Africa to Brazil, Russia, India and China—now included the ‘biggest states of three continents’.Footnote1 But it was much less clear that these five countries represented a sustainable model of political development over the medium or longer term. All of the countries have displayed increasing economic inequality over the past half century, while only one—India—could be classed as a mature, stable democracy. The essays in this special section focus on the two largest, most populous and least democratic of the BRICS, Russia and China, to examine the impact of economic inequality on their political trajectories.Footnote2

The statistics detailing the socioeconomic growth of Russia and China are impressive. Taken together, the two countries account for 41% of the total territory of the original four BRICs countries, and for 51% of their total population and 63% of their GDP. On Goldman Sachs projections, by 2050 China is likely to be the world’s largest economy, and Russia is to be its sixth largest.Footnote3 Despite their impressive record of economic growth, a striking feature of both countries is the non-egalitarian nature of their development—notwithstanding the (post)communist legacy. On most conventional measures, these two countries are now among the most unequal in the world. According to calculations derived from Russian official statistics, the Gini coefficient rose from 0.28 in 1990 (Alexeev & Gaddy Citation1993, p. 29) to 0.42 in 2010;Footnote4 the best estimates of Chinese Gini coefficients indicate a very similar rise, from 0.26 in 1983—just after the introduction of the contract responsibility system—to 0.49 in 2012 (Chen et al. Citation2010, p. 20; Wildau & Mitchell Citation2016).

The widening of income inequalities has been an international phenomenon; but according to the United Nations Citation2010 Human Development Report, it has been ‘especially marked in the countries that were part of the former Soviet Union’ (United Nations Citation2010, p. 72). On their figures, Gini coefficients were already higher in Russia than in the UK, and higher in China than in the United States. One consequence was that both countries were increasingly well represented on Forbes’ list of the world’s billionaires: in the 2011 list China doubled its representation to 115 (which took it to second place) and Russia was in third place with 101; there were more billionaires in Moscow at this time than in any other city in the world.Footnote5

What effect does such endemic economic inequality have on political stability? Aristotle pointed out in his Politics that ‘when men are equal they are contented’ (Everson Citation1996, p. 132). He drew particular attention to the people of Tarentum, who, ‘by sharing the use of their own property with the poor, [gained] their good will’ (Everson Citation1996, p. 160). Accordingly, ‘democracy appears to be safer and less liable to revolution than oligarchy’ (Everson Citation1996, p. 121). Concerns of this kind have been taken up by many later writers, including John Stuart Mill, who provided in his Representative Government for additional votes for those who exercised ‘superior [managerial] functions’ on the belief that the poor would otherwise use their electoral preponderance to enact ‘class legislation’ (Mills Citation1964, pp. 282, 285, 283).

The relationship between economic inequality and political instability in Russia and China is the topic of this special section. The five essays address different aspects of the relationship, and take different methodological approaches, but ultimately address a single core question: to what extent does inequality pose a challenge to the existing political systems?

Political instability in Russia and China

The evidence suggests that economic inequality in Russia and China is both substantial and increasing. Official statistics are always subject to political manipulation—as was the case when Russia increased its official count of ‘the poor’ by more than 2 million in early 2011 to take account the evidence of the 2010 census.Footnote6 There is, however, a substantial literature that can help us identify some of the shortcomings in official data and supplement them with independent estimates.Footnote7 For example, the Higher School of Economics has developed a comprehensive ‘index of wellbeing’ which shows that living standards for 40% of the population are still below where they were at the end of the communist period, as if ‘two countries’ existed in parallel (Kukol Citation2011, p. 11).

In China, household income and expenditure surveys have generally confirmed that economic disparities have been increasing not only in monetary terms, but also across households and regions and between urban and rural areas (Cai et al. Citation2010; Chen et al. Citation2010; Liu Citation2010).Footnote8 Despite attempts to enhance welfare programmes, the main thrust of the recent reforms has been to reduce or even eliminate the ‘iron rice bowl’ approach to social protection. The social programmes that have replaced them leave much of the population with scant protection in the event of sickness, old age or disability (Duckett Citation2007, Citation2011; Li & Zhong Citation2009). In both countries there are additional flows of ‘hidden income’, often related to corruption; on Chinese evidence about 75% of this additional income accrues to those who already have higher incomes, widening inequalities still further.Footnote9

The process by which political power has been converted into economic advantage has been documented in a range of studies. In Russia, as Kryshtanovskaya and White (Citation2011) have shown, a form of ‘state capitalism’ has developed in which leading officials dominate the boards of the largest companies, and in particular what the authorities have defined as ‘strategic enterprises’ in fuel and energy, the military–industrial complex, and the infrastructure. The more important the company, the more likely it is to include ministers or even members of the presidential administration on its board. And these patterns have persisted, despite the enforced withdrawal of state officials from a number of high-profile company boards in 2011: first deputy premier Zubkov remained at Gazprom, deputy premier Sechin at Rosneftegaz, energy minister Shmatko at RusHydro and Zarubezhneft, and transport minister Levitin on the board of Sheremetevo airport.Footnote10

For China, too, it is widely accepted that political power has enabled Communist Party (CCP) cadres and government officials to benefit disproportionately from economic growth (Goodman Citation2008). While government officials did not benefit from ‘nomenklatura privatisation’ in the same way as their Russian counterparts, they or their children had opportunities to acquire shares in state businesses (a notable phenomenon has been the children of officials engaging in business and in so doing benefitting from their parents’ political capital). For this and other reasons, current scholarship inclines towards the view that economic growth and marketisation are unlikely to lead to the emergence of new elites that might challenge the regime (Dickson Citation2003, Citation2008). This conclusion is based on an examination of the CCP’s organisation and structure, its corporatist strategy of developing business associations, the logic of co-option, the CCP’s strategy of adaptation in the light of lessons drawn from the Soviet collapseFootnote11 and surveys of entrepreneurs themselves.Footnote12

The sustainability of authoritarian politics of a Russian or Chinese kind has been placed in doubt by sustained, high level economic growth. A rich and still-influential social science literature associated particularly with Lipset (Citation1959) has suggested that rising levels of GDP will of themselves undermine authoritarian politics: societies will become more complex, professionals will increasingly combine to advance their own interests, and ‘cross-cutting cleavages’ will predispose political actors towards bargaining and accommodation rather than zero-sum confrontation. For some, such as Pye (Citation1990), the changes that had taken place in Eastern Europe were indeed a demonstration of the explanatory power of modernisation theories of this kind; but in the Russian case, its political system was actually more authoritarian in 2011 than it had been at the end of the Soviet period. Will post-communist authoritarianism in Russia be undermined by a still-developing society?

In the case of China, scholars have documented a rising tide of popular protest which usually does not confront the regime directly, remaining concerned with local and particular interests. However, such protest often crossed the boundary from ‘official, prescribed politics’ to ‘politics by other means’ (O’Brien Citation2003, Citation2008; O’Brien & Li Citation2006; Wasserstrom Citation2009; Cai Citation2010). Elsewhere, Gilley (Citation2004) has spoken of China’s ‘democratic future’ and Walter and Howie (Citation2010) of the ‘fragile foundation of China’s extraordinary rise’. Advancing a contrary view, Whyte (Citation2010b) and Wright (Citation2010) emphasise tolerance and an acceptance of the status quo among the Chinese mass public. Studies intended for a wider audience have been equally divided: for Hutton (Citation2007) there could in the end be no alternative to democracy and the rule of law, while Jacques (Citation2009) places more emphasis on the adaptability of China’s distinctive culture. Meanwhile, in China itself, public expressions of discontent more than tripled in the five years to 2010, reaching 180,000 annually.Footnote13

Overview of the special section

The essays that follow examine these themes from several different perspectives. While the central question concerns the implications of economic inequality for political stability, several essays approach the question from the perspective of institutions, while other essays use a range of public opinion data. Linda Cook and Martin Dimitrov adopt the former approach, and use social contract theory to explain political stability in communist autocracies. They argue that this stability is a consequence of an implicit exchange between the regime and the populace: citizens remain quiescent so long as the regime provides them with secure jobs, social services, subsidised housing and consumer goods. Cook and Dimitrov ask how well the social contract thesis applies in three different types of regimes. First, they examine the socialist social contract in the light of newly available archival evidence on the Soviet Union; second, they examine the social contract in reform-era China; and, third, in Putin’s Russia. They conclude that post-socialist regimes create distinctive ‘market social contracts’. More specifically, communist and authoritarian leaders cater to the consumption needs of their populations in a strategic effort to remain in office.

In rapidly expanding economies, the population shift from the country to the city creates particular tensions. This topic is examined by Elena Danilova, who compares social inequality in Russia and China and how it is perceived by the urban population. The evidence comes from representative surveys of the adult population in two major cities, Shanghai and St Petersburg, using a strictly comparable methodology. The results from the surveys show that although people in Russia and China have broadly egalitarian attitudes, there are significant differences in the way in which they view the current system of distribution. Egalitarian attitudes are connected not only with the actual incomes but they are very powerfully affected by subjective assessments of the distributive system, which often involves political judgments. The essay concludes that while there is a tendency towards the convergence of political regimes in the two countries, there are different patterns of legitimacy based as much on culture as on economic achievements. In both countries, the ruling elites rely mainly on culture in order to strengthen their political monopoly.

Economic crises can place social contracts under strain, stimulating demands for social protection whilst undermining the ability of the state to deliver it. Neil Munro uses two waves of the World Values Survey spanning the 2008 global financial crisis to analyse the determinants of support for state social welfare provision in a four-stage recursive model. He hypothesises that support is a function of economic self-interest, tapped by subjective economic satisfaction and relative income; ideology including beliefs about market fairness and inequality aversion; as well as temporal context. Munro finds that subjective economic satisfaction reduces support for greater welfare provision, while an aversion to inequality increases support. He also finds that public support for social welfare provision increased over the period, no doubt reflecting popular feelings of economic insecurity.

Using the same database, Ian McAllister and Stephen White examine the impact of economic development on public support for democracy. The starting point for the analysis is the debate between those who believe that economic development is a pre-requisite for democracy, and those who reject this view believing instead that economic prosperity is important only for ensuring democracy’s survival in the event of an existential threat. By using successive World Values Surveys conducted in Russia and China from 1990 onwards, McAllister and White are able to trace patterns of economic change and public support for democracy in the two countries over an extended period. The results show that education and, to a lesser extent, social mobility and economic attitudes, play an important role in promoting pro-democracy attitudes in both countries. The findings suggest that an increasingly large, tertiary-educated middle class may act as a potential driver for democratisation in both countries.

Recent research on authoritarian regimes argues that they provide public goods in order to prevent rebellion. Jane Duckett and Guohui Wang take up this theme to examine how the Chinese state has accommodated the demands of a large rural population. They show that the ‘threat of rebellion’ cannot explain Chinese party-state policies to extend public goods to rural residents in the first decade of the twenty-first century. Drawing on theories of policy making, Duckett and Wang argue that China’s one-party regime has extended public goods to the rural population under the influence of ideas and policy options generated by policy communities of officials, researchers, international organisations and other actors. The party centre adopted and implemented these ideas and policy options when they provided solutions to external shocks and supported economic development goals. Political institutions have also played a role, notably by encouraging officials to develop and experiment with policies. Overall, Duckett and Wang suggest that explanations of policies and their outcomes in authoritarian political systems need to take into account how institutions shape policy making and the influence of policy communities and their ideas.

In summary, the research reported in this special section has not found evidence that authoritarian regimes in Russia and China are especially at risk of political instability as a consequence of the inequality which has arisen during market reforms. Rather, both regimes have shown an ability to adapt to rising inequality by developing new strategies of self-legitimation to replace Communist ideology, and by developing or adapting social programmes to meet the needs, however minimally, of key sections of the population. This does not mean that the Russian and Chinese people have abandoned their aversion to inequality or are happy with existing levels of social protection. However, the Russian and Chinese regimes have shown themselves to be skilled at managing the policy agenda, guiding public opinion and co-opting or repressing political opposition. In these circumstances, we do not think that economic inequality poses significant danger to either regime.

Notes

This work was supported by the Economic and Social Research Council (grant number ES/J012688/1).

1 Rossiiskaya gazeta, 15 April 2011, p. 2.

2 Both countries have already been the subject of a substantial comparative literature. See, for instance, Nolan (Citation1995), Ma (Citation2000), Jha (Citation2002), Marsh (Citation2005), Larsson (Citation2006), Chen (Citation2009), Song (Citation2009).

3 ‘BRICs and Beyond’, Goldman Sachs, November 2007, available at: http://www.goldmansachs.com/our-thinking/archive/BRICs-and-Beyond.html, accessed 2 December 2016.

4 ‘Raspredelenie obshchego ob”ema denezhnykh dokhodov naseleniya’, available at: http://www.gks.ru/free_doc/new_site/population/urov/urov_32g.htm, accessed 29 November 2016.

5 Izvestiya, 11 March 2011, pp. 1, 3.

6 Kommersant’, 4 July 2011, p. 3.

7 In the Russian case this includes Zaslavskaya (Citation2004), Rimashevskaya (Citation2007), Shkaratan et al. (Citation2009), Tikhonova (Citation2011).

8 Major contributions include Khan and Riskin (Citation2001), Bian (Citation2002), Wang (Citation2008) and Whyte (Citation2010a), as well as edited collections by Shue and Wong (Citation2007), Wan (Citation2008) and Davis and Wang (Citation2009).

9 China Daily, 12 May 2010.

10 Moscow News, 5 July 2011, p. 2.

11 See also Munro (Citation2008), Shambaugh (Citation2008).

12 Similar arguments concerning China’s new rich have been presented by Chen (Citation2002), Tsai (Citation2007).

13 Daily Telegraph, 29 July 2011.

References

  • Alexeev, M. V. & Gaddy, C. G. (1993) ‘Income Distribution in the USSR in the 1980s’, Review of Income and Wealth, 39, 1.
  • Bian, Y. (2002) ‘Chinese Social Stratification and Social Mobility’, Annual Review of Sociology, 28.
  • Cai, H., Chen, Y. & Zhou, L.-A. (2010) ‘Income and Consumption Inequality in Urban China: 1992–2003’, Economic Development & Cultural Change, 58, 3.
  • Cai, Y. (2010) Collective Resistance in China: Why Popular Protests Succeed or Fail (Stanford, CA, Stanford University Press).
  • Chen, A. (2002) ‘Capitalist Development, Entrepreneurial Class, and Democratization in China’, Political Science Quarterly, 117, 3.
  • Chen, A. (2009) ‘Corporate Governance in Russia and Some Points of Comparison with China’, Chinese Economy, 42, 3.
  • Chen, J., Dai, D., Pu, M., Hou, W. & Feng, Q. (2010) The Trend of the Gini Coefficient of China, BWPI Working Paper 109 (Manchester, University of Manchester Brooks World Poverty Institute).
  • Davis, D. S. & Wang, F. (2009) Creating Wealth and Poverty in Postsocialist China: Studies in Social Inequality (Stanford, CA, Stanford University Press).
  • Dickson, B. J. (2003) Red Capitalists in China: The Party, Private Entrepreneurs, and Prospects for Political Change (Cambridge, Cambridge University Press).
  • Dickson, B. J. (2008) Wealth into Power: The Communist Party’s Embrace of China’s Private Sector (Cambridge, Cambridge University Press).
  • Duckett, J. (2007) ‘Local Governance, Health Finance, and Changing Patterns of Inequality in Access to Health Services’, in Shue, V. & Wong, C. P. (eds) Paying for Progress in China: Public Finance, Human Welfare, and Changing Patterns of Inequality (London, Routledge Curzon).
  • Duckett, J. (2011) The Chinese State’s Retreat from Health: Policy and the Politics of Retrenchment (London, Routledge).
  • Everson, S. (ed.) (1996) Aristotle: The Politics and the Constitution of Athens (Cambridge, Cambridge University Press).
  • Gilley, B. (2004) China’s Democratic Future: How It Will Happen and Where It Will Lead (New York, NY, Columbia University Press).
  • Goodman, D. S. G. (ed.) (2008) The New Rich in China: Future Rulers, Present Lives (London, Routledge).
  • Hutton, W. (2007) The Writing on the Wall: China and the West in the 21st Century (London, Little Brown).
  • Jacques, M. (2009) When China Rules the World: The Rise of the Middle Kingdom and the End of the Western World (London, Allen Lane).
  • Jha, P. S. (2002) The Perilous Road to the Market: The Political Economy of Reform in Russia, India and China (London, Pluto Press).
  • Khan, A. R. & Riskin, C. (2001) Inequality and Poverty in China in the Age of Globalization (Oxford, Oxford University Press).
  • Kryshtanovskaya, O. & White, S. (2011) ‘The Formation of Russia’s Network Directorate’, in Kononenko, V. & Moses, A. (eds) Russia as a Network State (Basingstoke, Palgrave Macmillan).
  • Kukol, E. (2011) ‘Luchshee—men’shinstvu’, Kommersant’, 7 April.
  • Larsson, T. (2006) ‘Reform, Corruption, and Growth: Why Corruption is More Devastating in Russia than in China’, Communist and Post-Communist Studies, 39, 2.
  • Li, B. & Zhong, Y. (2009) ‘How did China’s Transitions Impact People’s Welfare Benefits in the Reform Era?’, Journal of Contemporary China, 18, 62.
  • Lipset, S. M. (1959) ‘Some Social Requisites of Democracy: Economic Development and Political Legitimacy’, American Political Science Review, 53, 1.
  • Liu, X. (2010) ‘Decomposition of China’s Income Inequality, 1995–2006’, Chinese Economy, 43, 4.
  • Ma, S.-Y. (2000) ‘Comparing the Russian State and the Chinese State: A Literature Review’, Problems of Post-Communism, 47, 2.
  • Marsh, C. (2005) Unparalleled Reforms: China’s Rise, Russia’s Fall, and the Interdependence of Transition (Lanham, MD, Lexington Books).
  • Mill, J. S. (1964) Utilitarianism. Liberty. Representative Government (Lindsay, A. D. (ed.)) (London, Dent).
  • Munro, N. (2008) ‘Democracy Postponed: Chinese Learning from the Soviet Collapse’, Journal of Current Chinese Affairs, 37, 4.
  • Nolan, P. (1995) China’s Rise, Russia’s Fall: Politics, Economics and Planning in the Transition from Stalinism (London, Macmillan).
  • O’Brien, K. J. (2003) ‘Neither Transgressive nor Contained: Boundary-spanning Contention in China’, Mobilization, 8, 1.
  • O’Brien, K. J. (ed.) (2008) Popular Protest in China (Cambridge, MA, Harvard University Press).
  • O’Brien, K. J. & Li, L. (2006) Rightful Resistance in Rural China (Cambridge, Cambridge University Press).
  • Pye, L. W. (1990) ‘Political Science and the Crisis of Authoritarianism’, American Political Science Review, 84, 1.
  • Rimashevskaya, N. M. (ed.) (2007) Sberezhenie naroda (Moscow, Nauka).
  • Shambaugh, D. (2008) China’s Communist Party: Atrophy and Adaptation (Berkeley, CA, University of California Press).
  • Shkaratan, O., Inyasevskii, S. A., Krasilova, N. A., Krel’berg, I. M., Smyslov, D. A. & Yastrebov, G. A. (2009) Sotsial’no-ekonomicheskoe neravenstvo i ego vosproizvodstvo v sovremennoi Rossii (Moscow, Olma).
  • Shue, V. & Wong, C. (eds) (2007) Paying for Progress in China: Public Finance, Human Welfare and Changing Patterns of Inequality (London, Routledge).
  • Song, S. (2009) ‘Pension Systems and Reforms in China and Russia’, Chinese Economy, 42, 3.
  • Tikhonova, N. E. (2011) ‘Nizshii klass v sotsial’noi strukture rossiiskogo obshchestva’, Sotsiologicheskie issledovaniya, 5.
  • Tsai, K. S. (2007) Capitalism without Democracy: The Private Sector in Contemporary China (Ithaca, NY, Cornell University Press).
  • United Nations (2010) Human Development Report 2010 (New York, NY, United Nations Development Programme), available at: http://hdr.undp.org/en/content/human-development-report-2010, accessed 2 December 2016.
  • Walter, C. & Howie, F. (2010) Red Capitalism: The Fragile Foundation of China’s Extraordinary Rise (Singapore, Wiley).
  • Wan, G. H. (ed.) (2008) Inequality and Growth in Modern China (Oxford, Oxford University Press).
  • Wang, F. (2008) Boundaries and Categories: Rising Inequality in Post-Socialist Urban China (Stanford, CA, Stanford University Press).
  • Wasserstrom, J. N. (2009) ‘Middle-class Mobilization’, Journal of Democracy, 20, 3.
  • Whyte, M. K. (ed.) (2010a) One Country, Two Societies: Rural–Urban Inequality in Contemporary China (Cambridge, MA, Harvard University Press).
  • Whyte, M. K. (2010b) Myth of the Social Volcano: Perceptions of Inequality and Distributive Justice in Contemporary China (Stanford, CA, Stanford University Press).
  • Wildau, G. & Mitchell, T. (2016) ‘China Income Inequality among the World’s Worst’, Financial Times, 14 January.
  • Wright, T. (2010) Accepting Authoritarianism: State–Society Relations in China’s Reform Era (Stanford, CA, Stanford University Press).
  • Zaslavskaya, T. I. (2004) Sovremennoe rossiiskoe obshchestvo: sotsial’nyi mekhanizm transformatsii (Moscow, Delo).

Reprints and Corporate Permissions

Please note: Selecting permissions does not provide access to the full text of the article, please see our help page How do I view content?

To request a reprint or corporate permissions for this article, please click on the relevant link below:

Academic Permissions

Please note: Selecting permissions does not provide access to the full text of the article, please see our help page How do I view content?

Obtain permissions instantly via Rightslink by clicking on the button below:

If you are unable to obtain permissions via Rightslink, please complete and submit this Permissions form. For more information, please visit our Permissions help page.