582
Views
0
CrossRef citations to date
0
Altmetric
Miscellany

In Memoriam: Robert Heilbroner, 1919 – 2005

Pages 333-336 | Published online: 17 Feb 2007

Robert Heilbroner published over twenty books and countless articles over his fifty-year career – spent entirely at the Graduate Faculty of the New School in New York – but he was best known for his first book, The Worldly Philosophers, which brought to life that esoteric subject, the history of economic thought. In it we learn, for example, that Adam Smith, who lived with his mother until she died at the age of ninety and then continued his ‘bachelor's life in peace and quiet,’ was so absentminded that ‘on one occasion he descended into his garden clad only in a dressing gown and, falling into reverie, walked fifteen miles before coming to’. Karl Marx was ‘not an orderly man; his home was a dusty mass of papers piled in careless disarray, in the midst of which Marx himself, slovenly dressed, padded about in an eye-stinging haze of tobacco smoke’. And Joseph Alois Schumpeter was a ‘would-be aristocrat’ who lied to friends about his young wife's background: ‘when she was away for a year before their marriage, he explained that she was being properly educated in French and Swiss schools. In fact she was earning her living in Paris as a maid’ (Heilbroner Citation1999: 45, 140, 298).

These amusing titbits might have been enough to sell the book to one generation, but The Worldly Philosophers has now inspired several.Footnote2 Its staying power comes from a compelling rendition of the great efforts to understand the dynamics of capitalism. These dynamics include short-run economic fluctuations and long-run tendencies, impressive wealth accumulation and its devastating ‘side effects’ in terms of income inequality, poverty, government corruption, business collusion, and industrial concentration. Heilbroner linked these turbulent dynamics to the social, political, ethical and technological issues of the day. What bubbles up from the pages of The Worldly Philosophers is the tumultuous evolution of capitalist societies over the past 250 years and the creativity of the ‘great economic thinkers’ in capturing these complex dynamics.

At the same time as he was exploring the nature of the Smithian, Marxian and Schumpeterian contributions, Heilbroner was also making a name for himself as one of the most respected commentators on contemporary economic problems and especially on the prospects for social betterment in the late twentieth century. Heilbroner's writings on the future of capitalism constitute a unique genre. Books such as The Future as History (1961), An Inquiry into the Human Prospect (1980), Twenty-First Century Capitalism (1993) and Visions of the Future (1995) and articles in Social Research, The New Yorker and The New York Review of Books placed him at the forefront of public intellectual life in the latter part of the twentieth century.

How are we to reconcile Heilbroner the intellectual historian with Heilbroner the contemporary critic? As I have argued elsewhereFootnote3, these two strands of Heilbroner's writings are closely connected. The worldly philosophers' insistence on endogenous system dynamics, their focus on social determinants of individual psychology and behaviour and the rich interplay of morality and efficiency all help set the tone of Heilbroner's voice as prognosticator. At the same time, Heilbroner's deep concern with the prospects for late twentieth century capitalist societies provided the lens through which he interpreted the history of economic thought. The dual Heilbronerian ‘voices’ were not just compatible: the historical, ethical and social grounding of the classical vision are what gave meaning to Heilbroner's imagination of the prospects for capitalism in the future.

Heilbroner's embrace of the classicals and rejection of the modern-day neoclassicals hinges on the Schumpeterian distinction between ‘analysis’ and ‘vision’. Schumpeter (Citation1954: 42) defines vision as the ‘preanalytic cognitive act’ that ‘enters on the very ground floor.’ It is ‘ideological almost by definition’. Heilbroner rejected Schumpeter's belief that analysis and vision could be separated, arguing instead that it was precisely the interplay between the two that gave economics its creative strength, that is, its ‘worldly’ dimension.

Heilbroner's contributions to academic debates in the history of economic thought were limited, his most influential being perhaps his interpretation of the so-called ‘Adam Smith problem’. Heilbroner had limited patience for the esoterica that filled many journals in the history of economics. The history of economic ideas was of more than academic interest: it provided the visionary underpinnings for thinking about the future. The specific predictions of the worldly philosophers were often wrong (Heilbroner particularly enjoyed ‘sparring’ with Marx and Schumpeter in this regard). But this was much less important than the fact that these thinkers were deeply engaged with problems of capitalism in their day, and sought to generalize only from that very engaged perspective, in which politics and morality were intertwined with economic forces in a way that meant these ‘non-economic’ considerations could not be ignored. For all its lightness of style, the subtext of The Worldly Philosophers is an ambitious one: to unveil the grand role for economic thought in social progress. ‘[A] worldly philosophy,’ Heilbroner wrote, ‘has a unique potential to provide the visionary guidance that will help at least some capitalisms make their way as safely as possible through the coming decades…’ (Heilbroner Citation1999: 320 – 1).

In the seventh, and most recent, edition of the book, published in 1999, Heilbroner added a new, final chapter with the ambiguous title ‘The End of the Worldly Philosophy?’ Heilbroner clearly intended a play on the dual meaning of the word ‘end’: purpose and termination. He lamented that the grand purpose of economics, as exemplified by the worldly philosophers, had been lost with the modern embrace of science and its presumption of value-neutrality. In this sense, Heilbroner argued, the two meanings of the term ‘end’ in the title of the final chapter of The Worldly Philosophers are linked, as the narrow, ‘pseudoscientific’ focus of contemporary thought was leading economics to its demise because of its failure to play the important normative role in society that the ideas of Smith, Ricardo, Malthus, Marx, Mill, Keynes and Schumpeter played in their day. Heilbroner laments: ‘The new vision is Science, the disappearing one Capitalism’ (Heilbroner Citation1999: 314).

The economics profession has lost one of its most popular historians of economic thought and one of its most respected radical critics. While his brilliantly flowing and lucid writing style can probably never be replicated, Heilbroner's understanding of the purpose of economic thought – ‘to give meaning to economic life’ – will, I hope, be embraced by economists and intellectual historians for generations to come.

Notes

This piece draws on three recent essays of mine, listed as Milberg (Citation2004a, Citation2004b, Citation2005).

See, for example, the Summer 2004 issue of Social Research, entirely devoted to a celebration of the fiftieth anniversary of the publication of The Worldly Philosophers.

Milberg (Citation2004b).

References

References

  • Heilbroner R 1961 The Future as History New York: Grove Press
  • Heilbroner R 1980 An Inquiry into the Human Prospect New York: Norton
  • Heilbroner R 1993 Twenty-first Century Capitalism New York: Norton
  • Heilbroner R 1995 Visions of the Future New York: Oxford University Press
  • Heilbroner R 1999 The Worldly Philosophers: The Lives, Times and Ideas of the Great Economic Thinkers 7th edition. New York: Simon and Schuster (first edition 1953)
  • Milberg , W . 2004a . Guest editor's introduction . Social Research , 71(2) Summer : vii – xii .
  • Milberg , W . 2004b . The Robert Heilbroner problem . Social Research , 71(2) Summer : 235 – 50 .
  • Milberg W 2005 Eulogy for Robert Heilbroner reprinted in Challenge, May – June 1 10
  • Schumpeter J 1954 History of Economics Analysis New York: Oxford University Press

Reprints and Corporate Permissions

Please note: Selecting permissions does not provide access to the full text of the article, please see our help page How do I view content?

To request a reprint or corporate permissions for this article, please click on the relevant link below:

Academic Permissions

Please note: Selecting permissions does not provide access to the full text of the article, please see our help page How do I view content?

Obtain permissions instantly via Rightslink by clicking on the button below:

If you are unable to obtain permissions via Rightslink, please complete and submit this Permissions form. For more information, please visit our Permissions help page.