197
Views
15
CrossRef citations to date
0
Altmetric
Original Articles

Does employment protection reduce the demand for unskilled labour?

&
Pages 197-222 | Published online: 15 Aug 2006
 

Abstract

We propose a model in which workers with little education or in the tails of the age distribution – the inexperienced and the old – have more chance of job failure (mismatch). Recruits' average education should then increase and the standard deviation of starting age decrease when strict employment protection raises hiring and firing costs. We test the model using annual distributions of recruits' characteristics from a 1975–1995 panel of plants in Belgium, the Netherlands, Italy, the UK and the US. The model's predictions are supported using the Blanchard–Wolfers index of employment protection as well as our alternative index.

Acknowledgements

The authors have benefited from comments from John Addison, Clive Belfield, John Heywood, Winfried Koeniger and Xiangdong Wei, and from the comments of seminar participants at the University of Birmingham, KDI School of Public Policy and Management, and Lingnan University. Support from the Joseph Rowntree Foundation for this study is gratefully acknowledged. We retain responsibility for any remaining errors.

Notes

1In a similar vein, Koeniger et al. (Citation2004), propose a model in which employment protection reduces the firm's outside option, so permitting unions to negotiate higher wages. Hence, if higher employment protection shelters costs for unskilled more than skilled workers, strict employment protection should help unions to reduce the skilled/unskilled wage differential – which they find. Our model provides a rationale for greater employment protection effects for unskilled workers.

2There is also a time-varying measure of the strictness of employment protection legislation based on employer views (Di Tella & McCulloch, Citation2002), but this series is short, 1984–1990. Alternatively, there is a series on product market regulation (Nicoletti & Scarpetta, Citation2003) – which is related to labour regulation but, of course, is not the same.

3Admittedly, an increase in capital usage over time, in response to employment protection, could also account for recruitment of more skilled workers. Our empirical findings for the employment protection variable would then simply have to be interpreted as reduced forms.

4An alternative dispersion measure is the proportion of workers in the tails of the hiring distribution, which involves somewhat arbitrary cut-off points. Hence we choose the standard deviation.

5A recursive model may be consistently estimated using equation-by-equation ordinary least squares (Greene Citation2003: 397), but not if the covariance matrix of the equation disturbances is non-diagonal, as appears to the case for some of our specifications.

6Our index is constructed based on the OECD Citation(1999) index for individual dismissal of workers with regular contracts, applying OECD weights. It includes scores for procedural inconveniences (procedures and delay to start notice) notice and severance pay for no-fault individual dismissal and difficulty of dismissal (definition of unfair dismissal, trial period, compensation and reinstatement). It is then combined with an index of the strictness of regulation of temporary employment, again based on OECD Citation(1999), and smoothed over time.

7For an early discussion of how supply shifts may affect relative wages and employment, see Perlman Citation(1958).

8For consistency over time, we concentrate on permanent males, defining ‘permanent’ to include workers whether hired on a temporary basis or not, who became subsequently employed on an open-ended basis within a year. Where such hires fell below 2 in any year, we recorded a missing observation.

9However, an exception is the Italian distilling plant, which has starting age averaging only 23.7. Special factors seem to be operative in this plant, which recruits extensively among relatives of current employees. Such extra knowledge of applicants could allow age and education criteria to be lowered. Again, we rely on the fixed effects term in Equationequation (8) to control for these special factors.

10The instrument we used for education was the school-leaving age variable, which can reasonably be excluded from the age equation. The instrument we used for starting age was the average age of the company's worker stock which, for its part, can reasonably be excluded from the education equation.

Log in via your institution

Log in to Taylor & Francis Online

PDF download + Online access

  • 48 hours access to article PDF & online version
  • Article PDF can be downloaded
  • Article PDF can be printed
USD 53.00 Add to cart

Issue Purchase

  • 30 days online access to complete issue
  • Article PDFs can be downloaded
  • Article PDFs can be printed
USD 222.00 Add to cart

* Local tax will be added as applicable

Related Research

People also read lists articles that other readers of this article have read.

Recommended articles lists articles that we recommend and is powered by our AI driven recommendation engine.

Cited by lists all citing articles based on Crossref citations.
Articles with the Crossref icon will open in a new tab.