1,658
Views
1
CrossRef citations to date
0
Altmetric
Articles

Possible effects of domestic and foreign factors on monetary policy implementation in Turkey: a DSGE-VAR approach

, &
Pages 590-606 | Received 28 Feb 2013, Accepted 03 Oct 2014, Published online: 04 Nov 2014

Abstract

In this paper, we attempt to explore the possible effects of technology, foreign output, price and terms of trade shocks on short-term interest rates in Turkey within a dynamic stochastic general equilibrium-vector autoregressive (DSGE-VAR) framework. In a sense, the primary aim of our paper is to analyse whether the Central Bank of the Republic of Turkey (CBRT) should consider the role of technology, foreign output, price and terms of trade shocks in its monetary policy implementation. Empirical results reveal that the above-mentioned factors have importance for the CBRT, which intends to control economy-wide interest rates in order to maintain price stability.

JEL classification:

1. Introduction

A well-known monetary policy rule proposed by Taylor (Citation1993) has tended to be pursued by several central banks and policymakers to assess monetary policy performance since it was commonly acknowledged that monetary policy rules outperform discretionary policies. However, in the face of the fact that the economic environment has been changing with the ever-evolving globalisation process and technological developments that affect specifically financial markets, the original Taylor rule has proved insufficient to explain the overall considerations underlying the interest rate setting behaviour of central banks. Several economists and policy makers have then provided a number of modifications of the Taylor-type reaction functions with additional explanatory variables and some changes to existing ones. First, Taylor (Citation1993) used the GDP deflator as a measure of inflation in original reaction functions while later modifications tend to use different measures of inflation such as personal consumer expenditure price index, consumer price index (CPI) inflation, core CPI inflation, GDP price inflation and expected inflation (Billi, Citation2009; Kozicki, Citation1999). Second, the original formulation of the Taylor rule was designed as a linear form, with standard weights (0.5) put on inflation and output gaps while nonlinear versions of the Taylor rule assign different weights to the deviations of inflation and output from their targeted levels (Cukierman & Muscatelli, Citation2008; Dolado, Maria-Dolores, & Naveria, Citation2005; Gerlach, Citation2000; Klose, Citation2011). Third, a forward-looking Taylor rule with a wider set of information on anticipated values of variables has been designed instead of the standard form of Taylor rule, which embedded actual lagged values of inflation and output (Clarida, Gali, & Gertler, Citation1998, Citation2000).

The original Taylor rule has also been modified so as to include additional variables such as changes in asset prices (Belke & Polleit, Citation2007; Bernanke & Gertler, Citation1999; Botzen & Marey, Citation2010; Cecchetti, Genberg, Lipsky, & Wadhwani, Citation2000; Clarida, Gali, & Gertler, Citation1998; Fernandez, Koenig, & Nikolsko-Rzhevskyy, Citation2010; Fuhrer & Tootell, Citation2008; Hoffmann, Citation2013; Rigobon & Sack, Citation2003; Semmler & Zhang, Citation2003; Smets, Citation1997), variations in long-term interest rates (Clarida, Gali, & Gertler, Citation1998, 2000; Goodfriend, Citation1998; Jones & Kulish, Citation2013; Smets, Citation1997; Yüksel, Metin-Ozcan, & Hatipoglu, Citation2013) and exchange rates (Ball, Citation1999, Citation2000; Berger & Kempa, Citation2012; Chen & Chou, Citation2012; Engel & West, Citation2006; Galí & Monacelli, Citation2005; Galimberti & Moura, Citation2013; Hoffmann, Citation2013; Kempa & Wilde, Citation2011; Lubik & Schorfheide, Citation2007; Molodtsova, Nikolsko-Rzhevskyy, & Papell, Citation2008; Molodtsova & Papell, Citation2009; Svensson, Citation2000; Taylor, Citation2001; Wilde, Citation2012), among others, into the monetary reaction functions so as to provide a wider explanation to movements in interest rates. On the other hand, this framework may still lack the ability to capture the dynamics of short-term interest rates relating to the accelerating process of globalisation and openness to external shocks which confronted central banks with challenging economic conditions.

In this study, we employed dynamic stochastic general equilibrium-vector autoregressive (DSGE-VAR) models to analyse the role of domestic and foreign macroeconomic factors influencing short-term interest rates in an open economy framework for the case of Turkey. More precisely, we aim to investigate the effects of technology, foreign output, price and terms of trade shocks on short-term interest rates parallel to the theoretical framework of Galí and Monacelli (Citation2005) and Lubik and Schorfheide (Citation2007). Accordingly, we analyse whether the Central Bank of the Republic of Turkey (CBRT), which intends to control economy-wide interest rates, should take into account the possible effects of these shocks on short-term interest rates when implementing monetary policy. Galí and Monacelli (Citation2005) show the macroeconomic implications of monetary policy rules for the small open economy while, similarly, Lubik and Schorfheide (Citation2007) only estimate the parameters of the DSGE model and aim to seek an answer to whether changes in exchange rates have an impact on monetary policy implementation. Our study differs from Lubik and Schorfheide (Citation2007) in that we not only estimate the model parameters, but also compute the effects of technology, foreign output, price and terms of trade shocks on short-term interest rates in Turkey with impulse response and forecast error variance decompositions deriving from DSGE-VAR model estimation. Thereby, the main contribution of our study to the existing literature is the discussion of possible consequences of these shocks on monetary policy implementation in Turkey.

The rest of the paper is organised as follows. Section 2 evaluates the effect of the dynamics of the Turkish economy in the liberalisation period on monetary policy decisions. Section 3 introduces the theoretical and empirical methodology of the study. The empirical results and findings of the paper are discussed briefly in Section 4. Section 5 concludes and discusses some policy implications.

2. The case of Turkey’s economy

Turkey, as an emerging market, is an important case to be studied since CBRT has made significant monetary policy changes in terms of the exchange rate regime over the past few decades due to the effects of domestic and external shocks. There have been major changes in monetary and exchange rate policies since the liberalisation period in the 1980s and these changes have affected macroeconomic variables. With the so-called 24 Ocak 1980 economic policy changes, the liberalisation process of the Turkish economy started. Within this framework, the exchange market was deregulated and then capital movements were liberalised. However, the economy became more fragile and prone to crisis owing to the early liberalisation of capital flows before strengthening of the capital market. The 1994 crisis was a crucial point for the monetary policy of the CBRT. As stated by Ozdemir and Turner (Citation2004), the CBRT utilised open market operations and created Turkish Lira through exchange transactions in order to control liquidity and defend the economy against speculative attacks after the 1994 crisis. Additionally, implementation of a crawling band exchange rate regime started after the 1994 crisis (Berument & Pasaogullari, Citation2003). The main reason for the 1994 economic crisis in Turkey was that public debt was not sustainable in an environment of high inflation along with unstable growth performance and structural problems in financial markets. As a result, the factors caused instability in the Turkish economy and shortened maturity for investors and savings.

Due to its geopolitical importance, Turkey has also experienced a greater influence of international forces on its economic policy setting and macroeconomic variables. Within this context, the Turkish government announced its own national programme for the adoption of the Acquis communautaire or the European Union (EU) Acquis on 19 March 2001 after Turkey was recognised as a candidate EU state at the Helsinki European Council in 1999. Subsequently, in an effort to harmonise its policy structures with those of the EU, Turkey determined its monetary policy, fiscal policy and exchange rate policy in accordance with the Maastricht criteria to adopt the EU’s single currency, the euro. In line with the objective of reducing inflation permanently, implementation of a currency peg exchange rate regime began. However, the rising current account deficit and real appreciation of Turkish lira increased the fragility of the Turkish economy. An important part of the current account deficit arose from the external shocks, namely the rising oil prices and appreciation of the US dollar against major European currencies. Risks related to the Turkish economy have also become diversified with the fragile banking system (currency and maturity mismatches and rise in non-performing loans). All of these factors were sufficient enough for an economic crisis in Turkey and the February economic crisis in 2001 was trigged by a political crisis leading to GDP contraction, an increase in public sector borrowing requirements (PSBR) and a high inflation rate, as shown in Table .

Table 1. Major economic indicators of Turkey.

The impact of both domestic and foreign macroeconomic shocks upon short-term interest rates has significantly emerged in Turkey as a consequence of the 2001 economic crisis after the monetary policy changes with the abolition of the currency peg and transition into a floating currency regime and the implementation of inflation targeting strategy. Moreover, in an effort to harmonise its policy structures with those of the EU, at the beginning of 2002, the CBRT began to implement inflation targeting, which was inclined toward the use of short-term interest rates in accordance with the floating exchange rate regime since it is efficient under domestic and foreign shocks. In parallel with the price stability objective, the CBRT started to use short-term interest rates as a basic policy tool. As a result of the inflation targeting regime, accompanied by fiscal discipline, inflation and interest gradually decreased in Turkey. However, the 2007–2008 financial crisis negatively affected Turkish economic activity and GDP decreased by 4.8% in 2009. Since the volatility of cross-border capital flows increased after the 2007–2008 global crisis, specifically in the emerging markets, such as Turkey, many central banks started to change their policy tools in order to control the current account, exchange rate and credit growth. In Turkey, the CBRT has initiated a new mixed policy tool that consists of an asymmetric interest rate corridor controlling foreign fund supply and a reserve option mechanism managing the foreign fund demand (Aysan, Fendoğlu, & Kilinç, Citation2014). In this way, the CBRT considers price stability as the main objective and financial stability as the supportive objective. Concerns about raising the short-term interest rates to maintain price stability, which would prompt exchange rate appreciation and trigger financial stability, were the reasons for policy tool diversification. In other words, the traditional view of monetary policy of the CBRT changed after the global crisis and the CBRT started to implement more flexible monetary policy to fight against external shocks (Eşkinat, Citation2013). In this context, there have been some studies investigating whether the CBRT followed the Taylor rule during the crises period. Aklan and Nargelecekenler (Citation2008) showed that for the period of 2001–2006, the CBRT followed the Taylor rule in interest rate setting. Erdem and Kayhan (Citation2011) investigated the short-term interest rate decisions of the CBRT and changes in macroeconomic variables using Taylor type policy reaction functions for two periods. The findings of this study revealed that from January 2002 to March 2006 the policy of the CBRT was not consistent with the pure Taylor rule, in contrast to the findings of Aklan and Nargelecekenler (Citation2008), however during the period from April 2006 to November 2009 the CBRT followed a pure Taylor rule. Erdem and Kayhan (Citation2011) pointed out that for the period of 2006–2009, the CBRT considered the output gap movements and exchange rate fluctuations in short-term interest rate decisions. Uslu and Özçam (Citation2014) also examined this issue for the period of 2003–2012 and the results showed that CBRT did not follow a strict Taylor rule.

As for the so-called 24 Ocak 1980 economic policy changes, the year 2002, when inflation targeting within the context of the Taylor rule had begun implementation, can be recognised as a significant year for regime change in terms of monetary policy stance. Thus, the year 2002 could have led to structural breaks in short interest rate series in Turkey. We tested whether the year 2002 caused a structural break in the dynamics of a short interest rate, upon which we developed our empirical analysis. Since DSGE models derived from economic theory can be used to define all the linkages between short-term interest rates and domestic and foreign macroeconomic variables, we attempt to fill the gap in the literature by analysing the role of domestic and foreign macroeconomic shocks influencing short-term interest rates for the case of Turkey with the DSGE-VAR model’s impulse response and forecast error variance decompositions. When the alternative specifications of the Taylor rule are considered, our study focuses on the factors overlooked in Taylor’s monetary policy rule with responses to inflation, output gap and exchange rate. Within this framework, we defined a set of equations, namely the monetary policy reaction function, as well as the New Keynesian Phillips curve and IS curve. These equations were considered in our DSGE-VAR model estimation, where we show the role of technology and foreign shocks on short-term interest rates in Turkey.

3. Theoretical and empirical framework

Since the pioneering work of Sims (Citation1980), VAR models have been widely used by researchers to analyse macroeconomic dynamics. However, the basic VAR is unable to expose the detailed structure of shocks as it is a ‘reduced-form’ model. In order to unpack the shocks hitting the system and their effects on the economy, time series models should be identified with extra assumptions. Within this context, DSGE models derived from economic theory can be used to define all the linkages between variables (Liu & Theodoridis, Citation2010) as is evident from a growing literature in DSGE-VAR models (Chow, Lim, & McNelis, Citation2014; Chow & McNelis, Citation2010; Del Negro & Schorfheide, Citation2004; Franchi & Paruolo, Citation2012; Ghent, Citation2009; Lees, Matheson, & Smith, Citation2007; Liu, Gupta, & Schaling, Citation2008; Liu & Theodoridis, Citation2010; Morris, Citation2012; Watanabe, Citation2009).

3.1. The economic model

In line with the aim of our study, our economic model consists of three major equations, namely a monetary policy reaction function, New Keynesian Phillips curve and IS curve, all of which are forward-looking in nature. Our monetary policy reaction function formulation includes the exchange rate, which is introduced under the purchasing power parity (PPP) assumption. On the other hand, foreign factors, world output, terms of trade and foreign inflation, are incorporated into the system since open economies can engage in intertemporal as well as intratemporal trade for the purpose of smoothing consumption, as suggested by Lubik and Schorfheide (Citation2007).

We define a linear monetary policy reaction function with forward-looking behaviour where the central bank chooses its policy according to the expected inflation t+1 and deviations of output from its potential level and nominal exchange rate depreciation Δet.Footnote1 Thus, the target or policy interest rate is assumed to be determined as below:(1)

where , and are policy coefficients. δ is a coefficient denoting the long-run equilibrium nominal interest rate. When the short-term interest rate (rt) is assumed to follow the path , the policy rule with interest-rate inertia can be expressed as below:(2)

where ɛr,t is the unsystematic component of the monetary policy. ρ ∊ [0, 1] captures the degree of the interest rate smoothing. We summarised the response of the monetary policy authority to the changes in inflation and other macroeconomic variables (output gap and exchange rates) as in the equations above. On the other hand, in order to understand the dynamics of inflation, some modifications of the Phillips curve have been used by researchers and policymakers. The Phillips curve with forward-looking behaviour indicates that the current inflation rate is affected by the expected inflation. Accordingly, a higher/lower expectation of future inflation leads to a higher/lower current inflation (Semmler, Greiner, & Zhang, Citation2003, p. 10). Similar to Mihailov, Rumler, and Scharler (Citation2011), our New Keynesian Phillips curve specification including terms of trade is expressed as below:(3)

where κ > 0 is a function of factors such as labour supply and demand elasticities and parameters measuring the degree of price stickiness.Footnote2 Increases in output gap and expectations related to the terms of trade lead to an increase in the current inflation.

Along with the classical Philips curve approach, IS equations can be modified by the inclusion of expectations. An IS curve with forward-looking behaviour differs from the traditional one in that current output depends on expected future output and inflation as well as the interest rate. Accordingly, it is expected that economic agents prefer to smooth consumption; expectation of higher/lower consumption in the subsequent period leads them to consume more/less in the current period and thus current output rises. Similarly, if individuals expect the inflation rate to increase/decrease in the future, they will consume more/less today, which in turn raises/lowers the current inflation rate (Semmler, Greiner, & Zhang, Citation2003, p.10). Our formulation also includes technology and terms of trade as a determinant of current output. Within this context, we specify the IS curve as in equation (4), similar to Galí and Monacelli (Citation2005) and Lubik and Schorfheide (Citation2007);Footnote3(4)

In equation (Equation4), 0 < α < 1 is the import share and τ−1 > 0 denotes the intertemporal substitution elasticity.Footnote4 Endogenous variables of the IS curve are aggregate output (yt) and the CPI inflation rate (πt), whereas zt is technology growth, qt is the terms of tradeFootnote5 and is exogenous world output.Footnote6

3.2. DSGE-VAR model representation

The DSGE-VAR model is based on the basic VAR model as represented below:(5)

where ɛt ∼ Nn(0, Σɛ). Φ0 is an (n × k) matrix, while the matrix (Φj) is (n × n) for j = 1, ..., p. xt is a p dimensional covariance stationary vector stochastic process,Footnote7 while yt is (n × 1). When the vector has dimension (np + k) and the matrix Φ = [Φ0Φ1⋯Φp] is of dimension n × (np + k). The VAR model can be expressed as (Warne, Citation2012):(6)

3.2.1. Identifying structural shocks of the DSGE-VAR impulse response functions

Estimation of DSGE-VAR requires the identification of structural shocks to the model similar to structural vector autoregression (SVAR) models.Footnote8 If we assume that υt ∼ Nn(0, In) represent these shocks, they are related to the VAR residuals ɛt through;(7)

Within this framework, A0 is the (n × n) dimensional matrix and each column is equal to the contemporaneous response in yt from a unit impulse to the corresponding element of υt. For the identification of structural shocks n(n – 1)/2 restrictions need to be imposed in addition to the n(n + 1)/2 restrictions that are imposed through the assumed covariance matrix of υt (Warne, Citation2012).

If ɛt is substituted in equation (Equation5) using equation (Equation7), the shocks are defined as:(8)

where . When the structural shocks, υt, are identified, the responses of endogenous variables to these shocks can be computed as:(9)

where the vector is (np × 1) dimensional, while the matrix Jp has dimension (np × p) with In on top and zeros below such that . From equation (Equation9), the responses of the endogenous variables are specified (Warne, Citation2012):(10)

3.2.2. Forecast error variance decompositions

Forecast error variance decomposition in DSGE-VAR models can be estimated in a manner similar to that used for other VAR models.Footnote9 If is the n × n matrix with all impulse responses in y for period i, the long-run forecast error variance decomposition can be expressed as (Warne, Citation2012):(11)

3.3. Data

In accordance with the aim of our study, we carried out an empirical exercise by using data at quarterly frequencies from 1998:1 to 2013:4 due to data availability for the case of Turkey. The real GDP is seasonally adjusted with the base year (2010) = 100, whereas the CPI measures the percentage change from the previous period. The short-term interest rate is proxied by the overnight interbank rate. As for the nominal exchange rate variable, we computed a nominal exchange rate index with the base year (2010) = 100 expressed in logarithms by using nominal exchange rate defined in units of Turkish lira (TRY) per unit of US dollar ($). The terms of trade variable is measured as the (log-) ratio of export and import price indices. World output and inflation, technological progress and terms of trade are exogenous processes whereas the terms of trade variable is treated as endogenous as suggested by Lubik and Schorfheide (Citation2007). The time series were extracted from OECD and CBRT databases.Footnote10 All series incorporated in the empirical exercise are seasonally adjusted and estimations were carried out by using MATLAB routines.

There were monetary policy changes in Turkey during the period under study, however the year 2002 coincides with a major monetary policy regime change in Turkey as summarised in Section 1. On the other hand, we applied a unit root (UR) testFootnote11 with a structural break to the overnight interbank rate series to determine the date that led to a shift in the overnight interbank rate series. The test pointed out that 2003:02 caused a structural break in the overnight interbank rate series. Considering the statistical finding related to the overnight interbank rate series and the importance of the year 2002 for the Turkish economy in terms of monetary policy change, two DSGE-VAR models were estimated due to statistical and economic reasons. Model 1 considers the period from 1998:1 to 2013:4, while Model 2 was computed from the period 2002:1 to 2013:4.

4. Empirical results

For the empirical analysis, we employed DSGE-VAR modelling according to the theoretical framework presented in Section 2.1. The variables (yt, πt, rt, qt, Δet) form a linear rational expectations model, where we applied the marginal posterior mode estimation routine for the DSGE-VAR model. A lag order of 4 was selected for both Model 1 and 2 so that the model with the largest marginal likelihood is chosen. The DSGE-VAR model was identified by selecting state shocks equal to the number of endogenous variables (rt, zt, , , qt). We incorporated priors into the estimation process similar but not identical to Lubik and Schorfheide (Citation2007).Footnote12 Models 1 and 2 are solved with Anderson and Moore’s algorithm; both models use DSGE-VAR marginal posterior as an estimator, the hyperparameter is set to infinity and the inverse Hessian estimator was employed as the optimisation routine.Footnote13 Thus, we attempted to compute the response of the overnight interbank rate to one standard deviation shock in technology, foreign output and price and terms of trade and perform forecast error variance decomposition analysis of overnight interbank rate series. Thereby, we compared the results of impulse response and forecast error variance decomposition of the two DSGE-VAR models.

According to the neoclassical growth models, technological progress is a major factor influencing long-run economic growth as well as capital accumulation and population growth. Technological progress may also decrease production costs and thus may have a role in decreasing inflation as examined by Mincer and Danninger (Citation2000), Stalder (Citation2001), Storm and Naastepad (Citation2009), McAdam and Willman (Citation2011) and Alani (Citation2012). Therefore, technology shocks may have had an indirect impact on the CBRT’s policy interest rate, determined in response to changes in output and inflation. Figure shows that the overnight interbank rate fell following a one standard deviation shock in technology and the influence can be regarded as temporary since it lasts up to the fifth quarter in Models 1 and 2, which is consistent with the finding of Lubik and Schorfheide (Citation2007). On the other hand, the effect of technology shocks on the overnight interbank rate were relatively long-lived; the overnight interbank rate fell up to the following 40th quarter. Both models expose the negative relationship between technological progress and inflation in Turkey, consistent with the outcome of studies by Mincer and Danninger (Citation2000) and Stalder (Citation2001), and in contrast to Alani (Citation2012) who found that technological progress could have led to production of more competitive goods that could be sold at prices above similar goods in the domestic markets. Our finding stresses that the effects of a decrease in production costs become more persistent compared with the effects of an increase in production in Turkey. Thus, the CBRT reduced its policy interest rate, which in turn led to a decrease in short-term interest rates. It can also be inferred that the monetary policy regime change in 2002 did not have any determinative role on the relationship between technology shocks and short-term interest rates. On the other hand, our findings provide evidence for the implication that the structural dynamics of the Turkish economy, more precisely the production structure, had not changed significantly enough to influence the outcomes of technology shocks.

Figure 1. Original response of (rt) to ɛz,t.

Source: Authors’ calculation.
Figure 1. Original response of (rt) to ɛz,t.

In the wake of economic globalisation phenomena, the analysis of the effects of foreign shocks on a domestic economy has become more important, as supported by the outcomes of a number of studies (Adolfson, Laséen, Lindé, & Villani, Citation2007a, Citation2007b; Adolfson, Lindé, & Villani, Citation2006; Alba, Su, & Chia, Citation2011; Alp & Elekdağ, Citation2011; Backus, Kehoe, & Kydland, Citation1992; Baxter & Crucini, Citation1995; Berkelmans, Citation2005; Berument & Kilinc, Citation2004; Bodenstein, Erceg, & Guerrieri, Citation2009; Jiménez-Rodríguez, Morales-Zumaquero, Égert, Citation2010; Lubik & Schorfheide, Citation2007). As the world’s economies have become more interconnected, volumes of foreign trade among countries have expanded, and thus changes in foreign economic activity affect the demand for export goods. Then, prices of export goods increase/decrease, which in turn affect the general price levels in the domestic economy. According to Figure a long-lived effect on overnight interbank rate was detected by both models following a one standard deviation shock in foreign output level. This finding is in line with that of Lubik and Schorfheide (Citation2007) and Alba, Su, & Chia, (Citation2011), implying that changes in foreign output as an external shock may have a permanent effect on economic activity in Turkey consistent with the findings of Berument and Kilinc (Citation2004). On the other hand, the coefficient of foreign output level shock is relatively higher in Model 2, demonstrating that foreign output shocks were seriously taken into consideration by the CBRT after the inflation targeting regime. It can also be interpreted that CBRT’s monetary policy may essentially be under the influence of foreign economic activity as found by Alp and Elekdağ (Citation2011), thus the CBRT should closely monitor the level of economic activity in the world and implement its policy accordingly.

Figure 2. Original response of (rt) to .

Source: Authors’ calculation.
Figure 2. Original response of (rt) to .

On the other hand, any impact of foreign or domestic conditions on prices is expected to influence the export and the domestic prices of a good as stated by Kravis and Lipsey (Citation1977). Within this context, increases in the foreign price level may affect the domestic price level via the prices of imported goods as detected by Ferrucci, Jiménez-Rodríguez and Onorante (Citation2010), Lipińska and Millard (Citation2011) and Hamilton (Citation2012). Since increases in the prices of imported goods may lead to inflationary pressures on domestic prices, central banks may consider the role of foreign price shocks in their monetary policy implementation. Figure shows that as a result of a one standard deviation shock in foreign price level, both models detect short-term interest rate decreases sharply in line with the finding of Lubik and Schorfheide (Citation2007). However, the coefficient of foreign inflation shocks is relatively smaller in Model 2, as shown in Figure , pointing to the fact that the CBRT has focused on business cycles of foreign countries rather than foreign price dynamics when compared with our finding related to the impacts of foreign output shocks. Nevertheless, our findings reveal that the CBRT determines its policy interest rate in accordance with the trends in foreign price level and thus the overnight interbank rate may be influenced. Hence, it is critically important for the CBRT to clarify the channels through which the foreign price level influences the domestic price level by using quantitative techniques.

Figure 3. Original response of (rt) to .

Source: Authors’ calculation.
Figure 3. Original response of (rt) to .

It is theoretically accepted that an improvement in the terms of trade increases real income, thereby raising savings and investment, leading to an improvement of the current account balance. Thus, changes in current account balance reflect the need for quantities of foreign resources that should be borrowed to fund investment. In addition, the current account deficit is a major factor influencing risk perception and causing global imbalances (Acharya & Schnabl, Citation2010; Bernanke, Citation1995; Borio & Disyatat, Citation2011; Dullien, Citation2010; Eichengreen, Citation2009). Figure shows that as a result of a one standard deviation shock in terms of trade, implying improvement in terms of trade and thus current account balance, the overnight interbank rate decreased. However, the negative effect is not long-lived in Models 1 and 2, persisting to the fifth quarter in line with the finding of Lubik and Schorfheide (Citation2007). More precisely, it can be asserted that the CBRT considered the factors leading to changes in terms of trade when determining the policy rate despite our finding that terms of trade shocks have short-term effects on the dynamics of the overnight interbank rate. Consequently, we find a positive relationship between current account deficit and interest rate, revealing that an improvement in the terms of trade lowers the need for foreign resources to fund investments and leads to a fall in short-term interest rates as stated by Eicher, Schubert, and Turnovsky (Citation2008). Since the short-term interest rate falls, our finding also indicates that risk perception decreases due to the improvement of terms of trade.

Figure 4. Original response of (rt) to ɛq,t.

Source: Authors’ calculation.
Figure 4. Original response of (rt) to ɛq,t.

Forecast error variance decomposition analysis was also performed to determine the degree of importance of endogenous variables for the overnight interbank rate for the following 40 quarters. Thereby, the long-run variance of short-term interest is decomposed in the long run.

According to Table , the overnight interbank rate explains approximately 35% of the variation in itself up to the 40th quarter, while shocks in the overnight interbank rate account for approximately 10% of the variation in itself in Model 2. It can be asserted from both models that the short-term interest rate has an important explanatory power over the variation in itself, which is in line with the finding of Berkelmans (Citation2005). Thus, it is critically important to analyse the dynamics of the money markets for the success of the CBRT’s interest rate policy. Within this context, interactions between money and capital, derivatives and currency markets should be determined by the CBRT in an open economy framework. Furthermore, foreign factors should be considered in order to explain the variations in short-term interest rates as stressed by the forecast error variance decomposition results. Up to the 40th quarter, foreign output and price shocks account for approximately 50% of the variation in the overnight interbank rate in Model 1, while foreign dynamics have a major importance for the short-term interest rates since forecast error variance decompositions show that foreign shocks explain approximately 90% of the variation in the overnight interbank rate. These findings emphasise that economic integration of the Turkish economy with foreign economies has been deepened over the last decade. Accordingly, it can be asserted that macroeconomic policies targeting the convergence of the Turkish economy with the EU has been successful in this respect. Moreover, it was revealed that the CBRT has given importance to the dynamics of foreign economies in its monetary policy formulation when determining the policy rate. However, the limited effects of terms of trade shocks on the overnight interbank rate are in contrast to our implication about the increased integration level of the Turkish economy with foreign economies. We find that terms of trade shocks account for the 15% of the variation in overnight interbank rate from forecast error decompositions of Model 1. It can be interpreted that terms of trade shocks do not have any considerable impact on the dynamics of the overnight interbank rate as a result of Model 2.

Table 2. Forecast error variance decomposition results of rt (models 1 and 2).

Our forecast error variance decomposition results shown in Table are supported by Berkelmans (Citation2005) and Adolfson, Laséen, Lindé, & Villani, (Citation2007b); we reveal that changes in the level of foreign economic activity may play a key role in comprehending the dynamics of short-term interest rates in money markets in Turkey. Accordingly, foreign output and price and terms of trade shocks should be considered by the CBRT when implementing monetary policy in the process of financial liberalization and economic integration, which have had a continuous path. On the other hand, consistent with the findings of Adolfson, Laséen, Lindé, & Villani, (Citation2007b), technology shocks account for a maximum of 5% of the variation in the overnight interbank rate for the following quarters in contrast to the finding of Mertens (Citation2010) who showed that technology shocks have a major role in the variations in interest rates. Nevertheless, the CBRT should determine its interest policy by taking into account the consequences of technology shocks.

5. Conclusions

In this study, we examined the effects of domestic and foreign macroeconomic factors on short-term interest rates in an open economy framework with the DSGE-VAR model for Turkey. Impulse response and forecast error variance decomposition results provide evidence of the fact that short-term interest rates may be seriously affected by the foreign shocks. According to the impulse response analysis, positive shocks in foreign output and prices lead to an increase in the short-term interest rate proxied by the overnight interbank rate. The positive effect of the shock in foreign output on the overnight interbank rate lasts for the following 40 quarters, while the positive effect of foreign price shock on the overnight interbank rate does not have as high an impact on the overnight interbank as foreign output. The coefficients of foreign price shocks derived from the impulse response analysis of both models are relatively smaller. Forecast error variance decomposition analysis indicates that foreign output and price shocks account for a major part of the forecast error variance of the overnight interbank rate in models 1 and 2. We also found that a positive terms of trade shock leads to a decrease in the overnight interbank rate and it can explain a maximum of 15% of the 40-step forecast error variance of the overnight interbank rate. Our findings imply that domestic economic activity is seriously under the influence of foreign shocks and thus the CBRT should consider foreign output, price and terms of trade shocks in monetary policy implementation. On the other hand, the positive effect of technology shocks on the overnight interbank rate is short-lived with an effect persisting in the following five quarters, and technology shocks explain a maximum of 5% of the 40-step forecast error variance of the overnight interbank rate. Accordingly, it can be interpreted that the influence of technology shocks on the short-term interest rate can be regarded as limited and temporary when compared with the effects of foreign shocks. Nevertheless, the CBRT should consider technology shocks as well as foreign output, price and terms of trade shocks to maintain price stability since developments in technology may lead to a reduction in costs for firms in the face of the current period of rapid technological progress.

Notes

1. When the relative PPP condition is assumed to hold, πt is equal to , where Δqt is the change in terms of trade with respect to the previous period; is a world inflation shock. It is assumed that is an exogenous AR(1) process, , where is autoregressive coefficient and denotes the innovations of the process.

2. See Galí and Monacelli (Citation2005) and Mihailov, Rumler, & Scharler, (Citation2011).

3. The specification of the IS Curve by Lubik and Schorfheide (Citation2007) depends on the small open economy model with two sectors (household and firms) as summarised by Galí and Monacelli (Citation2005).

4. For more details, see Lubik and Schorfheide (Citation2007).

5. We calculate qt as the relative price of exports in terms of imports. The terms of trade is placed in the IS curve equation as in first difference form (Δ) to reflect the changes in (relative) prices that affect CPI inflation.

6. Technological progress, foreign output and terms of trade are assumed to evolve according to univariate AR(1) processes: zt = ρzzt−1 + ɛz,t, and Δqt = ρqΔqt−1 + ɛq,t, where, ρz, and ρq are autoregressive coefficient and ɛz,t, and ɛq,t denote the innovations of the AR(1) processes.

7. xt satisfies the relation t = 1, ..., T, where dt is q dimensional and deterministic. The residuals ɛt are assumed to be i.i.d. Gaussian with zero mean and positive definite covariance matrix. Πl is a matrix (p × p), while Ψ is (p × q), measuring the expected value of xt. The elements of the vector xt (dt) are all elements of the vector yt (xt) in the measurement equation of the DSGE model (Warne, Citation2012).

8. For the identification of SVAR models, see Breitung, Brüggemann, and Lütkepohl (Citation2007).

9. For the details of the conditional variance decompositions of the DSGE model function, see Warne (Citation2012).

10. The real GDP, consumer price inflation, overnight interbank rate and nominal exchange rate series are obtained from the OECD database; export and import price indices are extracted from the database of the CBRT.

11. For the details of the UR test, see Saikkonen and Lütkepohl (Citation2003) and Lütkepohl (Citation2007).

12. Prior distribution of model parameters identical and priors for the parameters of the model were determined to consider the fact that Turkey is a natural resource importing country. Therefore, domestic business cycle fluctuations are likely to have a major international relative price component in Turkey. Initial values, prior distribution of model parameters and parameter estimates can be provided upon request.

13. Estimation procedure requires the vector Bt, containing the variables used in the model to be modified as: Bt = (4rt, 4πtyt, Δet)′. For more information on the technical details of the estimation procedure, see Warne (Citation2012).

References

  • Acharya, V. V., & Schnabl, P. (2010). Do global banks spread global imbalances? The case of asset-backed commercial paper during the financial crisis of 2007–09. IMF Economic Review, 58, 37–73.10.1057/imfer.2010.4
  • Adolfson, M., Laséen, S., Lindé, J., & Villani, M. (2007a). Evaluating an estimated new Keynesian small open economy model ( Working Paper: No. 203). Sveriges Riksbank.
  • Adolfson, M., Laséen, S., Lindé, J., & Villani, M. (2007b). Bayesian estimation of an open economy DSGE model with incomplete pass-through. Journal of International Economics, 72, 481–511.10.1016/j.jinteco.2007.01.003
  • Adolfson, M., Lindé, J., & Villani, M. (2006). Forecasting performance of an open economy dynamic stochastic general equilibrium model ( Working Paper: No.190). Sveriges Riksbank.
  • Aklan, N. A., & Nargelecekenler, M. (2008). Taylor rule in practice: Evidence from Turkey. International Advances in Economic Research, 14, 156–166.10.1007/s11294-008-9148-9
  • Alani, J. (2012). Effects of growth in capital and money supply on inflation in Uganda. International Journal of Research in Management & Technology, 2, 407–413.
  • Alba, J. D., Su, Z., & Chia, W. M. (2011). Foreign output shocks, monetary rules and macroeconomic volatilities in small open economies. International Review of Economics and Finance, 20, 71–81.10.1016/j.iref.2010.07.007
  • Alp, H., & Elekdağ, S. (2011). The role of monetary policy in Turkey during the global financial crisis ( Working Paper: No. 11/10). CBRT.
  • Aysan, A. F., Fendoğlu, S., & Kilinç M. (2014). Managing short term capital flows in new central banking: Unconventional monetary policy framework in Turkey ( Working Paper: No. 14/03). CBRT.
  • Backus, D. K., Kehoe, P. J., & Kydland, F. E. (1992). International real business cycles. The Journal of Political Economy, 100, 745–775.10.1086/jpe.1992.100.issue-4
  • Ball, L. (1999). Efficient rules for monetary policy. International Finance, 2, 63–83.10.1111/infi.1999.2.issue-1
  • Ball, L. (2000). Policy rules and external shocks ( Working Paper: No. 7910). NBER.10.3386/w7910
  • Baxter, M., & Crucini, M. J. (1995). Business cycles and the asset structure of foreign trade. International Economic Review, 36, 821–854.10.2307/2527261
  • Belke, A., & Polleit, T. (2007). How the ECB and the US Fed set interest rates. Applied Economics, 39, 2197–2209.10.1080/00036840600749623
  • Berger, T., & Kempa, B. (2012). Taylor rules and the Canadian–US equilibrium exchange rate. Journal of International Money and Finance, 31, 1060–1075.10.1016/j.jimonfin.2011.12.010
  • Berkelmans, L. (2005). Credit and monetary policy: An Australian SVAR ( Discussion Paper: No. 2005-06). Reserve Bank of Australia Research.
  • Bernanke, B. S. (1995). The global saving glut and the U.S. current account deficit. Retrieved from http://www.federalreserve.gov/boarddocs/speeches/2005/200503102/#f4
  • Bernanke, B. S., & Gertler, M. (1999). Monetary policy and asset price volatility. Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City Economic Review, 4, 17–51.
  • Berument, H., & Kilinc, Z. (2004). The effect of foreign income on economic performance of a small-open economy: Evidence from Turkey. Applied Economics Letters, 11, 483–488.10.1080/1350485042000244512
  • Berument, H., & Pasaogullari, M. (2003). Effects of the real exchange rate on output and inflation: Evidence from Turkey. The Developing Economies, XLI, 401–435.
  • Billi, R. M. (2009). Was monetary policy optimal during past deflation scares? Economic Review, QIII, 67–98.
  • Bodenstein, M., Erceg, C., & Guerrieri, L. (2009). The effects of foreign shocks when interest rates are at zero ( Discussion Papers: No. 983). International Finance.
  • Borio, C., & Disyatat, P. (2011). Global imbalances and the financial crisis: Link or no link? ( Working Paper: No. 346). BIS.
  • Botzen, W. J. W., & Marey, P. S. (2010). Did the ECB respond to the stock market before the crisis? Journal of Policy Modelling, 32, 303–322.10.1016/j.jpolmod.2010.03.001
  • Breitung, J., Brüggemann, R., & Lütkepohl, H. (2007). Structural vector autoregressive modeling and impulse responses. In H. Lütkepohl & M. Kratzig (Eds.), Applied time series econometrics (pp. 159–195). New York, NY: Cambridge University Press.
  • Cecchetti, S. G., Genberg, H., Lipsky, J., & Wadhwani, S. (2000). Asset prices and central bank policy ( Report No. 2). Geneva: ICMB and the CEPR.
  • Chen, S. S., & Chou, Y. H. (2012). Rational expectations, changing monetary policy rules, and real exchange rate dynamics. Journal of Banking & Finance, 36, 2824–2836.
  • Chow, H. K., Lim, G. C., & McNelis, P. D. (2014). Monetary regime choice in Singapore: Would a Taylor rule outperform exchange-rate management? Journal of Asian Economics, 30, 63–81.10.1016/j.asieco.2013.09.001
  • Chow, H. K., & McNelis, P. D. (2010). Need Singapore fear floating? A DSGE-VAR approach ( Working Paper: No. 29). SMU Economics and Statistics.
  • Clarida, R., Gali, J., & Gertler, M. (1998). Monetary policy rules in practice: Some international evidence. European Economic Review, 42, 1033–1067.10.1016/S0014-2921(98)00016-6
  • Clarida, R., Gali, J., & Gertler, M. (2000). Monetary policy rules and macroeconomic stability: Evidence and some theory. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 115, 147–180.10.1162/qjec.2000.115.issue-1
  • Cukierman, A., & Muscatelli, A. (2008). Nonlinear Taylor rules and asymmetric preferences in central banking: Evidence from the United Kingdom and the United States. The B.E. Journal of Macroeconomics, 8, 1–31.
  • Del Negro, M., & Schorfheide, F. (2004). Priors from general equilibrium models for VARs. International Economic Review, 45, 643–673.10.1111/iere.2004.45.issue-2
  • Dolado, J. J., Maria-Dolores, R., & Naveria, M. (2005). Are monetary-policy reaction functions asymmetric? The role of nonlinearity in the Phillips curve. European Economic Review, 49, 485–503.10.1016/S0014-2921(03)00032-1
  • Dullien, S. (2010). Risk factors in international financial crises: Early lessons from the 2008–2009 turmoil ( Working Papers on Money, Finance, Trade and Development: No. 01). Competence Center Berlin.
  • Eichengreen, B. (2009). The financial crisis and global policy reforms. Retrieved from http://www.cepal.org/noticias/paginas/3/35143/Eichengreen_finan_crisis_glob_pol_10-09.pdf
  • Eicher, T. S., Schubert, S. F., & Turnovsky, S. J. (2008). Dynamic effects of terms of trade shocks: The impact on debt and growth. Journal of International Money and Finance, 27, 876–896.10.1016/j.jimonfin.2007.04.015
  • Engel, C., & West, K. D. (2006). Taylor rules and the Deutschmark: Dollar real exchange rate. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, 38, 1175–1194.10.1353/mcb.2006.0070
  • Erdem, E., & Kayhan, S. (2011). The Taylor rule in estimating the performance of inflation targeting programs: The case of Turkey. Global Economy Journal, 11, 1–17.
  • Eşkinat, R. (2013). New monetary policy approach of the central bank of Turkish Republic against financial systemic risk. Paper presented at the 9th International ASECU Conference on Systematic Economic Crisis: Current Issues and Perspectives, Sopje, Republic of Macedonia.
  • Fernandez, A. Z., Koenig, E. F., & Nikolsko-Rzhevskyy, A. (2010). Can alternative Taylor-rule specifications describe Federal Reserve policy decisions? Journal of Policy Modeling, 32, 733–757.10.1016/j.jpolmod.2010.06.005
  • Ferrucci, G., Jiménez-Rodríguez, R., & Onorante, L. (2010). Food price pass-through in the Euro area: The role of symmetries and non-linearities ( Working Paper: No. 1168). ECB.
  • Franchi, M., & Paruolo, P. (2012). On ABCs (and Ds) of VAR representations of DSGE models ( Working Paper: No. 2012/4). DSS Empirical Economics and Econometrics.
  • Fuhrer, J., & Tootell, G. (2008). Eyes on the prize: How did the Fed respond to the stock market? Journal of Monetary Economics, 55, 796–805.10.1016/j.jmoneco.2008.03.005
  • Galí, J., & Monacelli, T. (2005). Monetary policy and exchange rate volatility in a small open economy. Review of Economic Studies, 72, 707–734.10.1111/roes.2005.72.issue-3
  • Galimberti, J. K., & Moura, M. L. (2013). Taylor rules and exchange rate predictability in emerging economies. Journal of International Money and Finance, 32, 1008–1031.10.1016/j.jimonfin.2012.08.006
  • Gerlach, S. (2000). Asymmetric policy reactions and inflation. Retrieved from http://www.stefangerlach.com/Asymrev.pdf
  • Ghent, A. C. (2009). Comparing DSGE-VAR forecasting models: How big are the differences? Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control, 33, 864–882.10.1016/j.jedc.2008.10.004
  • Goodfriend, M. (1998). Using the term structure of interest rates for monetary policy. Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond Economic Quarterly, 84, 13–30.
  • Hamilton, J. D. (2012, March). Import prices and inflation. International Journal of Central Banking, 8, 271–279.
  • Hoffmann, A. (2013). Did the Fed and ECB react asymmetrically with respect to asset market developments? Journal of Policy Modeling, 35, 197–211.10.1016/j.jpolmod.2012.09.005
  • Jiménez-Rodríguez, R., Morales-Zumaquero, A., & Égert, B. (2010). The effect of foreign shocks in Central and Eastern Europe. Journal of Policy Modeling, 32, 461–477.10.1016/j.jpolmod.2010.05.009
  • Jones, C., & Kulish, M. (2013). Long-term interest rates, risk premia and unconventional monetary policy. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control, 37, 2547–2561.10.1016/j.jedc.2013.07.004
  • Kempa, B., & Wilde, W. (2011). Sources of exchange rate fluctuations with Taylor rule fundamentals. Economic Modeling, 28, 2622–2627.10.1016/j.econmod.2011.08.004
  • Klose, J. (2011). Asymmetric Taylor reaction functions of the ECB: An approach depending on the state of the economy. The North American Journal of Economics and Finance, 22, 149–163.10.1016/j.najef.2011.01.002
  • Kozicki, S. (1999). How useful are Taylor rules for monetary policy? Economic Review, QII, 5–33.
  • Kravis, I. B., & Lipsey, R. E. (1977). Export and domestic prices under inflation and exchange rate movements ( Working Paper: No. 0176). NBER.
  • Lees, K., Matheson, T., & Smith, C. (2007). Open economy DSGE-VAR forecasting and policy analysis: Head to head with the RBNZ published forecasts ( Discussion Paper: No. DP2007/01). Reserve Bank of New Zealand.
  • Lipińska, A., & Millard S. (2011). Tailwinds and headwinds: How does growth in the BRICs affect inflation in the G7? ( Working Paper: No .420). Bank of England.
  • Liu, D., Gupta, R., & Schaling, E. (2008). Forecasting the South African economy: A DSGE-VAR approach ( Working Paper: No. 32). CentER.
  • Liu, P., & Theodoridis, K. (2010). DSGE model restrictions for structural VAR identification ( Working Paper: No.402). Bank of England.
  • Lubik, T. A., & Schorfheide, F. (2007). Do central banks respond to exchange rate movements? A structural investigation. Journal of Monetary Economics, 54, 1069–1087.10.1016/j.jmoneco.2006.01.009
  • Lütkepohl, H. (2007). Univariate time series analysis. In H. Lütkepohl & M. Kratzig (Eds.), Applied time series econometrics (pp. 8–85). New York, NY: Cambridge University Press.
  • McAdam, P., & Willman, A. (2011). Technology, utilization and inflation: What drives the new Keynesian Phillips curve? ( Working Paper: No. 1369). ECB.
  • Mertens, E. (2010). Structural shocks and the comovements between output and interest rates. Journal of Economic Dynamics & Control, 34, 1171–1186.
  • Mihailov, A., Rumler, F., & Scharler, J. (2011). The small open-economy new Keynesian Phillips curve: Empirical evidence and implied inflation dynamics. Open Economies Review, 22, 317–337.10.1007/s11079-009-9125-9
  • Mincer, J., & Danninger, S. (2000). Technology, unemployment, and inflation ( Working Paper: No. 7817). NBER.10.3386/w7817
  • Molodtsova, T., Nikolsko-Rzhevskyy, A., & Papell, D. H. (2008). Taylor rules with real-time data: A tale of two countries and one exchange rate. Journal of Monetary Economics, 55, S63–S79.10.1016/j.jmoneco.2008.07.003
  • Molodtsova, T., & Papell, D. H. (2009). Out-of-sample exchange rate predictability with Taylor rule fundamentals. Journal of International Economics, 77, 167–180.10.1016/j.jinteco.2008.11.001
  • Morris, S. D. (2012). VAR(1) representation of DSGE Models. Retrieved from: http://econweb.ucsd.edu/~jhamilton/macro_morris_var.pdf
  • Ozdemir, K. A., & Turner, P. (2004). The demand for base money in Turkey: Implications for inflation and seigniorage ( Working Paper: No. 04/12). CBRT.
  • Rigobon, R., & Sack, B. (2003). Measuring the reaction of monetary policy to the stock market. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 118, 639–669.10.1162/003355303321675473
  • Saikkonen, P., & Lütkepohl, H. (2003). Testing for a unit root in a time series with a level shift at unknown time. Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Statistics, 65, 91–115.
  • Semmler, W., Greiner, A., & Zhang, W. (2003). The macroeconomy and monetary and fiscal policies in the Euro-area: Monetary policy. Retrieved from http://www.wiwi.uni-bielefeld.de/fileadmin/cemm/templates/downloads/book/macrobook.pdf
  • Semmler, W., & Zhang, W. (2003). Asset price volatility and monetary policy rules: A dynamic model and empirical evidence. Economic Modeling, 24, 411–430.
  • Sims, C. A. (1980). Macroeconomics and reality. Econometrica, 48, 1–48.10.2307/1912017
  • Smets, F. (1997). Financial assets and monetary policy: Theory and evidence ( Working Paper: No. 47). BIS.
  • Stalder, P. (2001). Forecasting Swiss inflation with a structural macromodel: The role of technical progress and the mortgage rate-housing rent link ( Working Paper: No. 3). BIS.
  • Storm, S., & Naastepad, C. W. M. (2009). Labour market regulation and productivity growth: Evidence for 20 OECD countries (1984–2004). Industrial Relations, 48, 629–654.
  • Svensson, L. E. O. (2000). Open-economy inflation targeting ( Working Paper: No. 6545). NBER.10.3386/w6545
  • Taylor, J. B. (1993). Discretion versus policy rules in practice. Carnegie-Rochester Conference Series on Public Policy, 39, 195–214.10.1016/0167-2231(93)90009-L
  • Taylor, J. B. (2001). The role of the exchange rate in monetary-policy rules. The American Economic Review, 91, 263–267.10.1257/aer.91.2.263
  • Uslu, L. Ç., & Özçam, A. (2014). A modified Taylor rule for the Central Bank of Turkey (CBRT): 2003–2012. Kahramanmaras Sutcu Imam University Faculty of Economics and Administrative Sciences Journal, 4, 223–245.
  • Warne, A. 2012. YADA manual – Computational details. Retrieved from: http://www.texlips.net/download/yada.pdf
  • Watanabe, T. (2009). The application of DSGE-VAR model to macroeconomic data in Japan ( Discussion Paper No. 225-E). ESRI.
  • Wilde, W. (2012). The influence of Taylor rule deviations on the real exchange rate. International Review of Economics and Finance, 24, 51–61.10.1016/j.iref.2012.01.001
  • Yüksel, E., Metin-Ozcan, K., & Hatipoglu, O. (2013). A survey on time-varying parameter Taylor rule: A model modified with interest rate pass-through. Economic Systems, 37, 122–134.10.1016/j.ecosys.2012.08.002