2,835
Views
2
CrossRef citations to date
0
Altmetric
Articles

Competitors’ stock price reactions in response to private equity placements: evidence from a transitional economyFootnote*

, &
Pages 550-575 | Received 21 Jul 2016, Accepted 02 Oct 2017, Published online: 05 Mar 2018

Abstract

This paper examines whether information conveyed by private equity placement decisions transfers to non-applying companies within the same industry. In particular, it investigates the impact of a company’s announcements of the application for, withdrawal, rejection, approval and completion of private equity placement, while examining the cross-sectional differences of the market performance of their industry counterparts, both in the short- and long-term. It was found that an intra-industry reaction exists; competitors experience a decrease in stock prices in response to the announcement of the application for, approval and completion of private equity placement and an increase in stock prices around the announcement of the withdrawal or rejection of applications. Further, it was found that competitors experience a decrease in their long-term stock performance following private placements. A higher discount on private equity placement is detrimental for private equity (P.E.) issuing companies in the long-term. This study, therefore, provides evidence of the existence of a contagion effect in the long-term while a competitive effect dominates in the short-term.

JEL classification codes:

1. Introduction

Over the last decade or so, private equity placements (P.E.P.s) in public markets have shown tremendous growth in developed and emerging stock markets. Private equity placements in U.S. financial markets have recently surpassed public seasoned equity offerings (S.E.O.s) in terms of dollar value and the number of transactions (Chen, Dai, & Schatzberg, Citation2010; Wruck & Wu, Citation2009).Footnote1 In 2010, UK companies made 336 P.E.P.s, amounting to $17.9 billion, while Australian companies offered $9.5 billion in private equity in 593 placements. In China, P.E.P.s were issued by 85% of companies, accounting for 81% of the value of seasoned equity financing during the period from 2006 to 2010 (Abidin, Reddy, & Chen, Citation2012; Fonseka, Colombage, & Tian, Citation2014; Yu & Xu, Citation2010).Footnote2 As a result of the current financial crisis, people believe that financial markets should be more regulated than they were previously. In recognition of the growing significance of P.E.P.s as a source of financing and the increasing financial risks, the China Securities Regulation Commission (C.S.R.C.) introduced regulation in 2006 requiring companies to meet its approval criteria before making P.E.P.s. China, therefore, provides an example of a highly regulated market setting for private equity financing activities. Chinese P.E.P.s have some features in common with those of other countries, such as non-public offering to specific targets and the existence of certain lock-in periods. Nevertheless, there are also unique characteristics, such as various purchasing methods with cash or assets, regulation of lower limits on the offer price, different lock-in periods for different investors and C.S.R.C. administrative regulations on P.E.P.s (Lu, Li, & Wu, Citation2011) that distinguish the Chinese private equity market from the rest of the world. Abidin et al. (Citation2012) argue that the new P.E.P. regulations have fewer requirements than those regulating public placements, which has resulted in the dramatic increase in the number of P.E.P.s since 2006. Hence, Chinese P.E.P.s not only affect P.E. issuing companies, but also have an impact on their industry peers. Gou, Hotchkiss, and Song (Citation2011) find that P.E.-backed companies show better market and operating performance compared to the period before such investments. Thus, one can argue that, if P.E.-backed companies perform better, this would improve their competitive position among companies in the same industry.

Stock issue announcements are motivated by managers’ desire to communicate information about the future prospects of the company. An under-valuation of the issuing company’s stocks can impact other companies in the same industry (contagion effects). The contagion effect suggests that a P.E.P. announcement by one company positively affects the future prospects of competitor companies. Therefore, investors are likely to establish a positive association between the stock price of the company making the announcement and its industry competitors, and the valuation effects will spill over to competitor companies. Alternatively, P.E. issuing companies experience a positive stock price reaction at the expense of competitor companies; thus, rivals will be negatively affected (competitive effects). The competitive effect implies that the information in a P.E.P. announcement changes the existing competitive situation and leads to wealth redistribution of competitor companies in the same industry. Therefore, a P.E.P. announcement by one company negatively affects competitor companies in the same industry. In this study, we investigate whether the C.S.R.C.’s announcement of P.E.P. arrangements generate a spillover effect on the returns of competitor companies.

Although P.E.P.s have increased tremendously in emerging markets recently, to the best of our knowledge, very few studies have explored the information transmission effect of P.E.P. announcements on competitor companies, even in developed markets. China is the second largest economy in the world and the Chinese stock market is one of the largest stock markets in Asia. Hence, the findings of this study are important for P.E. issuing companies, competitor companies, investors and regulators, because they derive from a different regulatory and institutional background and geographical context. Further, Dividend yields (payout ratio divided by Price-Earning (P/E) ratio) in China were very low, because relatively new Chinese companies did not have stable cash dividend policies (Shao & Lin, Citation2004; Wei & Jiang, Citation2001). As capital gains are not taxed, Chinese investors are motivated to seek rapid capital gains from short-term stock dividends, leading to high share price volatility (Powell, Qian, & Shi, Citation2013). Hence, stock price performance and the events that affect the stock price are important for investors. In this study, we address two research questions: How do the P.E.P. events such as application, approval and rejection, which are created by new P.E. regulations, affect stock price performance of competitor companies in both the short- and long-term? What is the effect of the information content of P.E.P.s on the stock price performance of competitor companies in both the short- and long-term?

This study contributes to the literature in several ways. First, according to the best of our knowledge, this is the first study that examines the information transmission effect of P.E.P. announcements in a highly regulated emerging market. Bo, Huang, and Wang (Citation2011) pointed out that, due to the transition nature of the economy, Chinese stock markets function differently from those of major mature market economies. We describe the institutional and P.E. regulatory differences between the U.S. and China in detail in Section 2. Second, we extend the prior literature of the information transmission effect of equity financing in the context of a highly regulated emerging market. Third, we explain the causes for the information transmission effect of P.E.P. events, both in the short- and long-term in China. One can argue that the financial market should be more regulated to overcome the adverse effects of the recent financial crisis. Further, one may believe that the introduction of regulation on the P.E.P. approval process is of particular interest to regulators in other countries and that China provides an excellent example of this. Our findings demonstrate that the highly regulated Chinese P.E. market offers large discounts due to the restrictions on the category and number of institutional investors and the P.E. offering price. Moreover, in China, the regulator has the authority to reject a P.E. application. We find that the P.E. discount results in a positive stock price reaction simultaneously in both the issuing and competitor companies, providing some evidence of the existence of the contagion effect, but only in the long-term. Cumming, Siegel, and Wright (Citation2007) identified that there is a need for additional studies to consider ‘the effects of different institutional contexts on the P.E.P. and the consequent implications for the investment and performance’. Finally, we attempt to bridge the gap of knowledge in understanding the consequences of a P.E.P. on competitors’ stock price performance in different institutional backgrounds and market conditions, consistent with the knowledge gap identified by Cumming et al. (Citation2007).

China began reforming its financial market in the early 2000s and integrating it into regional and global structures (Chan, Dang, & Yan, Citation2012). This study looks at P.E.P. in China, the world’s second largest economy and largest emerging economy in terms of gross domestic product (G.D.P.) and where P.E.P. is, by far, the dominant source of seasoned equity financing used by firms. Hence, the findings of this study are important for a large number of investors, researchers and policy-makers. China is an interesting test case for another set of reasons. Unlike in developed markets, private enforcement of investor rights and public enforcement of contractual disputes are neither well defined nor regulated in China, which relies more on an administrative governance structure to regulate the stock market (Pistor & Xu, Citation2005). Therefore, the findings of this study are useful for regulators and policy-makers of transitional/developing countries.

The Split Share Structure Reform in China started in 2005, which marks a major change in the ownership of the listed Chinese firms (e.g., Firth, Lin, & Zou, Citation2010; Hou, Kuo, & Lee, Citation2012). The reform abolished the split share structure (i.e., restricted state-owned and tradable shares), which resulted in the wealth of state shareholders being sensitive to share price movements and align the incentives of all shareholders (both state and private) to monitor and ensure managers maximise the market value of their firms (Hou et al., Citation2012). By the end of 2008, most Chinese listed firms had completed the ratification of their compensation payout plans, had enacted the gradual abolishment of their restricted shares, which became fully tradable in the stock market (Hou et al., Citation2012). Moreover, a new P.E.P.-specific regulatory regime was introduced by the C.S.R.C. in 2006, which is not amended to date. Therefore, findings of this study may be applicable for beyond the sample period and helpful for decision-making for investors, P.E. issuing and non-issuing firms and regulators. Especially, findings of this study help the regulator to understand the effect of P.E.P. regulation on P.E. non-issuing firms during the initial period, and it may provide some guideline on their regulation amendments in the future.

The rest of the paper is organised as follows. Section 2 provides a description of the institutional background and Chinese regulatory requirements for P.E. issuance, which is what motivates this empirical investigation. Section 3 discusses the relevant literature and develops the hypotheses tested in the study. In Section 4, we present data and the empirical research design, while Section 5 provides the empirical findings. Section 6 concludes the paper.

2. Review of institutional background and Chinese stock market regulations on P.E.P.s

Compared with developed countries, most companies in China are owned by the Chinese government, which greatly influences company operations and exerts enormous power in resource allocation and regulation enforcement (Tsai, Citation2008; Wu & Cheng, Citation2011). Sun and Tong (Citation2003) demonstrate that the State ownership domination of listed companies is a salient institutional feature in China. This distinct feature, as noted by Qian, Roland, and Xu (Citation1999), is the result of China’s step-by-step reform compared to the accelerated privatisation approach engaged by some Eastern European countries. The portion of State-owned companies or institutions accounted for ~ 70% of total shares (Zou & Xiao, Citation2006) prior to reform.

In 2005, the C.S.R.C. initiated share-split reform for listed companies and unfroze non-tradable, State-owned shares. Since the reform, publicly listed companies have relied primarily upon private placements to raise equity capital rather than other types of seasoned equity offerings for new investments. The Chinese stock market functions differently to those of the major market economies, due to heavy regulations (Bo et al., Citation2011). In developed markets such as the U.S., private placements are the sale of unregistered equity and bonds issued by a public company to a selected group of individuals or institutions. On the other hand, in China, the P.E.P.-specific regulatory regime was introduced by the C.S.R.C. in 2006, which made it mandatory for issuing companies to obtain approval from the regulator. This system is quite different from the self-registration P.E.P. system in other countries such as the U.S. Thus, the C.S.R.C. is actively involved in the P.E. issuing process in China; and companies that fail to comply with the regulatory conditions have their P.E.P. applications rejected.

According to C.S.R.C., the purposes of the P.E.P. regulations are to (i) reduce the related-party transactions, (ii) avoid competition, (iii) enhance independence, (iv) improve asset quality, (v) improve financial stability and (vi) enhance the sustained profitability of companies. The new P.E.P. regulations are expected to ensure that non-public offerings generate legitimate benefits. Further, companies offering P.E.P.s should determine the P.E. issue price, reflecting the best interests of all stakeholders. Regulations also govern the method for determining the P.E. price as well as the category and number of institutional investors/block-holders in a particular P.E. issue.

In the U.S., there are no restrictions on the pricing or size of a P.E.P. and the company has discretion in determining the level of discount. In China, the regulations restrict the categories of investors who can be invited to subscribe for a P.E. issue. The regulations favour passive investors, while limiting the number of institutional investors in any particular P.E. issue. Private equity placements are offered to unlimited ‘accredited investors’ and up to 35 ‘sophisticated investors’ in the U.S., but in China they must be offered to the top 20 shareholders of the company. Invitees in China should comprise: (i) not less than 20 securities investment fund management companies; (ii) not less than 10 securities companies; and (iii) not less than five insurance and financial institutional investors. However, P.E.P.s can be sold to a maximum of 10 investors who belong to any type of investor category. In China, the market discount for P.E.P.s typically lies above 30%, which is higher than in U.S. companies (Fonseka et al., Citation2014; Lu et al., Citation2011).

The primary benefits of issuing P.E. for companies are to obtain low cost capital, to build relationships with strategic investors and to raise much needed funds and, thereby, gain a competitive advantage. However, the C.S.R.C. regulations discriminate between companies by rejecting some P.E.P. applications. Moreover, the C.S.R.C.’s active role in regulating and approving P.E. issuance in China can result in a lengthy process for those companies that lodge an application for a P.E. issue (Yu & Xu, Citation2010). The P.E.P. should be concluded within 6 months of the date of the C.S.R.C. approval.

The same as the P.E. regulation in the U.S., there is no specific regulation on the value of a P.E.P. in China. However, the board of directors should disclose the maximum amount of capital it wants to raise for the project and the P.E.P. cannot exceed the amount required for the project. If the Board is uncertain about the amount of capital required, companies should disclose the maximum amount expected to be raised from the P.E.P. In the U.S., investors cannot re-sell the registered private placement for at least 6 months, depending on whether or not they are affiliated with the issuer. However, the stock can be sold to ‘qualified institutional investors’ within a restricted period. In China, all newly-issued P.E.P. stocks cannot be sold within 12 months, irrespective of the category of the investor. If the stocks are bought by the controlling stockholder or any other company controlled by the real controller, they cannot be re-sold within the next 36 months. In China, P.E.P.s are more highly regulated than in the US. Table shows the regulatory requirements for issuing P.E. in China.

Table 1. Summary of important C.S.R.C. regulations on P.E.P.s.

According to the C.S.R.C.’s requirements, the decision to approve or reject an application should be published in prescribed mass media, as well as on the C.S.R.C.’s website. Investors are not fully aware of all the price sensitive information available in incomplete markets (Merton, Citation1987). As a result, there is greater uncertainty about the stocks of companies with lower investor recognition. Rational investors, therefore, would expect such stocks to have a higher discount rate. In developed countries, such as in the U.S., the media is more independent and competitive than in China, where the media is assumed to be under strict controls (Besley & Prat, Citation2006).

3. Literature review and hypotheses

A substantial amount of research shows that P.E.P. announcements are associated with significant positive returns for P.E. issuing companies. Wruck (Citation1989), for example, finds that P.E. issuing companies realise statistically significant abnormal returns of 4.4% during the announcement period. A number of arguments have been proposed to justify this positive market response. Hertzel and Smith (Citation1993) argue that P.E.P.s are used by companies with limited financial slack to take advantage of profitable investment opportunities. Hertzel and Rees (Citation1998) and Hertzel, Lemmon, Linck, and Rees (Citation2002) state that the company signals its financial stability to the market by issuing equity privately. They find that P.E. proceeds are mainly used to finance new capital expenditure projects rather than using them to reduce financial leverage. Further, P.E.P.s have the capability to convey special information. Active investors such as mutual funds or other institutional investors who have the resources to monitor management find private placements attractive investments. Private equity placements, therefore, can alter ownership concentration, which can lead to an improvement in monitoring. Further, the change in concentration of ownership after private placements reveals new information to the market, signalling an efficient allocation of scarce resources, which leads to positive wealth effects (Brooks & Graham, Citation2005; Goh, Gombola, Lee, & Liu, Citation1999).

In capital markets, the occurrence of major events at a company or the disclosure of operational information by it not only affects its own stock price, but also the equity prices of its competitors. The positive association between the abnormal returns earned by the announcing company and those realised by its competitors is known as the contagion effect, while the negative relationship is referred to as the competitive effect. Our results provide evidence that P.E.P. events generate competitive effect on non-P.E.P. issuing companies in the same industry. Szewczyk (Citation1992) also explores whether announcements of public offerings of common stock elicit abnormal stock price reactions among companies within the same industry. He finds that average abnormal returns are significantly negative for announcing and non-announcing companies. This implies that investors draw inferences about the general prospects of the industry as a whole rather than shifts in competitive advantage between the announcing company and its industry rivals.

Erwin and Miller (Citation1998) find that, depending on the nature of the announcement, the stock prices of non-announcing companies are positively or negatively affected following an announcement by one of its industry rivals. These effects result from the market revising its expectations about the non-announcing companies’ prospects upon the receipt of new information from an industry peer. The market’s revision can turn out to be accurate if the event occurred as the announcing company carries new information that is relevant to competitive companies in the same industry (Desir, Citation2012). Few studies have examined whether equity issuing companies’ financing activities affect competitors’ returns. Akhigbe, Borde, and Whyte (Citation2003) analyse the impact of initial public offerings (I.P.O.s) on rival companies and find that there is no significant impact on rival companies’ stock price around I.P.O. issuance dates. However, Hsu, Reed, and Rocholl (Citation2010) focus on the impact of large size I.P.O.s on the performance of competing companies in the same industry and find that the companies in the same industry experience the exact opposite outcome. Slovin, Sushka, and Polonchek (Citation1992) analyse the industry-wide impact of the release of adverse information by investigating competitors’ stock price reactions to S.E.O.s in their industry.

This paper observes the determinants of P.E.P. announcement information transfer and their spillover effects on the competitor companies. We find that an increasing number of P.E.P. events in a particular industry have a negative spillover effect on competitor companies. Similarly, we find that a higher P.E.P. value also has a negative spillover effect on competitor companies. In contrast, increased P.E.P. discounts have a positive spillover effect on the stock prices of competitor companies. Prior studies do not adequately study the characteristics of P.E. deals and their spillover effects on industry counterparts in both developed and emerging markets. Our findings confirm that P.E. offer characteristics are also important determinants that affect competitor companies’ stock price performances.

Hsu, Reed, and Rocholl (Citation2011) study the impacts of large P.E. investment on competing companies in the same industry and find that, in the U.S. and Canadian markets, competitor companies are subjected to negative stock returns and abnormal stock returns in both the long- and short-term. The current study differs from Hsu et al. (Citation2011) in the following respects: (i) in China, mandatory approval from the regulator is required for P.E.P.s, whereas the U.S. has a self-regulatory’ P.E.P. system (Fonseka et al., Citation2014); (ii) the Hsu et al. (Citation2011) study sample of P.E.P.s were purchased by large P.E. investments, whereas our study covers the sample of P.E. financing which reflected minority ownership in target companies and our sample is 100% inclusive of P.E.P.s; (iii) the Chinese P.E.P. market is smaller than the U.S. market and has a shorter history of issuing P.E.P.s than the U.S. However, P.E.P.s have largely replaced traditional S.E.O.s in China due to the introduction of new P.E.P. regulations, while the regulations on S.E.O.s have remained unchanged. Hence, the relatively larger market for P.E.P.s reflects a change in corporate ownership; (iv) we investigate the effect of the regulator’s announcement of a P.E.P. on the stock price performance of competitor companies in the short- and long-term, while the Hsu et al. (Citation2011) study is restricted to P.E. investment announcements, where the regulator has no involvement in the timing of announcements. Therefore, it is worthwhile studying the effect of P.E.P. announcements on listed but non-P.E. issuing industry competitor stock prices in the context of a highly regulated capital market. From a methodological perspective, our article is related to the literature that considers the valuation effects of capital market transactions on companies in the same industry.

3.1. Hypotheses development

The literature provides several theoretical explanations and related empirical evidence on the effects of P.E.P. activity on industry competitors. The steps in the C.S.R.C. authorisation process involve assessment of an application for a P.E.P. and its subsequent approval or rejection. Some companies may withdraw the P.E.P. offer at any point between the time of application and approval, as well as after approval and before successful completion. It is also possible that some companies may not be able to successfully complete an approved P.E.P. Thus, all the events that include the announcement of a P.E.P. application, rejection or approval, and its subsequent withdrawal or completion have the potential to create an impact on competitors’ stock returns.

The first hypothesis relates to the initial submission of a P.E.P. application for C.S.R.C. approval. Since it is likely that the P.E.P. will enable the company to compete successfully against existing companies in the same industry, the P.E.P. application may have a negative impact on rivals’ stock prices (Hsu et al., Citation2010, Citation2011). On this basis, we propose the following hypothesis:

H1. The announcement of a P.E.P. application has a negative impact on the stock prices of competitors in the same industry.

As a P.E.P. is expected to allow the issuing company to compete more successfully against industry competitors, the approval of a P.E.P. may have a negative impact on competitors’ stock prices (this is a unique feature in China). Thus, we derive the second hypothesis:

H2. The announcement of C.S.R.C. approval of a P.E.P. has a negative effect on the stock prices of public listed companies in the same industry.

The successful completion of P.E.P.s provide the issuing company with the funds to invest in new capital expenditure projects and they can, therefore, achieve better performance than their industry counterparts. Hence, the successful completion of P.E.P.s may not be welcome news for competitor companies (Hsu et al., Citation2010, Citation2011). On this basis, we propose the following hypothesis:

H3. The announcement of the successful completion of a P.E.P. has a negative effect on the stock prices of public listed companies in the same industry.

If the application, approval or completion of a P.E.P. is not welcome news for competitors, then it follows that the news that an expected P.E.P. has not succeeded would be welcomed by competitors. A P.E.P. could be unsuccessful due to the application being rejected, withdrawal of the application during the approval process or withdrawal of the approved P.E. issue prior to completion. Considering the information above, we propose:

H4. The announcement of the rejection or withdrawal of the P.E.P. application by the C.S.R.C. has a positive price effect on publicly traded companies in the same industry.

In theory, stock prices can move due to investors updating expectations of future cash flows or discount rates. Cash flow news and discount rate news of equity financing lead to stock price movements, those factors work as functions of the predictive variables perceived and cash flow and discount rate news has an important bearing on the theoretical modelling of asset prices (Ang & Bekaert, Citation2007; Chen, Citation2009; Chen, Da, & Priestley, Citation2012; Larrain & Yogo, Citation2008). Wruck (Citation1989), Hertzel and Smith (Citation1993) and Lu et al. (Citation2011) use two variables (private placement discounts and P.E.P. proceedings) to determine the information effect at issuing company level. The discount reflects the ‘information price’ and the cost of the placement to the company (Hertzel & Smith, Citation1993). Chung and Hwang (Citation2010) advocate that the value of information and information acquisition has a considerable impact on the discount level in a private placement. Hertzel and Smith (Citation1993) used private placement discount to measure the information effects. They reveal that the stock price effect, based on the information effects, is larger for placements where the potential degree of under-valuation is high. Krasker (Citation1986) find that the size of a stock issue is negatively affected by the stock price. Hertzel and Smith (Citation1993) and Fonseka et al. (Citation2014) point out that the extent of information creation is subject to the economic scale of the P.E.P.s measured, using the Log of proceeds to measure placement size. In line with the studies of Wruck (Citation1989) and Hertzel and Smith (Citation1993), we argue that private placement discounts and the average proceeds from P.E.P.s at the industry level affect competitor companies. Private placement discounts and the value of P.E.P.s at an industry level is important information to transmit to the market. This information is valuable to investors, competitors and other stakeholders in the market who may act on the information and might impact on competitors’ stock price performance.

Rational investors will recognise this incentive and discount their estimates of value unless information is made credible. This credible information leads to over-valuation of competitor companies, which results in a negative stock price reaction. The extent of the information transmission effect is also subject to economies of scale and the size of discounts may be smaller in the industries that have larger placements. Hence, both the information cost of P.E.P.s (average P.E. discount at the industry levels) and the scale of P.E.P.s (average proceeds from P.E.P.s at the industry levels) can also be used to test the information transmission effect hypothesis, in addition to examining whether P.E.P.s exist within a particular industry. Based on the information above, we suggest:

H5. The scale of P.E.P.s and the number of P.E.P. events at the industry level have a negative price effect and the information cost of issuing companies has a positive effect on competitor companies in the same industry in the short-term.

Chen (Citation2015) study the announcement of S.E.O.s and capital deductions on stock prices of issuing and capital deduction firms on the Taiwan Stock Market and find a positive affect stock price return in the long-term. One can argue that this kind of positive stock price return can be spillover to other firms in the same industry. Along with the arguments of short-term stock price effects, completion of P.E.P. should also affect the stock price performance of industry rivals in the long-term. In particular, the completion of a P.E.P. is expected to give the P.E.P. issuing company a competitive advantage over its competitors and, thus, negatively affect the market performance of competitor companies in the long-term. However, if the information cost is large (P.E.P. discount), this may have a positive effect on competitor companies. Based on the information above, we suggest:

H6. The scale of P.E.P.s and the number of P.E.P. events at the industry level have a negative price effect and the information cost of issuing companies has a positive effect on competitor companies in the same industry in the long-term.

4. Data and methodology

Private equity placement data were collected manually from C.S.R.C.’s monthly Bulletin for the period 2006–2010. We chose 2006 as the starting year because the C.S.R.C. introduced the regulatory constraints on P.E. in that year. The initial sample includes 518 companies that applied for P.E.P. (615 company-year observations)Footnote3 and 428 companies that successfully completed the process (488 company-year observations) companies3. Out of this initial sample, companies in the financial industry including foreign-listed Chinese companies and Chinese companies dual-listed in Hong Kong, and companies with incomplete data, such as where important P.E.P. event dates were missed, were excluded to generate the final sample to be used in our empirical analyses.

We identified companies in the same industry as the P.E.P. issuing company using C.S.R.C. industry classification data and defined them as competitor companies. In order to observe clearly the difference in the pre- and post-stock price performance of the P.E.P. event, we further restricted competitor companies in our sample to those that were publicly listed at least 2 years before the P.E.P. event year and that did not issue P.E. during our sample period. The final sample contains 2544 competitor company observations. Data about the proceeds of P.E.P.s were obtained from the China Stock Market & Accounting Research (C.S.M.A.R.) seasonal equity offering database. We used the number of P.E.P. issues, average discount and average P.E.P. proceeds in each industry.

We employed the event study methodology to measure the market reaction of competitor (non-P.E.P. issuing) companies to the regulator’s announcements of P.E.P. events. For the purpose of generating the expected return, we first estimated the following market model:(1) Rit=αi+βiRmt+εit(1)

Where Rit is the return on the ith stock, Rmt is the return on the market index and Ɛit is an error term. This model is estimated using the daily return data for an estimation period of 255 days that ends 45 days prior to the event day—i.e., from t-300 day to t-45 day, where t is the event day. The alpha and beta parameters of the model were then used to estimate expected returns as follows:(2) ARit=Rit-Rit=Rit-α^i-β^iRmt(2)

Once abnormal returns were calculated for the sample companies for a particular day, the average abnormal returns were calculated as follows:(3) ARt¯=i=1nARitn(3)

where n is the number of sample observations on day t. The mean cumulative abnormal return over a given event period is the sum of the daily mean abnormal returns and is expressed as follows:(4) CAARi(-l,k)=t=-lkARit¯(4)

We used a cross-sectional standard deviation test to assess the significance of event window cumulative average abnormal returns (C.A.A.R.s).

(5) TCAAR=CAARt-l|tkσ^CAARt-l|tk/N(5)

where N is the number of observations, CAARt-l|tk is the mean C.A.A.R.i over the (−l |+k) event window and σ^CAARt-l|tk is the event window standard deviation (Brown & Warner, Citation1985).

We used the following regression models to test the influence of information transmission variables related to the successfully completed P.E.P. events of (−5, 5) on the abnormal return:

(6) CAARi,t=α+β1PEP Discountsi,t+β2No. of PEP Eventsi,j,t+β3PEP Proceedsi,j,t+βj(Controlsi,t-1)+εi,t(6)

We also used the following regression analyses to determine whether information transmission effects on market performance of competitors are significantly related to the successfully completed P.E.P. events in the long-term. Specifically, we employed the following two models:

(7) RETi,t=α+β1PEP Event Dummyi,t+βj(Controlsi,t-1)+εi,t(7)

(8) ARi,t=α+β1PEP Event Dummyi,t+βj(Controlsi,t-1)+εi,t(8)

where RETi,t is the annual stock return for each company i in year t. ARi,t is the annual abnormal return for each company i in year t. The i, j and t denote competitor companies, industry and time, respectively. The benchmark for abnormal returns is based on the equal weighted market return.

We estimated annual abnormal stock returns based on the three-factor model of Fama and French (Citation1993) using the calendar-time portfolio approach. Portfolios of private placements are formed daily, in calendar time. The regression model is:(9) Ri,t-Rft=αi+β1iRmt-Rft+β2iSMBt+β3iHMLt+εi,t(9)

where Ri,t is the return on portfolio i in day t, Rft is the risk free return on an average day t, Rmt is the return on a market index in day t, SMBt is the difference in the returns of a portfolio of small and big stocks in day t, HMLt is the difference in the returns of a portfolio of high book-to-market stocks and low book-to-market stocks in day t and εi,t is the error term for portfolio i in day t. The estimate of the intercept coefficient (αi) provides an average abnormal return for portfolio i. S.M.B. and H.M.L. portfolios factors were obtained from the RESSET database and all other data were obtained from the C.S.M.A.R. market database. The P.E.P. Event Dummyi,t is an indicator variable which is equal to 1 if year t in company ith belonged to industry j and there were one or more P.E.P. events, and zero otherwise. The sample comprises years for companies in which each company has data from P.E.P. and non-P.E.P. years. The P.E.P. Event Dummy variable tests the effect of P.E.P. events on competitor companies’ annual returns and annual abnormal returns.

To identify the important determinants of the information transmission effects in the long-term, we employed the following two models:(10) RETi,t=α+β1(PEP Discountsi,j,t)+β2(PEP Proceedsi,j,t)+βj(Controlsi,t-1)+εi,t(10) (11) ARi,t=α+β1(PEPDiscounts,i,j,t)+β2(PEPProceedsi,j,t)+βj(Controlsi,t-1)+εi,t(11)

where RETi,t is the annual total return for each company i in year t. ARi,t is the annual abnormal return for each company i in year t. The i, j and t denote competitor companies, industry and time, respectively. The variables, their definitions and the source of the data used in the regressions are summarised in Table .

Table 2. Variables used in regression analyses.

5. Empirical results and discussion

We analysed competitors’ short-term price reactions to P.E.P. events, the univariate change in their market performance before and after P.E.P.s and the cross-sectional responses to the number and value of P.E.P.s in their respective industry sectors. Further, we also analysed the change in competitors’ stock price performance in terms of presence (a dummy variable), number and value of P.E.P.s. Figure shows the number and value of P.E.P.s by year and Figure shows the number and value of P.E.P.s by industry.

Figure 1. Distribution of P.E.P.s by year. Source: C.S.R.C. data, which was also used by Fonseka et al. (Citation2014).

Figure 1. Distribution of P.E.P.s by year. Source: C.S.R.C. data, which was also used by Fonseka et al. (Citation2014).

Figure 2. Distribution of P.E.P.s by industry. Source: C.S.R.C. data, which was also used by Fonseka et al. (Citation2014).

Notes: The industry classification is based on the two-digit C.S.R.C. industry codes. Industries are as follows: A01 Agriculture; A03 Forestry; A07 Fishery; B01 Coal mining and dressing; B05 Ferrous metal ore mining; B07 Non-ferrous metal ore mining; B50 Mining service; C01 Food processing; C03 Foodstuff manufacturing; C05 Beverage manufacturing; C11 Textile (Cotton Mills); C13 Cloth production (Garments); C14 Leather; C21 Wood manufacture; C25 Furniture; C31 Paper; C35 Printing; C41 Oil processing and refining; C47 Chemical fibres; C48 Rubber; C49 Plastic; C51 Electronics components; C55 Electrical Equipment (Appliances); C61 Non-metal mineral products; C65 Ferrous metal foundries; C67 Non-ferrous metal foundries; C69 Metal products; C71 Common machines; C73 Special equipment manufacturing; C75 Traffic equipment manufacturing; C76 Electric equipment; C78 Instrument and office machine; C81 Medicine manufacturing; C85 Biological; D01 Utility; E01 Civil engineering construction; E05 Building fitting up and decoration; F03 Highway Transport; F07 Shipping; F09 Air transport; F11 Transportion subsidiary service; G81 Communications and related equipment; G83 Computer and related equipment; G85 Communications service; G87 Computer application service; H01 Wholesale of food and household products; H03 Wholesale of energy, materials and equipment; H11 Retail trade; I01 Banking; I21 Securities and futures; J01 Real estate; K34 Travel industry; K37 Healthcare and nursing service; K39 Leasing service; L01 Publishing industry; M, Comprehensive.
Figure 2. Distribution of P.E.P.s by industry. Source: C.S.R.C. data, which was also used by Fonseka et al. (Citation2014).

These graphs show that sample P.E.P.s are relatively evenly distributed across the sample period. Table shows descriptive statistics of the variables which used in regression both competitors firms and P.E. issuing firms.

Table 3. Descriptive statistics of independent variables of Competitor and P.E. issuing firms.

5.1. Competitor companies’ short-term price reactions

Considering the impact of the information transmission effect, the prior literature calculates C.A.A.R. from 10 days before the event date to 10 days after the date of the event (Hsu et al., Citation2010, Citation2011). Consistent with the literature, we chose similar time lags as our event windows. Table shows the C.A.A.R. for different event windows, which range from 10 days before the event date to 10 days after the event date. C.A.A.R.s are shown for announcement of the application, approval or rejection, withdrawal and completion of P.E.P. events.

Table 4. Short-term abnormal returns for competitor and P.E. issuing firms for all P.E.P. events.

According to panel A of Table , the results report significantly negative abnormal returns for competitors for alternative window periods around the announcement of an application for a P.E.P. For example, the reported C.A.A.R.s for the (−5, 5) and (−10, 10) event windows are −0.50% and −0.79%, respectively. These results support hypothesis 1, which predicts that competitors experience negative returns around the application for a P.E.P. by their counterparts within the industry. Similar results are observed in respect of approval events. For example, the C.A.A.R. of −0.18% reported for the (−5, 5) event window increased to −0.46% in the (−5, 20) window and −0.46% in the (−10, 10) window. These results support hypothesis 2, suggesting that competitors experience a decrease in their stock returns around the approval of a P.E.P. in the same industry. The results of our estimation also support hypothesis 3, which predicts negative returns for competitors around the announcement of the successful completion of P.E.P.s. This is confirmed by the fact that the C.A.A.R. of −0.14% reported for the (−5, 1) window is eventually increased to −0.32% and −0.43% in the (−5, 10) and (−10, 10) event windows, respectively. These values have lower negative values compared to the results associated with the application and approval, possibly reflecting the fact that the market has already discounted the effects of potential completion given the prior knowledge of the decision to grant approval. Descriptive data shows that the successful approval rate of Chinese P.E.P.s is ~ 83%. However, success in approval is not guaranteed for P.E. issuing companies obtaining much required capital from the P.E. market for their future investment projects. Hence, this information conveyed by P.E.P. decisions transfers to competitor firms within the same industry and they show a negative stock price reaction. However, uncertainty at the approval stage is lower compared to at the application stage; we observe that the less negative stock price reaction as competitor companies know what the P.E. market conditions are like in China.

In contrast, consistent with hypothesis 4, competitors’ returns increase around the withdrawal or rejection of the P.E.P. application by companies in the same industry. For the (−5, 1) event window, competitors generated a 0.77% C.A.A.R., which is statistically significant at the 1% confidence level and a C.A.A.R. of 0.59% for the (−5, 5) event window, which is also significant at the 10% level. The C.A.A.R. for longer window periods are not statistically significant. Furthermore, we observed that the rejection or withdrawal of P.E.P. applications leads to an upward adjustment of competitive companies’ stock price to the level at which they were at prior to the issuing companies’ P.E. application. According to Panel B of Table , P.E. issuing companies have positive market reactions to their application, approval and successful P.E.P. event completion announcements. Rejection and withdrawal of P.E.P. events are associated with a negative C.A.A.R., although the coefficients are not statistically significant.

Application, approval and successful completion of P.E.P.s are likely to be unwelcome news for competitor companies and such events are associated with negative returns for competitors. Competitor companies’ C.A.A.R.s are significantly negative for the periods around the application for P.E.P.s by their counterparts in the same industry than for the period around the approval and completion of P.E.P.s. These results suggest that competitor companies react strongly to the P.E.P. applications of their rivals, given that it is the first time information about potential P.E.P.s is known by the market participants. According to the C.S.R.C., one stated objective of P.E.P. administrative regulations is to minimise competition. However, the above analyses show that completion of P.E.P.s have a negative effect on stock returns of industry competitors in the short-term. These findings are consistent with the prior literature based on developed markets (Hsu et al., Citation2010, Citation2011).

The successful completion of P.E.P.s provide the issuing company with the funds to invest in new capital expenditure projects and they can, therefore, achieve better performance than their industry counterparts. The successful completion of P.E.P.s is a most important event which contains more information for investors’ reaction that might affect competitor firms’ stock price movements. To investigate whether the information transmission determinants of P.E.P. completion events affect the competitor companies’ stock price performance in the short-term, we incorporate average discounts, the log value of average P.E.P. proceeds and the number of P.E.P. events at industry levels as explanatory variables at the completion of the P.E.P. event and the regression results presented in Table . We include the number of P.E.P. events in the same industry and event window (−5, 5) in order to conduct a robustness test. The results show that a 1% increase in the PEP events leads to a 0.01% decrease in the competitor companies’ C.A.A.R. This result supports the argument that the P.E.P. events have a competitive effect on non-P.E.P. issuing companies in the same industry. The results also show that an average market discount at the industry level is negatively significant. A 1% increase in the average discount leads to a reduction in competitor companies’ short-term C.A.A.R. by 0.02%. The value of P.E.P. proceeds is also a statistically significant negative value, suggesting that an increase of 1% in the natural log value of average proceeds received from a P.E.P. leads to a decrease in the competitor companies’ C.A.A.R. by 0.01%. Further, these findings reveal that the information transmission of a P.E.P. negatively affects competitor companies’ stock price performance in the short-term. In addition, the market discount and the value of P.E.P. proceeds is the most important information that transfers to competitors companies from P.E. issuing companies.

Table 5. The information transmission effects of Private Equity Placements on Industry Competitors’ C.A.A.R.

5.2. Competitor companies’ long-term stock price performance

Table presents the correlation coefficients of the variables included in the regression analyses. Significant and negative correlations exist between P.E.P. events and stock returns/abnormal returns and between P.E.P. proceeds and stock returns/abnormal returns, while significant and positive correlations are reported between P.E. discounts and stock returns/abnormal returns of competitor companies, which provides some preliminary evidence for the relationship mentioned in hypotheses 5 and 6.

Table 6. Pearson correlation matrix of repressors.

We also attempt to explain the negative long-term market performance of competitor companies in the years in which P.E.P.s were completed by their industry rivals. This is accomplished by relating competitors’ annual returns or annual abnormal returns to a P.E.P. event dummy variable after controlling for the number of factors that are known to have impacted on the long-term stock price performance.Footnote4 The results are shown in Table . Models 1 and 3 show the relationship between the long-term stock returns and control variables. Consistent with hypothesis 6, a P.E.P. event is negatively related to competitors’ stock price performances. In particular, the estimates for Model 2 show a statistically significant 0.032% decrease in stock returns associated with the P.E.P. event. Similarly, estimates for Model 4 show a significant −0.03% decrease in abnormal stock returns associated with the P.E.P. event. According to the Table in Appendix A, a P.E.P. event has a positive effect on annual stock and abnormal stock returns of P.E. issuing companies.Footnote5 The significant coefficients, outlined above, generated in our estimation confirm that P.E.P. events have a competitive effect on the share prices of intra-industry counterparts.

Table 7. The effects of information transmission of successfully completed P.E.P. events on industry competitors’ long-term return.

Based on Wruck (Citation1989) and Hertzel and Smith (Citation1993), we argue that discounts and proceeds from P.E.P.s measure information effects and that stock price effects are based on the implication that the information effects are larger for placements where the potential degree of under-valuation is high. The discounts and proceeds from P.E.P.s at industry level transmit to the investors, competitors and other stakeholders in the market who react on this information. To strengthen our argument, we also assess whether the size of the P.E.P. event, as measured by the average value of P.E.P. events in a given year, is related to competitors’ long-term stock price performance. The results provided in Table show that the value of P.E.P.s is significantly negatively related to competitor companies’ stock returns and abnormal returns. In particular, stock returns and abnormal stock returns show a significant 0.01% and 0.006% decrease associated with the average value of P.E.P.s at the industry level. A P.E.P. discount at the industry level is significantly positive and stock returns and abnormal stock returns show a significant 0.05% and 0.014% increase associated with the P.E.P. discount at industry level.

Table 8. The effects of detailed information transmission of successfully completed P.E.P. events on industry competitors’ long-term return.

Furthermore, our results show that the C.S.R.C.’s announcement of P.E.P. arrangements generates a spillover effect on the stock returns of industry competitors in China. In general, this information transmission effect of P.E.P. announcements can be categorised into contagion and competitive effects. As revealed in our results, the information in a P.E.P. announcement changes the original competitive situation and leads to the short-term wealth redistribution of competitor companies in the same industry. Thus, we confirm that P.E.P. announcements have competitive effects in the short-term. The results of also show that P.E.P. events are negatively correlated with stock returns in the long-term, while suggesting the presence of competitive effects that are driven by the negative association between the stock return of the issuing firms and its industry competitors.

Table 9. The information effects of successfully completed P.E.P. on .P.E.P issuing firms in long-term returns.

6. Conclusions

Private placements are becoming a popular means of secondary equity offering among companies operating across different international capital markets, regardless of the stage of development of the market. This paper provides empirical evidence of the effect of P.E.P.s on competitors’ stock price using data from the highly transitional and regulated Chinese market. We find that competitors experience a decrease in stock prices in response to the announcements of application, approval and completion of P.E.P. events and an increase in stock prices around the announcements of withdrawal or rejection of P.E.P. events. Further, competitors experience a decrease in their long-term stock performance following P.E.P. events, suggesting the existence of a competitive effect both in the short- and the long-term. Hence, the outcome of our analysis confirms that information associated with a P.E.P. announcement changes the original competitive situation and leads to the short- and long-term wealth redistribution of competitor companies within the same industry. Moreover, the short-term effect of discounts on P.E.P.s on a competitor company’s C.A.A.R. is negative. However, the short-term effect of discounts on P.E.P.s positively affects the long-term stock returns and abnormal stock returns of competitor companies. Chinese companies place P.E. at a higher discount than U.S. companies (Fonseka et al., Citation2014; Lu et al., Citation2011 Citation). In the context of information spillover, the competitive effect dominates the contagion effect. Offering higher discounts on P.E.P.s assists issuing companies to raise the required amount of funds for their potential investment projects in the short-term. In addition, industry level discounts also have a positive impact on the stock price performance of their industry counterparts in the long-term.

Disclosure statement

No potential conflict of interest was reported by the authors.

Funding

This research was mainly supported by the China Postdoctoral Foundation [grant number 2016M602786] and the Natural Science Foundation of China [grant number 71372163].

Disclosure statement

No potential conflict of interest was reported by the authors.

Notes

* The authors wish to thank the participants at the Seminars on Accounting and Finance at Xi’an Jiaotong University, Xi’an International Studies University, 20th ‘SFM conference’ in Taiwan, 11th ‘International Symposium on Empirical Accounting Research in China’ in Beijing, ‘American Accounting Association Annual Meeting’ in August 2013, Anaheim, CA, and the ‘Accounting and Finance Association of Australia and New Zealand’ Conference in July 2014, Auckland, New Zealand for their comments and insights on earlier versions of the paper.

1. The total dollar amount of private equity investments in public listed firms increased from $2 billion to $88 billion in the period 1995–2006, whereas the total dollar amount of S.E.O.s in 2006 was $76 billion.

2. In the U.S., P.E.P.s reflect minority ownership stakes in target firms unless they represent a full buyout. On the other hand, average Chinese P.E.P.s are relatively larger and regulations on private equity (P.E.) attract large institutional buyers (see Section 2). Hence, we were compelled to restrict our analysis to placements by issuing firms and their spillover effects on competitor firms.

3. According to C.S.R.C. regulation, a company that obtained approval should complete the P.E.P. within 6 months. On average, sample companies took 2 months to complete their P.E.P.s. Hence, application, approval/rejection announcement events were not contaminated (clustered) by time (event windows).

4. Correlation matrix and VIF factors suggested that there is no multicollinearity problem.

5. P.E. issuing firm-year observations and their corresponding non-P.E. issuing observations were selected for P.E.P. firms. We created dummy variable for measuring P.E.P. events (if a firm has issued P.E. the variable is 1 and if the firm did not issue P.E. for the rest of the period that is indicated as 0).

References

  • Abidin, S., Reddy, K., & Chen, L. (2012). Determinants of ownership structure and performance of seasoned equity offerings. International Journal of Managerial Finance, 8(4), 304–331.10.1108/17439131211261242
  • Akhigbe, A., Borde, S. F., & Whyte, A. M. (2003). Does an industry effect exist for initial public offerings? The Financial Review, 38(4), 531–551.10.1111/fire.2003.38.issue-4
  • Ang, A., & Bekaert, G. (2007). Stock return predictability: Is it there? Review of Financial Studies, 20, 651–707.10.1093/rfs/hhl021
  • Besley, T., & Prat, A. (2006). Handcuffs for the grabbing hand? Media capture and government accountability. American Economic Review, 96(3), 720–736.10.1257/aer.96.3.720
  • Bo, H., Huang, Z., & Wang, C. (2011). Understanding seasoned equity offerings of Chinese firms. Journal of Banking & Finance, 35(5), 1143–1157.10.1016/j.jbankfin.2010.09.025
  • Brooks, L. D., & Graham, J. E. (2005). Equity Private Placements, Liquid Assets and Firm Value. Journal of Economics and Finance, 29(3), 320–336.
  • Brown, S. J., & Warner, J. B. (1985). Using daily stock returns: The case of event studies. Journal of Finance, 14(1), 3–31.
  • Chan, K. S., Dang, V. Q. T., & Yan, I. K. M. (2012). Effects of financial liberalization and political connections on listed Chinese firms’ financing constrains. The World Economy. doi:10.1111/j.1467-9701.2012.01447.x
  • Chen, H.-C., Dai, N., & Schatzberg, J. D. (2010). The choice of equity selling mechanisms: PIPEs versus SEOs. Journal of Corporate Finance, 16(1), 104–119.10.1016/j.jcorpfin.2009.08.003
  • Chen, L. (2009). On the reversal of return and dividend growth predictability: A tale of two periods. Journal of Financial Economics, 92, 128–151.10.1016/j.jfineco.2008.04.004
  • Chen, L., Da, Z., & Priestley, R. (2012). Dividend smoothing and predictability. Management Science, 58, 1834–1853.10.1287/mnsc.1120.1528
  • Chen, S. (2015). Seasoned equity offerings or capital deductions? The reaction of stock prices: Evidence from Taiwan, emerging markets finance and trade. doi:10.1080/1540496X.2015.109799
  • Chung, J., & Hwang, J. H. (2010). Pricing of Private Placements of Equity. Asia-Pacific Journal of Financial Studies, 39(1), 90–107.10.1111/ajfs.2010.39.issue-1
  • Cumming, D., Siegel, D. S., & Wright, M. (2007). Private equity, leveraged buyout and governance. Journal of Corporate Finance, 13(4), 439–460.10.1016/j.jcorpfin.2007.04.008
  • Desir, R. (2012). How do managers of non-announcing firms respond to intra-industry information transfers. Journal of Business Finance & Accounting. doi:10.1111/j.1468-5957.2012.02306.x
  • Erwin, G. R., & Miller, J. M. (1998). The intra-industry effects of open market share repurchases: Contagion or competitive? Journal of Financial Research, 21(4), 389–406.10.1111/jfir.1998.21.issue-4
  • Fama, E. F., & French, K. R. (1993). Common risk factors in the returns on stocks and bonds. Journal of Financial Economics, 33(1), 3–56.10.1016/0304-405X(93)90023-5
  • Firth, M., Lin, C., & Zou, H. (2010). Friend or Foe? The role of state and mutual fund ownership in the split share structure reform in China. Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis, 45, 685–706.10.1017/S0022109010000190
  • Fonseka, M. M., Colombage, S. R. N., & Tian, G.-L. (2014). Effects of regulator's announcements, information asymmetry and ownership changes on private equity placements: Evidence from China. Journal of International Financial Markets, Institutions and Money, 29(1), 126–149.10.1016/j.intfin.2013.11.008
  • Goh, J., Gombola, M. J., Lee, H. W., & Liu, F. (1999). Private placement of common equity and earnings expectations. The Financial Review, 34(3), 19–32.10.1111/fire.1999.34.issue-3
  • Gou, S., Hotchkiss, E. S., & Song, W. (2011). Do buyouts (still) create value? Journal of Finance, 66(2), 479–517.
  • Hertzel, M., Lemmon, M., Linck, J., & Rees, L. (2002). Long-run performance following private placements of equity. Journal of Finance, 57(6), 2597–2616.
  • Hertzel, M., & Rees, L. (1998). Earnings and risk changes around private placements of equity. Journal of Accounting, Auditing & Finance, 13, 21–35.10.1177/0148558X9801300102
  • Hertzel, M., & Smith, R. L. (1993). Market discount and shareholder gains for placing equity privately. The Journal of Finance, 48(2), 459–485.10.1111/j.1540-6261.1993.tb04723.x
  • Hou, W., Kuo, J.-M., & Lee, E. (2012). The impact of state ownership on share price informativeness: The case of the Split Share Structure Reform in China. The British Accounting Review, 44, 248–261.10.1016/j.bar.2012.09.003
  • Hsu, H., Reed, A. V., & Rocholl, J. (2010). The new game in Town: Competitive effects of IPOs. Journal of Finance, 65(2), 495–528.10.1111/j.1540-6261.2009.01542.x
  • Hsu, H., Reed, A. V., & Rocholl, J. (2011, June 1–8). Competitive effects of private equity. American Finance Association Annual Meeting 2012, Chicago, IL.
  • Krasker, W. S. (1986). Stock price movements in response to stock issues under asymmetric information. The Journal of Finance, 41(1), 93–105.10.1111/j.1540-6261.1986.tb04493.x
  • Larrain, B., & Yogo, M. (2008). Does firm value move too much to be justified by subsequent changes in cash flow? Journal of Financial Economics, 87, 200–226.10.1016/j.jfineco.2007.01.002
  • Lu, D., Li, S., & Wu, W. (2011). Market discounts and announcement effects of private placements: Evidence from China. Applied Economics Letters, 18(15), 1411–1414.10.1080/13504851.2010.539531
  • Merton, R. C. (1987). A simple model of capital market equilibrium with incomplete information. The Journal of Finance, 42(3), 483–510.10.1111/j.1540-6261.1987.tb04565.x
  • Pistor, K., & Xu, C. (2005). Governing stock market in transition economics: Lesions from China. American Law and Economics Review, 7, 184–210.10.1093/aler/ahi008
  • Powell, J. G., Qian, M., & Shi, J. (2013). The Chinese cash and stock dividend puzzles: Evidence from Joint earning announcements (Working Paper). Financial Management Forum, International Institute for Financial Studies. Retrieved March 15, 2014, from http://iifs.jxufe.cn
  • Qian, Y. Y., Roland, G., & Xu, C. G. (1999). Why is China different from Eastern Europe? Perspectives from organization theory. European Economic Review, 43(4–6), 1085–1094.10.1016/S0014-2921(98)00116-0
  • Shao, Z., & Lin, Y. (2004). A Study on Dividend Policy of Listed Firms. Market Weekly, 3, 45–47.
  • Slovin, M. B., Sushka, M. E., & Polonchek, J. A. (1992). Informational externalities of seasoned equity issues: Differences between banks and industrial firms. Journal of Financial Economics, 32(1), 87–101.10.1016/0304-405X(92)90026-T
  • Sun, Q., & Tong, W. H. S. (2003). China share issue privatization: The extent of its success. Journal of Financial Economics, 70(2), 183–222.10.1016/S0304-405X(03)00145-4
  • Szewczyk, S. H. (1992). The Intra-Industry Transfer of Information Inferred from Announcements of Corporate Security Offerings. Journal of Finance, 47(5), 1935–1945.10.1111/j.1540-6261.1992.tb04689.x
  • Tsai, B. H. (2008). Rights issues in China as evidence for the existence of two types of agency problems. Issues & Studies, 44(3), 43–70.
  • Wei, G., & Jiang, Y. (2001). A Survey on Dividend Policy in China. Economics Science, 12(1), 79–87.
  • Wruck, K. (1989). Equity ownership concentration and firm value: Evidence from private equity financing. Journal of Financial Economics, 23(1), 3–28.10.1016/0304-405X(89)90003-2
  • Wruck, K. H., & Wu, Y. (2009). Relationships, Corporate governance, and performance: Evidence from private financings. Journal of Corporate Finance, 15(1), 30–47.10.1016/j.jcorpfin.2008.08.010
  • Wu, J., & Cheng, M. L. (2011). The impact of managerial political connection and quality on government subsidies. Chinese Management Studies, 5(2), 207–226.10.1108/17506141111142834
  • Yu, J., & Xu, B. (2010). The dissimilation of announcement effects of private placement between bull and bear markets: An empirical research in Chinese stock market. IEEE, 2, 558–562.
  • Zou, H., & Xiao, J. Z. (2006). The financing behaviour of listed Chinese firms. The British Accounting Review, 38(3), 239–258.10.1016/j.bar.2006.04.008

Appendix A:

Effects of successfully completed P.E. event on P.E. issuing firms in long-term returns.

Notes: Robust standard errors clustered with industries and time are in parentheses. R.E.T. and A.R. are annual stock returns and abnormal stock returns, respectively, and used as dependent variables. Age represents the log value of number of operating years from establishment. Size is measured by the log of the total assets. L.E.V. is financial leverage and measured by the ratio of interest bearing liability to equity in each firm at the beginning of the year. F.D. is financial distress and calculated by Altman Z-score. B.E.T.A. is the systematic market risk at the beginning of the year and it is calculated using past 36 months of daily returns. R.O.A. is return on assets at the beginning of the year. M.B.V. is Market to book value ratio at the beginning of the year. O.W.N. is ownership and is a dummy variable; 1 if controlling shareholder is State and 0 otherwise. P.E.P._E1 is Private Equity Placement (P.E.P.) event; if a firm has issued P.E. it is 1 and if the firm did not issue P.E. for the rest of the period it is 0.

*** Significance at 1%.

** Significance at 5%.

* Significance at 10%.