4,554
Views
15
CrossRef citations to date
0
Altmetric
Research Article

Aging and economic growth: is there a role for a two-child policy in China?

Pages 438-455 | Received 29 May 2019, Accepted 25 Nov 2019, Published online: 02 Mar 2020

Abstract

The current study seeks to determine the type of population policy China should implement to effectively promote economic growth, especially in the context of its aging population. Using multiagent simulation technology, I integrate the two-child policy into a complex model featuring population, resources, and economic growth. My simulation results indicate that under the constraining effect of aging on economic growth, the implementation of a two-child policy alone could promote economic growth, albeit in a limited fashion: it would be more economically advantageous to combine a two-child policy with policy that promotes human capital growth. These findings provide new evidence regarding the relationship between population aging and economic growth. It is insufficient to emphasize only a liberalization of birth restrictions and promote population growth: rather, a combination of various policies would be more successful. A cluster of policies that aim to increase both fertility and investment in human capital can effectively curb economic recession otherwise caused by an aging population, and such a policy cluster could concurrently increase the supply of new labor and improve skills that appreciate with age.

JEL CLASSIFICATIONS:

1. Introduction

In recent years, there has been a surge of interest among researchers in the relationship between population aging and economic growth. Various studies have shown that population aging can slow economic growth (Peng, Citation2005), and that a shrinkage in the proportion of the young, working-age population can lower the overall labor force participation rate. However, some studies indicate that population aging does not necessarily delay economic growth (Fougère et al., Citation2009). Ultimately, the threat of an aging population tends to be overstated: it is frequently exaggerated by media and too often based on partial analysis (Herrmann, Citation2012).

China is a country with a large population, and so its population-aging trend is not unexpected. As of 2014, 15.53% and 10.06% of the population had reached the ages of 60 and 65, respectively. Additionally, the growth rate of China’s working-age population has declined, and the absolute quantity of working age adults began to attenuate in 2015, resulting in a structural labor shortage (Fang & Wang, Citation2006). At the same time, China faces the pressures that come with economic development.

Therefore, to alleviate the problems that tend to accompany population aging, China brought to an end its one-child policy, which had been firmly enforced for over 30 years. In 2013, China put forward a selective two-child policy that specified that if either the husband or the wife had come from a single-child family, they could have a second child. Three years later, in 2016, another policy change allowed all couples to have a second child (i.e., a universal two-child policy) (Zeng, Zhang, & Liu, Citation2017). Since the implementation of the two-child policy, China’s birth rate has increased (Zhai, Zhang, & Jin, Citation2014). While some studies believe that China’s two-child policy can effectively promote the country’s economic growth, still others believe the two-child policy can play only a limited role in this area (Li, Citation2016).

Can China’s two-child policy effectively promote economic growth there? More specifically, can its two-child policy effectively constrain the adverse effects that population aging can otherwise impose on economic growth? Indeed, research on these issues can inform the creation of effective population policies and promote economic growth. The current study makes two significant contributions, as follows. (1) For analytical purposes, this study uses multiagent modeling and simulation methods and incorporates aging, economic growth, and two-child policies into a simulation system. (2) By setting various policy portfolio scenarios, I determine the optimal policy portfolio (i.e., that which best addresses population aging so as to promote economic growth in China).

The remainder of this paper is organized as follows. Section 2 provides a literature review, and Section 3 introduces the methodology used herein, including the simulation model and data used. Section 4 reports the simulation results. Section 5 concludes with regard to the research findings and outlines policy implications.

2. Literature review

There has been extensive research on the relationship between population aging and economic growth. To undertake such research while using multiagent modeling and computer simulation methods, I first need to define the term “economic growth.” From there, the impact of population aging on economic growth can be analyzed from two perspectives. Finally, I can develop my own research method by analyzing those used in previous studies.

2.1. Economic growth and its influencing factors

There is no fixed definition for “economic growth.” At the national level, it is generally defined in terms of continuous growth in gross domestic product (GDP) (Neuenkirch & Neumeier, Citation2015). However, some studies have shown that use of the GDP measure has its drawbacks: it does not, for example, consider environmental pollution or degradation (Hu, Citation2000). Some studies instead propose a “green GDP” measure (Talberth & Bohara, Citation2006). In any case, GDP continues to be the most widely used measure of economic growth (Camba-Mendez, Kapetanios, Smith, & Weale, Citation2001), and it is used in the current study.

Many studies focus on the factors that affect economic growth, and there is no overarching consensus among them. The theory of endogenous growth asserts that an economy can drive sustained growth without relying on external forces; according to that theory, endogenous technological progress is the determining factor that ensures sustained economic growth (Adak, Citation2015; Freire, Citation2019). The Solow growth model (Durlauf, Kourtellos, & Minkin, Citation2001) and the exogenous economic growth model have been put forward, and various factors thought to affect economic growth include capital (Hendrickson, Salter, & Albrecht, Citation2018), labor (Auzina-Emsina, Citation2014), the savings rate (Uddin, Alam, & Gow, Citation2016), the population growth rate (Bucci & Moritz Müller, Citation2018), and the technological progress rate (Alani, Citation2012).

In terms of policies that promote economic growth, I propose that technological innovation be encouraged and human capital increased. The term “human capital” refers to the capital embodied in a laborer (Pelinescu, Citation2015), including work skills, technical level, and health status (Ogundari & Awokuse, Citation2018). Nationally, achieving a higher level of human capital can promote innovation (Lenihan, McGuirk, & Murphy, Citation2019), improve technical level, promote effective resource allocation (Zallé, Citation2019), and ultimately support economic growth (Chen & Fang, Citation2018).

2.2. The impact of population aging on economic growth

The literature indicates that population aging can adversely affect a country’s economic growth. In an emerging economy, lagging annual growth in the aging index and in the old age dependency ratio can curtail growth (Aurora, Renuga Nagarajan, & Silva, Citation2017). Bloom and Finlay (Citation2009), for example, highlight the need in east Asia for policy that offsets the potentially negative effects of an aging population.

On the other hand, other studies suggest that population aging does not necessarily delay economic growth, and that it is influenced by several factors. For example, according to Li, Li, and Chan (Citation2012), China’s demographic structure is in a transitional phase, in which economic growth is fostered by increasing savings and investment rates among its aging population. Population aging fosters long-term growth in an endogenous growth framework; however, its effect depends on changes in both fertility and mortality (Prettner, Citation2013). Irmen (Citation2017) indicates that an economy’s steady‐state growth rate becomes independent of its age structure, and that neither a higher life expectancy nor a decline in fertility affects economic growth in the long term. The assumptions behind that conclusion are rational capital planning and labor-saving technical change. Similarly, Hsu, Liao, and Zhao (Citation2018) found that aging does not necessarily adversely affect growth in China. Nicole and Beer (Citation2015) believe that in Europe, the Europe 2020 employment targets can suffice in compensating for the demographic burden imposed by population aging. A higher level of life expectancy increases among both young people and adults the incentive to innovate (Lancia & Prarolo, Citation2012). Thus, population aging leads to industry specialization, which in turn intensively leverages age-appreciating skills and erodes the comparative advantage of industries for which age-depreciating skills are more important (Cai & Stoyanov, Citation2016).

2.3. Existing research methods

The literature leverages a variety of research methods, including the three-period overlapping generation model (Lancia & Prarolo, Citation2012; Choi & Shin, Citation2015), and Prettner (2013) incorporates endogenous growth models and semi-endogenous growth models. Other methods found in the literature include a computable general equilibrium model (Peng, Citation2008), a life-cycle model (Kolasa & Rubaszek, Citation2015), and a general equilibrium overlapping generations model (Hsu et al., Citation2018). However, Brucker (Citation2008) indicates that traditional old-age dependency ratios can be misleading, as they do not account for differences in labor force participation rates.

Indeed, a literature review offers no consensus regarding the effect of aging on national economic growth. Multiple factors intertwine with aging and play a role in economic growth, be it positive or negative. In terms of research methods, many studies within the literature use a quantitative analysis model; many also use computer simulation. Nonetheless, no research to date employs multiagent modeling and simulation technology and systematically integrates the two-child policy, aging, and economic growth. The current study fills this gap in the literature by exploring these topics.

3. Methods

3.1. Why use a complex, multiagent model?

Several economics researchers have used an agent-based model (Gibson & Setterfield, Citation2015) in what is most commonly referred to as “agent-based computational economics” research. This model is based on complex adaptive system theory and integrates computer simulation technology to simulate the behavior of multiple heterogeneous agents. When undertaking dynamic simulation, the researcher can observe the behavior rules of various subjects. This model does not rely on traditional mathematical equations and econometric models; instead, it leverages computer programming to study nonlinear and heterogeneous economic agents (Carrão & WikAtique, Citation2019). For this reason, this model allows one to analyze nonlinear relationships, and this is especially useful; moreover, it is possible to introduce into the system a variety of influencing factors, as variables.

As the behavior of an agent evolves, the value of a variable can change. In this way, a researcher can identify the key variables that drive the evolution process (Liu, Citation2017). This is especially important for policymakers, as it is difficult to institute a given socioeconomic policy while conducting what are essentially real-world experiments: especially when policies can have deleterious effects, such experiments are ethically impossible. However, the use of multiagent modeling and a simulation platform can compensate for this shortcoming. Using these tools, one can undertake policy experiments and present the results as three-dimensional visualizations. As such, by using different policy scenarios, policymakers can clearly see the effects of the implementation of a given policy. In this way, the use of this method can help lay the foundation for the implementation of effective policies. In fact, the model has already been effectively applied to policy formulation in various fields, and achieved positive results (Drakaki, Gören, & Tzionas, Citation2018; Gao et al., Citation2018).

This study builds a multiagent simulation system that considers population, the two-child policy, resources, and economic growth. By making full use of multiagent modeling, one can simulate the characteristics of a large number of agents and bring population policy and economic growth into the system at the same time, with the endpoint of effectively analyzing the consequences of the two-child policy with respect to economic growth.

3.2. Conceptual model

The conceptual model serves as the foundation of the simulation model. The conceptual model is based mainly on the existing theoretical and empirical research, but is also informed by original author contributions.

Land and other resources are essential to human survival. Humans use their work-related skills to develop resources such as land and earn income to satisfy their own consumption needs (Zallé, Citation2019). If there is a surplus, it can accumulate as wealth (i.e., GDP). As mentioned, at the national level, an increase in GDP connotes economic growth (Camba-Mendez et al., Citation2001). Meanwhile, fertility is achieved at the childbearing age, and reproductive behavior is affected by government policies, such as family-planning policies and the two-child policy (Liu & Liu, Citation2018). In the conceptual model, the population is differentiated by age (f (α)) and comprises the young-age population (Yage), the working-age population (Wage), and the old-age population (Oage). (1) f(α)=Yage, <18Wage, 1865Oage, >65(1)

When an agent reaches the maximum life expectancy (θ), the agent exits and dies (f(x)). When no resources are available for consumption (income = I ≤ 0), the agent will die out. (2) f(x)=0,f (a)>θ or I 0(2)

The land resource system provides survival resources for use by the population system. Here, land is classified as “abundant land” or “nonabundant land” (Wu, Wang, Xu, Tan, & Zhang, Citation1995). Abundant land” refers to that which offers high-level economic benefits and generates no pollution during crop production and unit area utilization. Any land lacking in these characteristics is considered nonabundant (Shen et al., Citation2012). Based on these studies, I designed a variable (percent-abundant-land) that reflects the amount of abundant land.

Thanks to technological advances, nonabundant land can be transformed into abundant land (Kong, Zhang, Xu, & Qi, Citation2004). Additionally, an increase in human capital investment can enhance human working skills (Onkelinx, Manolova, & Edelman, Citation2016). In these ways, more survival-essential resources can be obtained and more wealth created. Changes in human capital are influenced by human capital policy (Yoon, Citation2006; Haini, Citation2019; Siddiqui & Rehman, Citation2016). To effectively simulate the impact of a two-child policy on economic growth, it is necessary to introduce a number of variables that effectively link the relationships among various agents and subsystems. The effects of the policy are analyzed in the system. The design of these variables is based on the literature, but also on original author contributions. For example, according to the definition of “human capital” in the Section 2, the following variables are set in the model to measure human capital policy: working-skills refers to agents’ work-related abilities and skills, and resource-growth technology refers to technology that promotes resource growth (see and ).

Figure 1. Framework of the conceptual model. Source: The author’s design and calculation results.

Figure 1. Framework of the conceptual model. Source: The author’s design and calculation results.

Table 1. Main variables: descriptions and sources.

3.3. Simulation model

The simulation model is based on the conceptual model, and I use the NetLogo simulation platform. NetLogo is a programming platform that at once inherits the Logo language and improves upon the Logo language’s shortfalls. In modeling it can control tens of thousands of agents; therefore, NetLogo modeling can simulate the behavior of micro-level individuals and the emergence of macro-level models, as well as the relationships between them. Moreover, NetLogo is a platform used with success to simulate natural and social phenomena—especially those involving complex systems—over time.

The simulation platform is divided into three parts. The left part controls the system variables, and sliding blocks were designed for it. One can design various policy scenarios by controlling these variables. The middle part is a statistical display of the simulation results. Finally, the right part is the three-dimensional display of the simulation results. As the simulation time increases, simulation data are produced and maintained, and ultimately used in quantitative analysis.

3.4. Initialization and input data

Initialization of the simulation model requires the assignment of variables. Certain initial values are based on China’s real-world conditions. For example, the value of China’s number-people (population, expressed in tens of millions) as of 2016 is 138.3. Other variables are similarly based on research results. Meanwhile, to analyze trends under various experimental scenarios, I manually controlled for the effects of some important variables; one such variable is max-resources, which can assume different grade values. By enacting these levels of change in various experimental scenarios, one can observe the related impact. Some grade variables have no units; the main concern is the change in numerical level (Akl, Sarker, & Essam, Citation2019; Schweiger et al., Citation2019) for example the wealth (GDP) (see ).

Table 2. Main variables: overview of baseline data.

3.5. Comparative simulation

To analyze the effect of the two-child policy on economic growth in the context of an aging population in China, I designed three policy scenarios. Before the comprehensive two-child policy was implemented, only a select population was allowed to have two children (SimBT1). This policy scenario, as the benchmark, was compared to the other two scenarios.

The second policy scenario features the aging of China’s population (i.e., increasing the life-expectancy-max variable). A fully liberalized two-child policy would increase the number of births, which would in turn increase the value of number-population (SimAT1). The third policy scenario also assumes an aging population and a fully liberalized two-child policy, but additionally assumes increased investment in human capital and technology, thus increasing the value of certain relevant variables (e.g., max-working-skills and resource-growth-technology [SimAT2]), as shows.

Table 3. Parameters of the different simulation scenarios.

3.6. Model validation and robustness

There is no generally accepted method by which to assess the validity and robustness of agent-based models (Balci, Citation1998). However, the approach used is considered one of model verification and validation, and use of this approach is supported by the literature. Additionally, the use of multiple data sources improved the validity of the model (e.g., determined whether the conceptual model was a reasonably accurate representation of real-world conditions) (Law & Kelton, Citation1991).

Furthermore, the removal of errors from the simulation program helped preclude the incorrect application of the conceptual model, and thus guaranteed the model’s validity and robustness. I used an iterative process that adjusts poorly characterized experimental variables, to accommodate extreme conditions and sensitivity. The calibration process improved the goodness of fit between the model and the data. Through these tests, I pinpointed those changes within the model’s dynamic evolving patterns that stemmed from changes in the values of certain parameters. Therefore, based on the simulation results, the results of the effect of the two-child policy on economic growth can be deemed acceptable.

4. Results and discussion

4.1. Descriptive statistics of results

presents the results of the three simulation scenarios (SimBT1, SimAT1 and SimAT2). The third simulation scenario yields a minimum GDP of 2677.00, which is greater than that obtained with either of the other two simulation scenarios (2371.00 and 2481.00); it also yields a maximum GDP of 6236.00, which is greater than that obtained from the other two (3707.00 and 4043.00). The third simulation also exhibits the largest mean GDP.

Table 4. Statistical analysis of the description of three simulation scenarios.

The results of these three simulation scenarios are statistically significant. As shows, there are significant differences between SimBT1 and SimAT1 (T= –3.93; p = 0.00). There are also statistically significant differences between SimAT1 and SimAT2 (T=–11.41; p = 0.00).

4.2. SimBT1 and SimAT1

The simulation results indicate that under a population-aging trend, the implementation of the two-child policy in China is conducive to promoting economic growth. shows that, in the simulation period, economic growth would be significantly lower in the absence of the two-child policy than it would be in its presence. Statistical analysis of the simulation data under the two scenarios uncovers significant differences between the two (T = –3.93; Sig. (two-tailed) p = 0.00).

Figure 2. Simulation results before and after implementation of the two-child policy. Source: The author’s design and calculation results.

Figure 2. Simulation results before and after implementation of the two-child policy. Source: The author’s design and calculation results.

Since the implementation of the two-child policy, the number of births in China has increased; various studies also reach this conclusion (Zeng & Hesketh, Citation2016). Although the rate of population growth is lower than expected, China’s birth rate has indeed increased (Liu & Liu, Citation2018). This addition to the population can ease the population-aging trend and eventually become a new part of the labor force. To a certain extent, the policy promoted economic growth during the simulation period; however, had the two-child policy not been implemented in China, the one-child policy would have prevailed—and under that policy, the model shows that over the simulation period, economic growth in China would have slowed. Clearly, in the absence of the two-child policy, China’s outlook vis-à-vis economic growth would not have been favorable.

China’s population-aging trend has been aggravating economic growth, thus affecting the sustainability of the country’s economic development. As seen in the literature findings, population aging has a negative impact on many aspects of national health, including economic growth (Chomik, McDonald, & Piggott, Citation2016; Lee & Shin, Citation2019). In particular, labor-intensive industries continue to play an important role in China’s economic development (Wei, Citation2017), and shortfalls in new labor have constrained development in these industries. On the other hand, elderly individuals are now more becoming increasingly older and hence prone to physical discomfort and serious illness; these changes result in increases in personal medical and nursing expenses and reduced savings. As such, the aging of a population will constrain the overall savings rate, and such a constraint will reduce savings funds, directly reduce the scale of investment, and reduce the national economic growth rate (Gao & Zhang, Citation2018).

4.3. SimAT1 and SimAT2

The simulation results also indicate that the combination of the two-child policy and increased human capital investment will bring about better economic growth. According to , compared to the implementation of the two-child policy alone, the two-child policy in conjunction with a human capital policy will work better to promote economic development. In statistically analyzing the simulation data under the two scenarios, significant differences between them become apparent (T=–11.41; Sig.(two-tailed) p = 0.00).

Figure 3. Simulation results of the two-child policy and human capital policy. Source: The author’s design and calculation results.

Figure 3. Simulation results of the two-child policy and human capital policy. Source: The author’s design and calculation results.

The direct effect of the two-child policy is an increase in the quantity of people; however, human capital policy promotes economic growth from the perspective of population quality. Especially in the context of population aging, the effect of human capital policy becomes more prominent. The findings in the literature support this conclusion (Bowlus, Mori, & Robinson, Citation2016). Population aging creates more opportunities for young individuals to invest in human capital and supply more skilled labor in middle age (Fougère et al., Citation2009). Consequently, the reduced young-adult labor supply initially lowers economic growth and exacerbates the economic costs of aging, but current (future) middle-aged cohorts are (will be) more skilled and work for a longer time; these conditions will eventually improve economic growth and lower the cost of population aging. Furthermore, with the accelerated development of the aging population, a new “aging products” market will be created that will increase the demand for equipment, raw materials, and intermediate products, and promote physical capital investment. The literature cites similar views (Magalhães, Stevens, & Thornton, Citation2017).

5. Conclusions and recommendations

5.1. Conclusions

The current study uses multiagent modeling and simulation technology to simulate the effect of China’s two-child policy on that country’s economic growth, in the context of its aging population. I built a multiagent simulation model involving population, resources, and technology, and constructed different policy scenarios. My simulation results show that China’s implementation of the two-child policy can increase its labor supply, relative to non-implementation. Furthermore, the policy promotes economic growth and, to a certain extent, alleviates the population-aging trend. The simulation results also show that the in-tandem implementation of the two-child policy and human capital policies will be more conducive to economic growth than the two-child policy alone.

5.2. Recommendations

These conclusions have important reference value in promoting economic development in the context of population aging. This trend is especially obvious in China; at the same time, the country faces environmental pollution and socioeconomic transformation. Despite the increase in the number of births after implementing the two-child policy, the expected effect on aging was not found to be significant. The main reason for this is the current decline in the desire to have children. This attenuation relates in part to deficiencies in social security, which increase child maintenance costs. Therefore, a feasible policy would be to incentivize giving birth (e.g., offering more paid maternity/paternity leave, better kindergarten services, and a maternity/paternity allowance).

The simulation results also show the positive role of increasing human capital investment in the context of population aging. Therefore, rather than solely institute a two-child policy, it is more important to implement a human capital policy, increase human capital investment, and promote improvements in population quality. The main policies relating to such investments attach importance to worker training, so as to enhance their skill base and improve the overall worker knowledge system. Improving the basic education level of the entire population should also be a goal: by increasing education expenditures, the human capital stock of the whole society can be increased.

However, there are two outstanding issues worth noting—namely, the number of children and human capital accumulation. The literature shows that at the micro level, an increase in the number of children can preclude human capital accumulation, as having extra children compels a household to reduce the per-child investment it makes in education (Van & Bovenberg, Citation1997; Raurich & Seegmuller, Citation2019). To counter this reduction in human capital accumulation, steps need to be taken in addition to the two-child policy (and its attendant increase in the per-family number of children). In addition to the aforementioned improvements to social security and child maintenance costs, there is a need to increase policies that promote macro-level human capital accumulation.

This study, like any study, has some limitations. Not all the factors that can affect economic growth are included in the simulation system used herein. Additionally, there persists a certain gap between the simulation framework and real-world conditions. Nonetheless, this explorative study does provide context and serve as a starting point for further investigation, and will support future studies in population aging and economic growth.

Disclosure statement

No potential conflict of interest was reported by the author.

Additional information

Funding

This work was supported by the Fundamental Research Funds for the Central Universities (YJ201855).

Notes on contributors

Yong Liu

Professor Yong Liu conducts research in the areas of economics and public policy. His research focuses on economic growth and policy. His work has been sponsored by the National Science Foundation of China, Chinese Academics of Science, and UCI, and has resulted in publications in Journal of Economic Issues, Energy Policy, and Science of the Total Environment, etc.

References

  • Adak, M. (2015). Technological progress, innovation and economic growth; the case of Turkey. Procedia - Social and Behavioral Sciences, 195(3), 776–782. doi:10.1016/j.sbspro.2015.06.478
  • Akl, A. M., Sarker, R. A., & Essam, D. L. (2019). Adaptive simulation budget allocation in simulation assisted differential evolution algorithm. Applied Soft Computing, 83, 105678. doi:10.1016/j.asoc.2019.105678
  • Alani, J. (2012). Effects of technological progress and productivity on economic growth in Uganda. Procedia Economics and Finance, 1, 14–23. doi:10.1016/S2212-5671(12)00004-4
  • Aurora, A. C., Renuga Nagarajan, T. N., & Silva, S. T. (2017). The impact of ageing and the speed of ageing on the economic growth of least developed, emerging and developed countries, 1990–2013. Review of Development Economics, 21(3), 909–934. doi:10.1111/rode.12294
  • Auzina-Emsina, A. (2014). Labour productivity, economic growth and global competitiveness in post-crisis period. Procedia - Social and Behavioral Sciences, 156(26), 317–321. doi:10.1016/j.sbspro.2014.11.195
  • Balci, O. (1998). Handbook of simulation: Principles, methodology, advances, applications, and practice, chapter verification, validation and testing. New York, NY: John Wiley and Sons.
  • Binswanger, H. P., & Mcintire, J. (1987). Behavioral and material determinants of production relations in land-abundant tropical agriculture. Economic Development and Cultural Change, 36(1), 73–99. doi:10.1086/451637
  • Bloom, D. E., & Finlay, J. E. (2009). Demographic change and economic growth in Asia. Asian Economic Policy Review, 4(1), 45–64. doi:10.1111/j.1748-3131.2009.01106.x
  • Bowlus, A. J., Mori, H., & Robinson, C. (2016). Ageing and the skill portfolio: Evidence from job-based skill measures. The Journal of the Economics of Ageing, 7, 89–103. doi:10.1016/j.jeoa.2016.02.003
  • Brucker, E. (2008). Employment population age-share differences: An international comparison of the economic impact of population aging. Journal of Aging & Social Policy, 21(1), 17–30. doi:10.1080/08959420802525448
  • Brunow, S., & Hirte, G. (2009). Regional age structure and economic growth: An econometric study for German region. Dresden Discussion Paper, 21(2), 139–149.
  • Bucci, A., & Moritz Müller, L. E. (2018). Dilution effects, population growth and economic growth under human capital accumulation and endogenous technological change. Journal of Macroeconomics, 62, 1–18. doi:10.1016/j.jmacro.2018.08.003
  • Cai, J., & Stoyanov, A. (2016). Population aging and comparative advantage. Journal of International Economics, 102, 1–21. doi:10.1016/j.jinteco.2016.04.006
  • Camba-Mendez, G., Kapetanios, G., Smith, R. J., & Weale, M. R. (2001). An automatic leading indicator of economic activity: Forecasting GDP growth for European countries. The Econometrics Journal, 4(1), S56–S90. doi:10.1111/1368-423X.00053
  • Carrão, P. V. R., & WikAtique, M. (2019). The evolution of ethnocentrism revisited: An agent-based model with inductive reasoning. EconomiA. doi:10.1016/j.econ.2019.03.005
  • Chen, Y., & Fang, Z. (2018). Industrial electricity consumption, human capital investment and economic growth in Chinese cities. Economic Modelling, 69, 205–219. doi:10.1016/j.econmod.2017.09.021
  • Chen, F., & Sun, X. (2014). Urban-rural income polarization and economic growth in china: Evidence from the analysis of a dynamic panel data model. Applied Economics, 46(32), 4008–4023. doi:10.1080/00036846.2014.950792
  • Choi, K. H., & Shin, S. (2015). Population aging, economic growth, and the social transmission of human capital: An analysis with an overlapping generations model. Economic Modelling, 50(2), 138–147. doi:10.1016/j.econmod.2015.05.015
  • Chomik, R., McDonald, P., & Piggott, J. (2016). Population ageing in Asia and the Pacific: Dependency metrics for policy. The Journal of the Economics of Ageing, 8, 5–18. doi:10.1016/j.jeoa.2016.05.002
  • Cuaresma, J. C., Lábaj, M., & Pružinský, P. (2014). Prospective ageing and economic growth in Europe. The Journal of the Economics of Ageing, 3, 50–57. doi:10.1016/j.jeoa.2014.05.003
  • Drakaki, M., Gören, H. G., & Tzionas, P. (2018). An intelligent multi-agent-based decision support system for refugee settlement sitting. International Journal of Disaster Risk Reduction, 31, 576–588. doi:10.1016/j.ijdrr.2018.06.013
  • Durlauf, S. N., Kourtellos, A., & Minkin, A. (2001). The local Solow growth model. European Economic Review, 45(4–6), 928–940. doi:10.1016/S0014-2921(01)00120-9
  • Fang, M. Y., & Wang, T. (2006). Challenge facing china's economic growth in its aging but not affluent era. China & World Economy, 14(5), 20–31. doi:10.1111/j.1749-124X.2006.00035.x
  • Fougère, M., Harvey, S., Mercenier, J., & Mérette, M. (2009). Population ageing, time allocation and human capital: A general equilibrium analysis for Canada. Economic Modelling, 26(1), 30–39. doi:10.1016/j.econmod.2008.05.007
  • Freire, C. (2019). Economic diversification: A model of structural economic dynamics and endogenous technological change. Structural Change and Economic Dynamics, 49, 13–28. doi:10.1016/j.strueco.2019.03.005
  • Gao, Y. M., & Zhang, S. S. (2018). The impact of population ageing on China's economic growth: Based on the perspective of labor supply and capital investment. Shandong Social Sciences, 6, 163–167.
  • Gao, Y., Liu, G., Casazza, M., Hao, Y., Zhang, Y., & Giannetti, B. F. (2018). Economy-pollution nexus model of cities at river basin scale based on multi-agent simulation: A conceptual framework. Ecological Modelling, 379, 22–38. doi:10.1016/j.ecolmodel.2018.04.004
  • Gibson, B., & Setterfield, M. (2015). Intermediation, money creation, and Keynesian macro-dynamics in multi-agent systems. Social Science Electronic Publishing, 11(1), 155–161.
  • Haini, H. (2019). Internet penetration, human capital and economic growth in the Asian economies: Evidence from a trans log production function. Applied Economics Letters, 26(21), 1774. doi:10.1080/13504851.2019.1597250
  • He, L., & Li, N. (2018). The threshold effect of longevity: Life expectancy and economic growth. Applied Economics Letters, 26, 1–4. doi:10.1080/13504851.2018.1543932
  • Hendrickson, J. R., Salter, A. W., & Albrecht, B. C. (2018). Preventing plunder: Military technology, capital accumulation, and economic growth. Journal of Macroeconomics, 58, 154–173. doi:10.1016/j.jmacro.2018.08.004
  • Herrmann, M. (2012). Population aging and economic development: Anxieties and policy responses. Journal of Population Ageing, 5(1), 23–46. doi:10.1007/s12062-011-9053-5
  • Hsu, M., Liao, P., & Zhao, M. (2018). Demographic change and long‐term growth in china: Past developments and the future challenge of aging. Review of Development Economics, 22(3), 928–952. doi:10.1111/rode.12405
  • Hu, X. (2000). Understanding of the measurement method of economic growth. Northern Economy and Trade, 2, 64–66.
  • Irmen, A. (2017). Capital‐ and labor‐saving technical change in an aging economy. International Economic Review, 58(1), 261–285. doi:10.1111/iere.12216
  • Islam, S. (1996). Economic freedom, per capita income and economic growth. Applied Economics Letters, 3(9), 595–597. doi:10.1080/135048596356032
  • Kolasa, A., & Rubaszek, M. (2015). The effect of ageing on the European economies in a life-cycle model. Economic Modelling, 52(6), 770–774. doi:10.1016/j.econmod.2015.06.020
  • Kong, X. B., Zhang, F. G., Xu, Y., & Qi, W. (2004). The progress and driving forces of change in arable land in intensive agricultural region during the past 50 years–a case study of Quzhou county in Hebei province. Journal of Natural Resources, 19(1), 12–20.
  • Lancia, F., & Prarolo, G. (2012). A politico-economic model of aging, technology adoption and growth. Journal of Population Economics, 25(3), 989–1018. doi:10.1007/s00148-011-0364-x
  • Law, A. M., & Kelton, W. D. (1991). Simulation modelling and analysis. New York, NY: McGraw-Hill.
  • Lee, H., & Shin, K. (2019). Nonlinear effects of population aging on economic growth. Japan and the World Economy, 51, 100963. doi:10.1016/j.japwor.2019.100963
  • Lenihan, H., McGuirk, H., & Murphy, K. R. (2019). Driving innovation: Public policy and human capital. Research Policy, 48(9), 103791. doi:10.1016/j.respol.2019.04.015
  • Li, D. (2017). China's high-quality cultivated land has decreased. Heilongjiang's Grain, 6, 50–50.
  • Li, H. (2016). Comprehensive second child and economic development. Economic Research Reference, 12, 43–44.
  • Li, X., Li, Z., & Chan, M. (2012). Demographic change, savings, investment, and economic growth. The Chinese Economy, 45(2), 5–20. doi:10.2753/CES1097-1475450201
  • Liu, Y. (2017). Industrial pollution resulting in mass incidents: Urban residents' behavior and conflict mitigation. Journal of Cleaner Production, 166(10), 1253–1264. doi:10.1016/j.jclepro.2017.08.125
  • Liu, J., & Liu, T. (2018). Two-child policy, gender income and fertility choice in China. International Review of Economics & Finance. doi:10.1016/j.iref.2018.12.009
  • Loupias, C., & Wigniolle, B. (2019). Technological changes and population growth: The role of land in England. Economic Modelling, 79, 198–210. doi:10.1016/j.econmod.2018.10.014
  • Magalhães, J. P., Stevens, M., & Thornton, D. (2017). The business of anti-aging science. Trends in Biotechnology, 35(11), 1062–1073. doi:10.1016/j.tibtech.2017.07.004
  • Mo, J. (2018). Land financing and economic growth: Evidence from Chinese counties. China Economic Review, 50, 218–239. doi:10.1016/j.chieco.2018.04.011
  • Neuenkirch, M., & Neumeier, F. (2015). The impact of UN and US economic sanctions on GDP growth. European Journal of Political Economy, 40, 110–125. doi:10.1016/j.ejpoleco.2015.09.001
  • Nicole, V. D. G., & Beer, J. (2015). From demographic dividend to demographic burden: The impact of population ageing on economic growth in Europe. Tijdschrift Voor Economische En Sociale Geografie, 106(1), 94–109.
  • Ogundari, K., & Awokuse, T. (2018). Human capital contribution to economic growth in Sub-Saharan Africa: Does health status matter more than education? Economic Analysis and Policy, 58, 131–140. doi:10.1016/j.eap.2018.02.001
  • Onkelinx, J., Manolova, T. S., & Edelman, L. F. (2016). The human factor: Investments in employee human capital, productivity, and SME internationalization. Journal of International Management, 22(4), 351–364. doi:10.1016/j.intman.2016.05.002
  • Pelinescu, E. (2015). The impact of human capital on economic growth. Procedia Economics and Finance, 22, 184–190. doi:10.1016/S2212-5671(15)00258-0
  • Peng, X. (2005). Population ageing, human capital accumulation and economic growth in China. Asian Population Studies, 1(2), 169–188. doi:10.1080/17441730500317246
  • Peng, X. J. (2008). Demographic shift, population ageing and economic growth in China: A computable general equilibrium analysis. Pacific Economic Review, 13(5), 680–697. doi:10.1111/j.1468-0106.2008.00428.x
  • Prettner, K. (2013). Population aging and endogenous economic growth. Journal of Population Economics, 26(2), 811–834. doi:10.1007/s00148-012-0441-9
  • Raurich, X., & Seegmuller, T. (2019). Growth and bubbles: Investing in human capital versus having children. Journal of Mathematical Economics, 82, 150–159. doi:10.1016/j.jmateco.2019.01.007
  • Sasmal, J. (2012). Resource and technology as constraints to growth in agriculture: The Indian experience. Conference Proceedings of the International Journal of Arts & Sciences, 5(3), 57–70.
  • Schweiger, G., Gomes, C., Engel, G., Hafner, I., Schoeggl, J., Posch, A., & Nouidui, T. (2019). An empirical survey on co-simulation: Promising standards, challenges and research needs. Simulation Modelling Practice and Theory, 95, 148–163. doi:10.1016/j.simpat.2019.05.001
  • Shen, R. F., Chen, U. S., Kong, X. B., Li, T. Y., Tong, Y., & Wang, J. K. (2012). Concept of cultivated land quality and its evaluation and management countermeasures. Journal of Soil Science, 49(6), 1210–1217.
  • Siddiqui, A., & Rehman, A. U. (2016). The human capital and economic growth nexus: In east and south Asia. Applied Economics, 28(49), 1–14. doi:10.1080/00036846.2016.1245841
  • Su, D., & Yao, Y. (2017). Manufacturing as the key engine of economic growth for middle-income economies. Journal of the Asia Pacific Economy, 22(1), 47–70. doi:10.1080/13547860.2016.1261481
  • Sunde, U. (2011). Life expectancy and economic growth. Journal of Economic Growth, 16(2), 99–133. doi:10.1007/s10887-011-9065-2
  • Talberth, J., & Bohara, A. K. (2006). Economic openness and green GDP. Ecological Economics, 58(4), 743–758. doi:10.1016/j.ecolecon.2005.09.002
  • Uddin, G. A., Alam, K., & Gow, J. (2016). Population age structure and savings rate impacts on economic growth: Evidence from Australia. Economic Analysis and Policy, 52, 23–33. doi:10.1016/j.eap.2016.08.002
  • Van, E., & Bovenberg, C. (1997). Progressive taxes, equity, and human capital accumulation in an endogenous growth model with overlapping generations. Journal of Public Economics, 64(2), 153–179. doi:10.1016/S0047-2727(96)01616-7
  • Wei, Y. Q. (2017). The position and evolution of labor-intensive industries in Zhejiang's manufacturing industry. Jiangsu Business Theory, 36, 5–9.
  • Wu, C., Wang, J., Xu, H., Tan, G., & Zhang, W. (1995). The evaluation of the urban land resource classification and its relation to the optimum allocation of land. Journal of Natural Resources, 24(1), 260–280.
  • Yoon, J. H. (2006). International real business cycle model with human capital and skill acquisition activities. Korea & the World Economy, 7(2), 253–276.
  • Zallé, O. (2019). Natural resources and economic growth in Africa: The role of institutional quality and human capital. Resources Policy, 62, 616–624. doi:10.1016/j.resourpol.2018.11.009
  • Zeng, Y., & Hesketh, T. (2016). The effects of China's universal two-child policy. The Lancet, 388(10054), 1930–1938. doi:10.1016/S0140-6736(16)31405-2
  • Zeng, Y., Zhang, X., & Liu, L. (2017). From ‘selective two-child policy' to universal two-child policy: Will the payment crisis of china's pension system be solved? Finance & Trade Economics, 5(1), 14–21.
  • Zhai, Z. W., Zhang, X. L., & Jin, Y. (2014). Demographic consequences of the immediate and comprehensive liberalization of the second-child policy. Population Studies, 38 (2), 3–17.
  • Zhang, H., Zhang, H., & Zhang, J. (2015). Demographic age structure and economic development: Evidence from Chinese provinces. Journal of Comparative Economics, 43(1), 170–185. doi:10.1016/j.jce.2014.07.002

Appendix 1.

Explanation for the method used

The current study’s research method is based on complex adaptive system theory and the use of computer simulation software. I have designed various simulation scenarios for the current study, and the optimal results are screened. The advantage of this method is that it does not depend on the use of mathematical equations; it can therefore be used to study nonlinear and heterogeneous economic agents. The method is divided into four main steps: (1) Build a conceptual model, (2) Build a simulation model, (3) Initialize and input data, and (4) Validate the model. I provide below the details of each of these steps.

A1 Build a conceptual model

The conceptual model is the foundation of the simulation model. Construction of the conceptual model is based mainly on the theoretical and empirical literature, but additionally includes original author contributions. The model completes the construction of the entire simulation system’s framework. The various variables within the system are based on this model.

A2 Build a simulation model

The simulation model is based on the conceptual model, and the NetLogo simulation platform is used for simulation. The model transforms the theoretical framework and variables of the conceptual model, thus making the computer identifiable. This transformation does not require the creation of mathematical equations; rather, it leverages computer programming language through the command statement (command center) to achieve interaction among the various subjects (e.g., clear-all, set max-resources 50, ask patches, and set……if……). These individual commands involve different functional modules. Some examples follow.

to setup clear-all set max-resources () setup-patches setup-turtles update-lorenz-and-gini reset-ticks end

The combination of these functional modules comprises the whole of the simulation model, which includes output modules for various graphics and tables.

A3 Initialize and input data

Initialization of the simulation model requires the assignment of variables. Certain initial values are based on China’s real-world conditions; other variables are similarly based on research results. Meanwhile, to analyze trends under various experimental scenarios, I manually controlled for the effects of some important variables.

A3.1 SimBT1

Before the comprehensive two-child policy was implemented in China, only a select population was allowed to have two children. This policy scenario, as the benchmark, was compared with the other two scenarios.

A3.2 SimAT1

The second policy scenario features the aging of China’s population. A fully liberalized two-child policy would increase the number of births, which would in turn increase the value of number-population.

A3.3 SimAT2

The third policy scenario also assumes an aging population and a fully liberalized two-child policy, but additionally assumes increased investment in human capital and technology.

A4 Model validation

There is no generally accepted method by which to assess the validity and robustness of agent-based models (Balci, Citation1998).

  1. The approach used is considered one of model verification and validation, and use of this approach is supported by the literature. Additionally, the use of multiple data sources improved the validity of the model (e.g., determined whether the conceptual model was a reasonably accurate representation of real-world conditions) (Law & Kelton, Citation1991).

  2. The removal of errors from the simulation program helped preclude the incorrect application of the conceptual model, and thus guaranteed the model’s validity and robustness.

  3. I used an iterative process that adjusts poorly characterized experimental variables, to accommodate extreme conditions and sensitivity. The calibration process improved the goodness of fit between the model and the data.