64
Views
0
CrossRef citations to date
0
Altmetric
Original Articles

The labour scarcity paradox reconsidered: a simple growth theoretic explanation

Pages 1501-1504 | Published online: 23 Sep 2009
 

Abstract

By calibrating a Solow model augmented by natural resources, this paper offers a simple explanation of the labor scarcity paradox during the process of America's catching up with Britain, which static models have difficulties in accounting for so far.

Notes

1 James and Skinner (Citation1985), p. 517.

2 Habakkuk (Citation1962), p. 96−97.

3 It may seem odd that they happened to be exactly the same. Yet it is a good baseline case until we find evidence suggesting otherwise.

4 James and Skinner (Citation1985), p. 527.

5 Maddison (Citation1982), Table 3.3, p. 48.

6 I tried running regressions using data from Maddison (Citation1982) for Great Britain, but the parameter estimates don't make much sense with α = 0.66, and β = 1.2. One reason is that the sample size is too small (every ten years from 1820 to 1913).

7 Habakkuk (Citation1962), p. 111.

8 In 1870, 50% of the total employment was in the agricultural sector in America, while the British counterpart was only 22.7%. This gap would have been larger in 1850. Source: Maddison (Citation1982), Table C5, p. 205.

9 This is a sensible assumption if they were using the same technology.

10 I take the arithmetic average of the US population growth rates of 1.2% (during 1700−1820) and 1.8% (during 1820−1979). Source: Maddison (Citation1982, Table 3.4, p. 49).

11 I take the arithmetic average of the British population growth rates of 0.7% (during 1700−1820) and 0.6% (during 1820−1979). Source: Maddison (Citation1982, Table 3.4, p. 49).

12 Unfortunately no direct data for 1850 is available.

13 I use the above data of America's labour force in 1849, Britain's labour force in 1851, and the population growth rates during that period for both countries for extrapolations.

14 This is calculated from Maddison (Citation1982, Table D13, p. 232), which indicates the US capital stocks as 6.52 and 10.36 in 1870 and 1880, respectively with 1950 = 100.

15 This is calculated from Maddison (Citation1982, Table D12, p. 231), which indicates the British capital stocks as 16.13 and 31.95 in 1830 and 1860, respectively with 1950 = 100.

16 I take arithmetic average of real interest rates between 1841−1850 and 1851−1860. Source: James and Skinner (Citation1985, p. 539).

17 James and Skinner (Citation1985, p. 537).

18 Both US and Britain data are for 1871−1880 as ‘ratio of gross fixed nonresidential investment to GDP at current market price from Maddison (1985), Table 2.3, p. 40.

19 Habakkuk (Citation1962), p. 4.

Log in via your institution

Log in to Taylor & Francis Online

PDF download + Online access

  • 48 hours access to article PDF & online version
  • Article PDF can be downloaded
  • Article PDF can be printed
USD 53.00 Add to cart

Issue Purchase

  • 30 days online access to complete issue
  • Article PDFs can be downloaded
  • Article PDFs can be printed
USD 205.00 Add to cart

* Local tax will be added as applicable

Related Research

People also read lists articles that other readers of this article have read.

Recommended articles lists articles that we recommend and is powered by our AI driven recommendation engine.

Cited by lists all citing articles based on Crossref citations.
Articles with the Crossref icon will open in a new tab.