2,234
Views
0
CrossRef citations to date
0
Altmetric
Research Article

Does Innovation Lead to Firm Growth? Explorative versus Exploitative Innovations

&

ABSTRACT

In this article, we examine the relationship between innovation and firm growth. Drawing on previous research, we implement a classification of innovations based on whether they are explorative or exploitative. Access to Swedish register data comprising the entire private sector from 1997 to 2012 allows us to construct innovation patterns for more than 480,000 firms. GMM-estimations confirm a significant and positive effect of both exploitative and explorative innovation on firms’ employment growth. More radical explorative innovations are shown to have a more persistent growth effect, while exploitative innovation increases labour demand in the short run.

JEL CLASSIFICATION:

I. Introduction

Understanding how innovation influences firm performance, in particular employment, is high on the agenda for policy-makers. As firms convert knowledge into innovations and strengthen their market position, they are likely to contribute to economic growth and welfare. A large number of countries have also stressed knowledge upgrading and innovation policies as a means to promote long-term, sustainable growth. The combination of globalization and rapid technological change has meant a stiffening in competition, further emphasizing the importance of firms’ innovation capacities.

Here, we examine how different types of innovation influence employment growth at the firm level, an area where knowledge is scarce and ambiguous as compared to other performance measures (Coad Citation2009; Harrison et al. Citation2014; Vivarelli Citation2014). We make a distinction depending on whether innovation strategies can be characterized as explorative or exploitative (March Citation1991), where the former can be characterized as having a search scope in order to invent new products that presently are not available on the market. The latter strategy emphasizes improvement rather than novelty of products or processes.

Combining patent application with patent classification, we create a knowledge profile for each firm at the two-digit level over a period of 15 years. If a firm did not apply for a patent in the same patent class during the last 5 years, it is defined as an explorative innovation; otherwise, it is an exploitative innovation.Footnote1 Altogether, our dataset includes more than 480,000 firms from the manufacturing and service industries, and we estimate the effects innovation has on firm-growth using the system GMM-model.

Comparing the two strategies, we find that firms engaged in explorative innovations enjoy a stronger employment growth, but the differences are not drastic. The results support a persistent employment growth effect, however, only in the case of explorative innovation, while displacement effects seem to prevail for exploitative innovations.

II. Hypothesis and econometric strategy

Based on previous research findings we test the following hypotheses: i) employment is positively related to both explorative and exploitative innovative activities, ii) employment effects are more pronounced for explorative innovative activities iii) employment effects to persist over several periods.

We embark on a standard log-linear employment equation (Layard and Nickell Citation1986), modified to first differences in order to eliminate firm fixed effects and to incorporate both current and lagged measures of our two innovation measures,

(1) Δnit=α1Δnit1+α2Δnit2+β1Δwit+β2Δkit+β3Δysit+β4Exploitativeit+β5Explorativeit+β6Exploitativeit1+β7Explorativeit1+β8Exploitativeit2+β9Explorativeit2+Xitδ+Δεit(1)

where Δnit=nitnit1 is the first difference in the logarithm of employment of firm i at year t. All other continuous variables are defined in the same way. We control for the wage rate wit, gross fixed capital kit and industry demand ysitFootnote2 Vector X contains dummy variables for ownership structure,Footnote3 sub-industries,Footnote4 years and regions.Footnote5 Finally, εit is the error term, expected to exhibit standard properties.

EquationEquation (1) is estimated using system-GMM techniques, which implies that lagged variables are used as instruments to control for potential endogeneity. First, the lagged dependent variable Δnit1 is potentially correlated with the error term Δεit and therefore risk introduces endogeneity in the estimations. We use nit3 and earlier realizations of nit as instruments for the first difference lagged dependent variable Δnit1 (Lachenmeier and Rottman Citation2011).

Second, one might consider the endogeneity of our two innovation variables. As suggested by Lachenmeier and Rottman (Citation2011), innovation decisions are often based on long-term considerations, while employment decisions are based on more short-term considerations. Hence, we assume that innovation decisions are made at least one period before employment decisions and instrument our innovation variables with one-period lagged level values, assumed uncorrelated with the error term.Footnote6

III. Data and descriptive statistics

Data are provided by Statistics Sweden’s Business Register and covers all registered firms and establishments in Sweden since 1987 and the European Patent Office’s PATSTAT database, supplemented with data from the Swedish Patent Office. Pooling firm-level data and patent application data leave us with a sample of 2,159,666 observations for 482,513 firms across 20 industries for the period 1997 to 2012.

For all firms, a patent history profile is created based on the patents the firm applied for during a five-year moving windowFootnote7 prior to any given yearFootnote8 which enables us to categorize innovations in the following way:

  • Exploitative innovation: A dummy variable is equal to one if a firm applies for a patent in year t in a patent class where it has already applied for a patent for the last 5 years, zero otherwise.

  • Explorative innovation: A dummy variable is equal to one if a firm applies for a patent in year t within a patent class where it has not applied for a patent for the last 5 years, zero otherwise.

provides descriptive statistics.Footnote9

Table 1. Descriptive statistics.

Number of observations: 2,159,666. All monetary variables are expressed in deflated thousands of SEK.

IV. Empirical results

The results from the regressions are shown in . Based on specifications 1 and 2, we find that both exploitative and explorative innovations have positive and significant effects on subsequent firm employment growth. The strength, however, decreases over time for both types of innovations. For exploitative innovations, it turns negative after 2 years, albeit insignificant, indicating that firms may enjoy efficiency gains already in the short term, while it may take time before it results in a reduced workforce.Footnote10

Table 2. Results, regression coefficients.

Explorative innovations are more likely to come up with new products and processes and generate an increase in labour demand. While both explorative and exploitative innovations are included in the regressions simultaneously, only the former remains statistically significant.

All control variables (wage rate, capital stock and sector gross value added) have the expected signs and are highly significant. The test statistics support the validity of the system-GMM method. The Sargan test does not reject the null hypothesis that our instruments are exogenous, while the AR(2) test does not reject the null hypothesis of no second-order autocorrelation at the 5% significance level.Footnote11

V. Conclusion

Using patent data, we have shown that explorative innovations have a more pronounced and persistent effect on employment growth than exploitative innovations.Footnote12 This type of innovation adheres more closely to Schumpeter’s early view on the role of the entrepreneur in initiating creative destruction processes.

The different impact of exploitative and explorative innovations on firm growth has important implications for government policies. Policies encouraging novelty may be rewarding for society in terms of long-term employment growth. An essential part of such policies is acceptance of failure and exit rules that allow for a second chance. Well-developed financial markets and access to venture capital may be another pillar. Moreover, as shown in numerous previous studies, only stimulating R&D may not be an optimal policy instrument and may even deter high-tech entry (Acemoglu et al. Citation2013).

We end this paper with two suggestions for future research on the link between innovation and employment growth. First, to test if and how the results are affected by excluding firms that never apply for a patent. Second, assess how productivity might play a mediating role in linking innovation and employment growth.

Acknowledgments

We would like to thank Ding Ding for excellent support with the econometric part of the study.

Disclosure statement

No potential conflict of interest was reported by the author(s).

Data availability statement

The data that support the findings of this study are available from Statistics Sweden (SCB). Restrictions are applied to the availability of these data, which are used under licence for this study. Further information on how to access these data can be found at:

https://www.scb.se/en/services/ordering-data-and-statistics/guidance-for-researchers-and-universities/

Additional information

Funding

This work was supported by Marianne and Marcus Wallenberg’s Foundation.

Notes

1 Akcigit and Kerr (Citation2018), introducing similar concepts in a theoretical model, provide some correlations.

2 Industry demand is measured as industry-aggregated gross value added. All monetary variables are measured in fixed prices..

3 The influence of types of ownership on employment growth and innovation are inconclusive (see e.g. Barba Navaretti Citation2004; Dachs and Peters Citation2014).

4 See Herstad (Citation2018). We use the first level of NACE Rev. 2 to identify 20 industries.

5 We use 72 labour market regions (FA-regions) as our spatial unit of measurement.

6 The validity of this assumption is subsequently tested using the Sargan test.

7 The depreciation rate for knowledge capital is five years (Griliches Citation2007).

8 The patent applications classes (121) are determined at the two-digit level of International Patent Classification (IPC). See Bloom, Schankerman, and Van Reenen (Citation2013) for a similar approach.

9 See Daunfeldt and Halvarsson (Citation2015) for details regarding the employment-growth distribution of Swedish firms.

10 Labour regulations may also deter laying off employees.

11 The results are virtually unchanged when using a three-year window of innovation or a Heckman selection model to control for survival effects. We expect them to be robust to a separation on patenting and non-patenting firms, see Balasubramanian and Sivadasan (Citation2011).

12 For a brief discussion of alternative innovation measures, see Colombelli, Krafft, and Quatraro (Citation2014).

References

  • Acemoglu, D., U. Akcigit, N. Bloom, and W. R. Kerr. 2013. “Innovation, Reallocation and Growth.” NBER WP 18993. Cambridge, MA: NBER.
  • Akcigit, U., and W. R. Kerr. 2018. “Growth through Heterogeneous Innovations.” Journal of Political Economy 126: 1374–1443. doi:10.1086/697901.
  • Balasubramanian, N., and J. Sivadasan. 2011. “What Happens When Firms Patent? New Evidence from U.S. Economic Census Data.” The Review of Economics and Statistics 93: 26–146. doi:10.1162/REST_a_00058.
  • Barba Navaretti, G. 2004. “Host Country Effects: Conceptual Framework and the Evidence.” In Multinational Firms in the World Economy, edited by G. Barba Navaretti and A. J. Venables. Princeton: Princeton University Press.
  • Bloom, N., M. Schankerman, and J. Van Reenen. 2013. “Identifying Technology Spillovers and Product Market Rivalry.” Econometrica 81 (4): 1347–1393. doi:10.3982/ECTA9466.
  • Coad, A. 2009. The Growth of Firms: A Survey of Theories and Empirical Evidence. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar Publishing.
  • Colombelli, A., J. Krafft, and F. Quatraro. 2014. “High-growth Firms and Technological Knowledge: Do Gazelles Follow Exploration or Exploitation Strategies?” Industrial and Corporate Change 23 (1): 261–291. doi:10.1093/icc/dtt053.
  • Dachs, B., and B. Peters. 2014. “Innovation, Employment Growth, and Foreign Ownership of Firms: A European Perspective.” Research Policy 43 (1): 214–232. doi:10.1016/j.respol.2013.08.001.
  • Daunfeldt, S. O., and D. Halvarsson. 2015. “Are High-growth Firms One-hit Wonders? Evidence from Sweden.” Small Business Economics 44 (2): 361–383. doi:10.1007/s11187-014-9599-8.
  • Griliches, Z., Ed. 2007. R&D, Patents and Productivity. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
  • Harrison, R., J. Jaumandreu, J. Mairesse, and B. Peters. 2014. “Does Innovation Stimulate Employment? A Firm-level Analysis Using Comparable Micro-data from Four European Countries.” International Journal of Industrial Organization 35: 29–43. doi:10.1016/j.ijindorg.2014.06.001.
  • Herstad, S. J. 2018. “Product Innovation and Employment Growth at the Firm Level: A Quantile Regression Approach to Inter-industry Differences.” Applied Economic Letters 25 (15): 1062–1065. doi:10.1080/13504851.2017.1394970.
  • Lachenmeier, S., and H. Rottman. 2011. “Effects of Innovation on Employment: A Dynamic Panel Analysis.” International Journal of Industrial Organization 29: 210–220. doi:10.1016/j.ijindorg.2010.05.004.
  • Layard, R., and S. Nickell. 1986. “Unemployment in Britain.” Economica 53: 121–S169. doi:10.2307/2554377.
  • March, J. G. 1991. “Exploration and Exploitation in Organizational Learning.” Organization Science 2 (1): 71–87. doi:10.1287/orsc.2.1.71.
  • Vivarelli, M. 2014. “Innovation, Employment and Skills in Advanced and Developing Countries: A Survey of Economic Literature.” Journal of Economic Issues 48 (1): 123–154. doi:10.2753/JEI0021-3624480106.