321
Views
0
CrossRef citations to date
0
Altmetric
Research Article

Freeze-out mergers: the case of shareholders with multiple shares

&
Pages 65-70 | Published online: 20 Sep 2022
 

ABSTRACT

This paper investigates the role of freeze-out mergers in mitigating the free-rider problem in tender offers. In contrast to a framework in which each shareholder owns exactly one share, our model allows shareholders to have multiple shares. We find that a more aggressive freeze-out clause forces shareholders to tender more shares. Therefore, raiders capture a greater amount of surplus when the requirement for freeze-out mergers becomes easier to satisfy.

JEL CODES:

Acknowledgments

We wish to thank the editor (David Peel) and two reviewers for their helpful comments on our work. Any remaining errors are ours.

Disclosure statement

No potential conflict of interest was reported by the author(s).

Notes

1 It should be noted that Dalkır, Dalkır, and Levit (Citation2019) examine the role of freeze-out mergers in mitigating the free-rider problem with the one-share-per-shareholder model. They find that raiders cannot capture any surplus because freeze-out mergers do not eliminate the free-rider problem. However, as mentioned in Holmström and Nalebuff’s (Citation1992), the free-rider problem does not exclude raiders from obtaining surplus when shareholders have multiple shares. This suggests the possibility that the freeze-out mergers affect the part of the raiders’ surplus.

2 The freeze-out thresholds vary significantly across jurisdictions. For example, in Canada and several European countries, the raider is allowed to freeze out minority shareholders only after obtaining more than 90% of shares (see Gomes Citation2012). In contrast, most U.S. states adopt a simple majority rule for freeze-out mergers.

3 As discussed in Holmström and Nalebuff’s (Citation1992), this case implies that the total number of a firm’s shares is sufficiently large, whereas the number of shareholders is not.

4 For example, as pointed out by Oh and Baek (Citation2015), the total fraction of tendered shares is random if the raider’s negotiation ability with the blockholder is not known to shareholders.

5 Following the previous studies on freeze-out mergers (e.g Dalkır, Dalkır, and Levit Citation2019; Gomes Citation2012), we assume that the freeze-out threshold is not a raider’s decision variable because jurisdictions specify freeze-out thresholds.

6 The increase in the raider’s expected surplus due to a more aggressive freeze-out clause is not too small. For example, if the freeze-out threshold goes to one-half, then it is optimal for shareholders to tender all shares (see Equationequation (A1) in the proof of Proposition 1). Thus, the total fraction of tendered shares by shareholders equals one (i.e. T=1), implying that the raider can capture all surplus from the merger by letting the offer price approach zero (i.e. p0). In contrast, when f=1, it is not optimal for shareholders to tender all shares at a sufficiently small offer price. Thus, the raider can capture only a fraction of the surplus, as in Holmström and Nalebuff’s (Citation1992).

Log in via your institution

Log in to Taylor & Francis Online

PDF download + Online access

  • 48 hours access to article PDF & online version
  • Article PDF can be downloaded
  • Article PDF can be printed
USD 53.00 Add to cart

Issue Purchase

  • 30 days online access to complete issue
  • Article PDFs can be downloaded
  • Article PDFs can be printed
USD 205.00 Add to cart

* Local tax will be added as applicable

Related Research

People also read lists articles that other readers of this article have read.

Recommended articles lists articles that we recommend and is powered by our AI driven recommendation engine.

Cited by lists all citing articles based on Crossref citations.
Articles with the Crossref icon will open in a new tab.