418
Views
5
CrossRef citations to date
0
Altmetric
Articles

Learning-Shaping Crises: A Longitudinal Comparison of Public Personnel Reforms in Italy, 1992‒2014

, , , &
Pages 119-138 | Received 24 Feb 2015, Accepted 06 Feb 2016, Published online: 07 Apr 2016

Abstract

This article analyses the attempts to reform public administration, notably personnel management, in Italy between 1992 and 2014, with a focus on implementation and the period following the multiple crises that have unfolded since 2008. By untangling the policy learning processes between multiple crises, past reform attempts and domestic and European “contexts in motion”, the article finds that efficiency-oriented reforms have floundered regardless of the political color of governments or indeed of the nature – political or technocratic – of the governments. Domestic factors, notably the frequency of government alternation, i.e. government instability, and European pressure have further reinforced the orientation towards single-loop lessons, i.e. the almost exclusive effecting of short-term cost-cutting measures.

This article is part of the following collections:
25 years of research in comparative policy analysis

Introduction

This article aims to investigate the impact of fiscal crisis on policy change. Drawing on the crisis management literature, we define crisis as an “episode of threat and uncertainty, a grave predicament requiring urgent action” which is unexpected or unanticipated (Boin and ‘t Hart Citation2003, p. 544). Confronted with the ambiguity that typically marks crises, leaders may adopt fundamentally different postures (Hermann and Dayton Citation2009), and this implies that crises are occasions for framing contests between actors advocating or opposing policy change (Boin et al. Citation2009).

Crises can be opportunities for policy change since they delegitimize long-standing policies underpinning the status quo (Keeler Citation1993). By exposing the inadequacies of the existing system, crises can be exploited by leaders to deliver long-awaited reforms that in normal times are protected by dominant coalitions and sustained by organizational inertia. However, research on crisis management shows that the opportunities for reform in the wake of a crisis are smaller than often thought. The ability to bring about policy change entails a number of functional requirements as leaders need to embrace novel policy ideas and articulate a vision, sell it to diverse audiences and wield power to see it enacted (Boin and ‘t Hart Citation2003). These requirements make risk-adverse leaders prefer crisis containment to reform, i.e. preserve the status quo in the short-term rather than launch reform that only pays off in the long run. Crises can also be observed as opportunities of policy learning (Stern Citation1997), both at individual and institutional level. In this perspective, the periods of crisis are a testing ground for lessons learned in previous years, triggering or forestalling further learning and policy change (Smith and Elliott Citation2007; Deverell Citation2009), so that policy learning can be seen as a mechanism of policy diffusion over time (Shipan and Volden Citation2012).

We address the crisis’ “change vs status quo” dilemma by focusing on the fiscal crisis caused by the global financial and then economic upheaval since 2008 (Posner and Blondal Citation2012). We define the fiscal crisis as an unexpected episode of threat and uncertainty that has confronted leaders with the choice between the immediate urgency of cutting spending in the short term (crisis containment) and the desirable goal to effect major administrative reform in the long term, also as a way of increasing efficiency and hence the resources for future investments or spending (Hood and Wright Citation1981; Pollitt Citation2010). The fiscal crisis under examination was unexpected as it originated from worldwide banking and economic crises (Kickert and Randma-Liiv Citation2015) and it constituted a threat to existing systems particularly in the South European region where governments faced the possibility of default (Armingeon and Baccaro Citation2012).

In this article we probe into how the learning processes stimulated by successive crises have interacted with Italy’s domestic institutional context and with the influence of the European Union. Specifically, we analyze the impact on the post-2008 policy change of the interaction between learning and technocratic governments, government instability and the pressures for fiscal retrenchment coming from the EU. We focus on Italy for two reasons. First, it is the only case in Southern Europe where the threat of severe fiscal crisis was not unprecedented since the country faced a currency crisis in the period 1992–1994 (Ongaro Citation2009; Di Mascio et al. Citation2013). Thus, it is particularly suitable for exploring the role of recursive learning processes during each crisis and between the two crises (Moynihan Citation2009; Elliott and Macpherson Citation2010). Second, Italy is the only case in Southern Europe where the fiscal crisis led to the formation of a technocrat-led government that could face the fiscal crisis without concern for the short-term electoral gains so often detectable in party governments.

To preview our main findings, this research shows that policy-learning processes have operated in the sense of focusing Italy’s response to the fiscal crisis on short-term containment rather than public management reform. The lessons drawn from the past have probably acted as “prisons” (Brändström et al. Citation2004), inducing and constraining policy makers to focus their attention only on short-term expenditure reductions. In the field of public personnel management this has meant tough restrictions on recruitment, and therefore expenditure containment has been achieved at the price of excluding from public employment younger and potentially more qualified prospective candidates. The impact of these lessons was strengthened by the domestic institutional context and by European pressure. In spite of its insulation from short-term electoral constraints, a technocratic government chose not to embark on public management reform, even as political instability and the EU’s austerity orientation kept up the pressure for immediate fiscal gains rather than longer-term reform.

The remainder of the article unfolds as follows. The next section presents the research framework. In the following section we outline our methodology. The next two sections are empirical: we first reconstruct learning processes as they unfolded before the 2008 fiscal crisis and then analyze the response to the fiscal crisis triggered by the banking and economic crises since 2008. In the concluding section we place our findings in the context of some of the relevant literature and propose some implications of our study for further comparative research.

Research Framework

A fiscal crisis is likely to produce a variety of responses (Peters et al. Citation2011). We focus here on “administrative reform policy”, namely the policy that has the deliberate aim of improving the functioning of the public administration. Specifically, for the purpose of this study, the impact of the crisis on administrative reform is assessed in the domain of public personnel policies. A long list of trends in public personnel reform can be observed, although the concrete implementation varies and generally little data on outcomes are available (Demmke and Moilanen Citation2010). We adopt a dichotomous classification whereby public personnel policies can be distinguished between reforms aimed at improving the performance of organizations in the public sector (public management reforms) and short-term spending cuts with a focus on downsizing (cutbacks).

In doing so, we build on previous studies that focused on the personnel domain as an area that is especially exposed to fiscal retrenchment (Derlien and Peters Citation2008) which can be achieved by tightening the civil servants’ belts in order to reduce spending reductions and/or by implementing civil service reform in order to increase productivity (Pollitt and Bouckaert Citation2011). This is why public personnel have also been the privileged target of the intervention by actors such as the EU in countries like Italy and Greece (Zahariadis Citation2013, Citation2014). In particular, we focus on one dimension of public employment, namely staff size, which has been a core element of the austerity packages adopted in most OECD countries to lower public expenditure beyond wage cuts (Lodge and Hood Citation2012).

To assess the response to the fiscal crisis, we analyze the nature of the cuts, drawing on some of the contemporary cutback management literature (Pollitt Citation2010; Raudla et al. Citation2015). These measures can be transversal (“cheese slicing”), yielding across-the-board cuts affecting all policy areas regardless of their impact on political priorities. Alternatively, these measures can be selective, enabling governments to protect most effective programs from short-term spending control (“strategic prioritization”) and/or connect cutback management to broader administrative modernization initiatives aimed at increasing public sector productivity (“efficiency savings”).

We focus on public personnel cutbacks as measures that address the actual policy failures revealed by crises (May Citation1992). At the center of our analysis we put the decision-making process. Even if this process extends throughout the policy cycle, the analysis focuses on decisions made by the government over the period considered, trying to understand the way in which previous decisions interplay with the later ones through policy learning and lead to policy change. Thus, the main perspective adopted is that of policy learning at the institutional level under conditions of fiscal crisis.

Several different notions of learning have emerged in the policy literature (Bennett and Howlett Citation1992). We focus on policy learning qua model of action (Argyris Citation1976). In this sense single loop learning is a refinement of established actions to improve performance without changing guiding assumptions or without taking alternative courses of action into account, while double loop learning is a change in the frame of reference and guiding assumptions. Given our focus on fiscal retrenchment, we can equate different types of public personnel cutbacks to specific types of policy learning (Argyris and Schon Citation1978). Across-the-board cutbacks can be considered as single-loop learning processes with the aim of crisis containment as they do not alter the fundamentals of the administrative system (Levine Citation1985). Conversely, selective measures imply public management reform and can be considered double-loop learning processes.

Further, we observe policy learning with reference to its outcome distinguishing between lessons distilled and lessons implemented (Bennett and Howlett Citation1992; Deverell Citation2009). If a lesson is not carried out to the extent that it alters behavior, it is understood as distilled. If the lesson is drawn and subsequently acted upon, it is understood as implemented.

We also distinguish between inter-crisis and intra-crisis learning (Moynihan Citation2009). Inter-crisis learning concerns the process of learning in the post-crisis period, and is aimed at the prevention of and response to future crises. “Intra-crisis” learning occurs during crises when actors must engage in policy making within a limited time and under intense pressure.

By developing an analytical case study of the Italian public personnel policies under conditions of successive crises, we aim at generating insights into the impact of three factors on policy learning and policy change: government insulation from electoral pressures, government instability, and the role of the European Union. We examine the possible influences of these factors in turn.

First, party actors know that they are more likely to be vilified when things go wrong in the short term than praised when things go right in the long term ‒ what Hood (Citation2011, p. 10) calls the “negativity bias”. Thus concerns about the electoral costs of reforms often lead to reforms being quickly abandoned (Zahariadis Citation2013). Conversely, the impact of this political myopia can be reduced by electoral insulation (Geddes Citation1994), which in turn can be brought about by a crisis. In particular, the ordinary concerns with the electoral impact of reform can be expected to play a muted role under a technocratic government (McDonnell and Valbruzzi Citation2014), such as the one chaired in Italy by Mario Monti, which came into office in late 2011 amidst the political turmoil created by immediate fears of the country’s sovereign default.Footnote1Inasmuch as insulation from short-term electoral considerations makes reform more feasible, a first proposition can be formulated:

P1:

The formation of a technocratic government is a facilitator of public management reform.

If technocratic governments may be expected to facilitate reform, frequent government alternation, as occurred in Italy in the period examined in this article (Mele and Ongaro Citation2014), will likely lead to cost containment as the preferred response to the fiscal crisis. Frequent government alternation may in fact activate a “time compressing effect” (Fleischer Citation2013), pushing governments towards measures that can be rapidly implemented over those with longer-term payoffs. The “time compressing effect” may also indirectly operate on the dynamics of the learning processes, as it can activate the evocation of the historical analogy between the previous fiscal crisis and the current one. Since crises are immersed in historical sequences, when a new crisis arises, the way in which decision makers respond to it will in part depend on the solutions that actors have applied to previous crises, as previous solutions will influence the instruments and the interpretations available to future actors (Neustadt and May Citation1986; Haydu Citation1998). Governments will look back to past solutions and use them in crisis management when there are similarities between the contexts of the crises (Brändström et al. Citation2004). Moreover, in the perspective of the garbage can model of policy choice, to a considerable extent policy solutions can be independent from policy problems (Cohen et al. Citation1972), and this mechanism can be particularly evident when previous solutions are already defined. These conditions apply to Italy, which faced a previous fiscal crisis in the early 1990s in a context of political instability that persisted throughout the subsequent period. In sum, a second proposition is:

P2:

Frequent government alternation is a facilitator of crisis containment through budget cutbacks.

A final factor potentially affecting the nature of public personnel policies has been the embeddedness of Italy in the European Union. From the early 1990s on, a fiscally conservative paradigm has asserted itself in the European Commission as the cornerstone of the European Monetary Union (EMU) project (Jabko Citation2006). The policy goals to be attained are “sound money” and, connected to it, low government deficits, which are considered the necessary preconditions for economic growth (Bonatti and Fracasso Citation2013; Howarth and Rommerkirchen Citation2013). This “culture of stability”, combined with economic research arguing that fiscal retrenchment based on spending cuts rather than tax hikes positively contributes to economic growth and that government debt above a certain threshold stifles economic growth (e.g. Reinhart and Rogoff Citation2010), has become the foundation of the Commission’s economic worldview over the period of investigation of this study, and in particular of its position that fiscal austerity is expansionary through its impact on market confidence (Rehn Citation2013). When the Greek crisis exploded in 2010, threatening contagion to the weaker members of the European Monetary Union, decision makers in the Commission interpreted this event through the lens of the austerity paradigm, thus requiring spending cuts in the Member States to be accelerated in order to win back the confidence of markets (De Grauwe and Yumei Citation2013). Therefore, administrative reforms have not been sustained by the activation of an “actor certification” mechanism (Dunlop and Radaelli Citation2013) implying the role of external actors as “teachers of reform” who enjoy the legitimacy needed to validate the claims for reform in domestic contexts. As found by research on the Greek case (Zahariadis Citation2014), in the context of the sovereign debt crisis, EU institutions, and indeed external creditors, have not certified public management reform; rather they have emphasized spending cuts as the priority response. A final proposition is therefore:

P3:

EU attitudes permeated by the tenets of the austerity paradigm, by failing to provide public management reform certification and by putting pressure on governments to prioritize quick fiscal retrenchment, are a facilitator of prompt crisis containment through cutbacks.

Methodology

Our study draws on 24 semi-structured interviews with key experts knowledgeable about the dynamics of the post-2008 crisis in the domain of public employment in Italy ().

Table 1. List of interviews

Challenges to the validity of research posed by the use of soft data have been addressed in several ways. First, the respondents have been selected from a variety of backgrounds: elected officials as well as tenured officials from all the institutions tasked with the planning, implementing and monitoring of fiscal consolidation measures as well as administrative reforms in Italy (Ministry of Finance, Ministry of Public Administration, Ministry of Government Program Implementation, Cabinet Office, Parliament, ARAN – National Agency for Negotiation with the Public Sector Unions, Court of Accounts), trade union officials, advisers working in ministerial cabinets and senior managers responsible for the public sector in a major consultancy firm. Second, information from face-to-face interviews was cross-checked with alternative documentary sources, such as reports drawn up by the Ministry of Economy and the Ministry of Public Administration and reports prepared by research institutes. Finally, the interviews had both open- and closed-ended questions so as to add thicker insights into the process of crisis management to the categorical assessment of spending measures enacted in reaction to the crisis. The questionnaire and the set of alternative documentary sources are available from the authors. The next two sections review the administrative reforms of the 1992–2014 period from the perspective of the 2008–2014 intra-crisis learning processes.

In order to understand the role of historical analogy in crisis management and in policy diffusion in the same jurisdiction over time, the first empirical section tracks the administrative reforms which have taken place before the 2008 crisis. We rely on secondary and statutory sources to reconstruct the 1992–1994 fiscal crisis and the following 1995–2008 sequence of policy change in public personnel size definition. The policy learning processes that emerged during those two periods are characterized in terms of single or double loop based on the consideration of their substantive content. Lessons learned are distinguished between distilled or implemented based on the outcomes they have produced in terms of modification of courses of action.

All these processes fall under the rubric of inter-crisis policy learning, since the time perspective adopted focuses on the 2008–2014 fiscal crisis. The second empirical section addresses the lessons learned during 2008–2014 by decision makers looking at previous experiences of coping with the fiscal crisis (1992–1994) and administrative reforms (the whole previous period 1992–2008). It then delves into the 2008–2014 intra-crisis learning process: learning that occurred over 2008–2014 based on the experiences of the same period.

The Path to the 2008 Fiscal Crisis

Lessons Learnt from the 1992–1994 Fiscal Crisis

The administration of public personnel in Italy is based on the distinction between the workforce that is, on paper, required for executing the job (notional staff), and the actual one, which is mainly driven by the amount of resources available to the public employer to hire staff – the former setting a ceiling to recruitment. At the beginning of the 1990s the figures for notional staff were far above the actual staff in most public sector organizations. Thus, the ceiling represented by the notional staff did not operate as a mechanism for containing the expansion of the workforce, which was partly driven by patronage (Cassese Citation1993; Di Mascio Citation2012). Furthermore, the organization was particularly fragmented so as to multiply the posts classified as “managerial”, and a number of administrative posts retained their own rules and wage scales, thus being shielded from the general discipline of public employment. Finally, dismissals were extremely difficult to effect due to statutory protections.

After the currency crisis that led to the lira’s expulsion from the European Monetary System in 1992 and the risk of sovereign default, the Amato government was forced to face the problems of the low productivity of public employment and its excessive size and cost. A measure to halt the growth in size of public employment was the freeze on recruitment ().

Table 2. Learning Processes (1992–2007)

In the aftermath of the corruption scandals that brought down the postwar party system in 1992–1993, the center-left Amato government was succeeded by a technocratic government led by the former President of the Bank of Italy, Carlo Azeglio Ciampi. As a response to systematic overspending, in 1993 the Ciampi government (1993–1994) launched the “privatization” of public employment, which was subjected to the rules of collective bargaining, and thus of private labor law, in order to achieve flexibility in the management of human resources within the public sector (Bordogna and Neri Citation2011). A two-tier labor contract system was also set up, one at the national level for each sector and an integrative one at the level of each individual administration. A new autonomous agency (ARAN) was tasked with negotiating collective contracts with the unions on a technical and neutral basis, while specialized advisory bodies (Servizi di Controllo Interno) were established for assessing organizational performance at the level of each administration, a provision that was meant to usher in a new era of results-based accountability.

However, the implementation of this public management reform generated perverse effects as collective bargaining caused real wages to grow, whilst productivity did not. The total of the salaries estimated during the bargaining process at the national level was significantly increased by individual administrations, without any return in terms of increased productivity. Furthermore, integrative contracts were not used to link variable components of the wage to performance. Finally, most public employees obtained career progressions without passing any competitive selection. Since top managers’ appointments hinged upon political loyalty rather than identified objectives, they were not concerned about the efficient utilization of human resources. By renouncing an autonomous role in the management of human resources, managers left room for the pervasive influence of trade unions.

The Ciampi government also adopted a selective measure directly aimed at curbing public personnel layouts. Public administrations were tasked to carry out estimates of the staff workload every two years, a procedure which was meant to facilitate the determination of the “proper” notional staff. Based on assessment methods previously approved by the Minister for Public Administration, public sector organizations were supposed to realize massive reorganizations, reducing their workforce and rationalizing its distribution among bureaucratic units and levels of career. However, even this less demanding process of public management reform did not translate into effective implementation.

Lessons Learnt from the 1995–2008 Inter-Crisis Period

Two short-lived governments, which did not engage with public personnel reform, followed the Ciampi government: a center-right government (Berlusconi I 1994–1995), and a second technocratic government led by a senior Bank of Italy official, Lamberto Dini (1995–1996). From 1996 on the country entered a period of alternation between center-left and center-right coalitions, both highly fragmented and unstable.

The center-left Prodi I government launched a new wave of administrative reforms aimed at raising productivity by establishing performance evaluation as the main criterion for personnel management. As had happened for the first wave of reforms, the plans for administrative modernization were thwarted by the politicization of top management and the poor quality of collective bargaining, producing a growth in the public employment payroll without productivity gains.

The Prodi government also launched in 1997 a Triennial Plan of Staff Requirement, a tool for reducing the permanent workforce by a fixed percentage (0.5 per cent in the first year), adopting differentiated measures in different administrations. Administrations gained the opportunity to compensate for permanent staff losses with temporary positions. This measure paved the way for a dysfunctional recruitment system, as contracts for these temporary workers were prolonged year after year, strengthening their expectation of being “titularized” (i.e. that they would sooner or later get tenure).

Continued pressure on the public accounts pushed the center-right Berlusconi II government in 2001 to re-introduce the hiring freeze, the across-the-board measure adopted by Giuliano Amato in 1992. This measure was continued until 2006, but weakened by the provision of derogations authorized on a case by case basis by the government, mostly under pressure from the unionized temporary workers striving for “titularization”. Derogations were progressively circumscribed to a limited number of public organizations, in part because of the progressive consolidation of the information system developed by the Ministry of Finance, which entrenched cutback measures into the routines for crisis management. As a result of the continued freeze on recruitment, between 2003 and 2007 the tenured workforce decreased by 1.9 per cent, although this drop was largely compensated for by the significant increase (+7.4 per cent) in temporary workers (Ragioneria Generale dello Stato Citation2014). However, this drop was not sufficient to avoid the formalization in 2005 by the European Commission of the infringement procedure for breaching the 3 per cent deficit-to-GDP limit prescribed by the Stability and Growth Pact of the EU. The infringement procedure provided an impulse for the further reinforcement of the hire freeze as a tool to reduce spending without conflicting with current policies and objectives.

In order to meet public finance targets negotiated at the European level after the infringement proceedings for violation of the Stability and Growth Pact in 2005, the center-left Prodi II government, which was in power in the period immediately preceding the onset of the crisis (2006–2008), launched new measures displaying a mix of across-the-board cuts and selective interventions, mostly re-proposing the solutions adopted by the Prodi I government in 1997, even though they were more precisely specified and decoupled from major plans of administrative modernization ().

Selective measures included a staff ceiling for ministerial advice offices, which were not to exceed 15 per cent of the total workforce, and the merger or abolition of local offices of the central government. These selective measures presupposed a complex reorganization which was to be coordinated by a Cabinet Office Mission Unit jointly led by the Ministry for Public Administration, the Ministry of the Economy, and the Interior Ministry; sanctions were designed for non-complying departments, in the form of a prohibition on recruitment. The center-left government was very keen to engage the trade unions, and it adopted the “concertation method”, based on a Memorandum of Agreement on Public Work and Quality Service with all the most representative trade unions in 2007.

However, these measures did not produce any results, as they were reportedly plagued by a range of factors, including “data manipulation and opportunistic behavior by the target administrations” (Interview, State auditor, October 23, 2012); the fragmentation of the governing coalition (Interview, Ministry of Public Administration senior official, December 6, 2012); the limits of the concertation method itself, at least as practiced on that occasion, which “gave veto power to the trade unions” (Interview, Ministry of Finance senior official, November 12, 2012); and the abrupt termination of the legislature in 2008.

Conversely, across-the-board cuts affected both notional and actual personnel. A transversal cut in the notional staff was carried out in 2006, implementing a fixed replacement rate based on a percentage of the 2006 terminations. It is notable that one provision forbade resorting to temporary staff, coupled with a program (which soon proved to lack the resources to be sustainable) of gradual “titularization” of the temporary personnel already in service.

This experience consolidated the appraisal coming from the implementation of the measure enacted by the previous Prodi I government: the choice to mix selective and across-the-board measures was an attempt to appear attentive to the long-term modernization of the bureaucratic apparatus and not only to short-term crisis management. However, in a context marked by political instability, there were scarce chances to implement public management reforms.

interprets each of the reported reforms in term of model of action and typology of lessons learnt from the 2008–2014 inter-crises policy learning perspective.

The Response to the 2008 Fiscal Crisis: Single Loop Expenditure Containment Measures Implemented

Berlusconi IV Government

The center-left coalition was sharply divided and could only count on a bare majority, which collapsed in 2008, paving the way to the third electoral success of Silvio Berlusconi and his fourth government. At the beginning of its mandate, the Berlusconi IV government attempted to revitalize the implementation of the previous waves of reforms focused on increasing productivity via the re-launch of NPM tools such as performance management. The modernization effort was driven by the Minister for Public Administration Renato Brunetta, who exploited the persistent legitimacy crisis of the Italian public sector as leverage for the implementation of a new comprehensive reform of the public employment regime.

The reform was launched as a crusade against the “fannulloni” (slackers) allegedly thriving in the Italian public workforce and it was complemented by measures against absenteeism which reduced sick leave pay and increased monitoring practices. Performance-related pay was reinstated by means of a forced-ranking logic whereby only one-quarter of civil servants could get the highest bonus, and one-quarter would not get any bonus, with a lower bonus to the remaining 50 per cent.

The reform was still under way when the effects of the global economic crisis started to be felt, leading policy makers to prioritize austerity measures which had proved to be effective in previous experiences of crisis-management ().

Table 3. Learning Processes (2008–2014)

The urgent need to get Italy’s ballooning public debt under control made “austerity measures collide with the implementation of the new reform, entirely hollowing out the implementation of performance-related pay” (Interview, ARAN senior official, December 12, 2012). In fact, the freeze on wages for the 2010–2014 period introduced by the Minister of Finance Giulio Tremonti in 2010 deprived the reform of the economic resources needed for performance-related pay to work.

The deficit reduction strategy was focused solely on the reinforcement of the across-the-board cuts. Negative feedback from the perverse effects of previous reform attempts precluded the re-launch of selective measures: having learned from his previous experiences as minister in 1994 and 2001–2004 how difficult it is to implement the reorganization of government as well as performance management in the Italian context marked by political instability, Tremonti deemed the re-launch of these measures too risky for the country’s overall fiscal stability.

Therefore, the response devised by the Berlusconi IV government was based on the extension and reinforcement of the replacement rate system already in place. After setting a cap on staff turnover in 2009 at 10 per cent of employee terminations in 2008, for the period 2010–2013 the reduction of recruitment was set at 20 per cent of the previous year’s terminations ‒ a cap to be removed only in subsequent legislative periods. The tightening of the replacement rate was sustained by positive feedback from previous interventions as “its uniformity suits well the current politico-administrative context marked by fragmented governing coalitions incapable of setting priorities” (Interview, Trade Union senior official, November 12, 2012).

Trade unions could not effectively oppose the tightening of the replacement rate as their legitimacy had been severely weakened by Brunetta’s campaign against their allegedly excessive influence on the public sector, which led to the split of the largest confederation, the Confederazione Generale Italiana del Lavoro, from the other two major unions, the Confederazione Italiana Sindacati Lavorarori and the Unione Italiana del Lavoro, the last two maintaining a cooperative relationship with the government. Paradoxically, the learning process started out as double-loop by Brunetta ended up as single-loop since the campaign against the trade unions which was meant to reduce their influence over public employment regulations provided leverage for the implementation of across-the-board cuts.

The tightening of the replacement rate, coupled with the pay freeze, was considered by the unions the least painful intervention, since the uniformity of cuts enabled them to preserve organizational cohesion among their different branches. Those to be more harshly hit by the provisions that slashed the budget for fixed-term contracts to 50 per cent of the amount allocated in the year 2009 were the temporary workers, who had a lower unionization rate.

When concerns about the sustainability of the Italian public budget mounted, market sentiment vis-à-vis Italy worsened sharply in summer 2011. It is in this context that the European Central Bank (ECB), in the persons of then President Jean-Claude Trichet and incoming President Mario Draghi, then at the Bank of Italy, sent a confidential letter to the Berlusconi government to spur it to implement both fiscal retrenchment and a broad set of reforms, including of the public administration and specifically of public personnel policy. Indications for fiscal retrenchment were later confirmed and made more detailed in the joint report to the Eurogroup by the ECB and DG Economic and Financial Affairs in November 2011 in the context of a special surveillance of Italian reforms decided at the European Council of October 2011 (European Commission Citation2011).

Consequently, the government adopted a further reinforcement of cuts at the level of both actual and notional personnel. Eventually, however, the incapacity of the Berlusconi government to cope with the worsening economic situation caused the collapse of its majority, paving the way for the Monti government.

Monti and Letta Governments (2011–2014)

When he took office, Mario Monti, a former European Commissioner, was President of Bocconi University in Milan. The Monti government was backed by a very large majority encompassing both Berlusconi’s party and the two main opposition parties. The numbers of both actual and notional workforce continued to plunge under the Monti government, which drew up a response focused solely on the repertoire of across-the-board cuts adopted by previous party governments ().

Despite its technocratic nature, the Monti government did not re-launch administrative reform. The circle of economists gathered around the Prime Minister did sketch a proposal for the reorganization of the state apparatus but this strategy was deemed by policy makers “too sophisticated, and too large to be feasible” in a context marked by political fragmentation and the short time horizon due to the imminence of national elections and the European pressure to meet fiscal targets in the short term (Rome, Democratic Party MP, February 6, 2014).

Indeed, drawing on previous experience of crisis management, the limit on the replacement rate was extended until the end of 2016 and the resulting reduction of the actual workforce was consolidated by further interventions on notional staff to eventually align it, in most public administrations, with the actual staff: after roughly a couple of decades the ceiling to recruitment based on notional staff finally became effective, as it finally tended to coincide with the actual staff. The reduction in the notional staff could be compensated between different offices, within the same or across public administrations. The sanction for non-implementation lay in forbidding further recruitment to the concerned administration. Redundancies would be dealt with through inter-administration mobility. Outright dismissal of public workers was also threatened, though more as a means to send a symbolic sign of addressing the external criticism of public workers “than as a really countenanced course of action” (Rome, Ministry of Finance adviser, October 8, 2012).

The enforcement of the last round of transversal cuts in the notional workforce was hindered by a faltering parliamentary majority and the uncertainty and politicking triggered by the approaching elections, which occurred in February 2013. By August 2013 such important ministries as Interior, Foreign Affairs or Justice had not yet reduced their staff. Nonetheless, in the other ministries reductions of notional staff did occur, with cuts of 36 per cent of the top level managerial positions, 45 per cent of the second level and 34 per cent of public employees between 2007 and 2013. As a result, 7,416 of the actual workforce for the ministries considered (118,571 public employees) exceeded the limits imposed on notional personnel. The redundancies were much lower than those estimated ex ante by the Monti government (11,000) and were easily absorbed through early retirement.

At the very end of its mandate, the Monti government postponed the vexed issue of the temporary workers. Not unexpectedly, given the history of personnel management in Italy (for an overview, see Ongaro Citation2011), their contracts were prolonged year after year, strengthening their understandable expectation of being “titularized”. However, the practice of “titularization” became less frequent in the 2008–2011 period (only 50,000 out of 310,000 temporary workers switched to permanent status). In December 2012, the duration of their contracts was prolonged by six month, de facto shifting to the next government the solution of this thorny problem.

Elections were held in February 2013, and they saw the anti-system Five Star Movement (M5S) gain more than 25 per cent of the votes and become the second most-voted-for political party. As M5S refused to cooperate with either the center-left or the center-right, the two mainstream parties agreed to back a national unity government, headed by Enrico Letta, the deputy secretary of the mainstream center-left party, the Democratic Party. The Letta government only lasted 10 months: following the appointment of the new national secretary of the Democratic Party, Letta was forced to resign in February 2014.

The Letta government, during its brief life from April 2013 to February 2014, first moved the temporary workers’ term to December 2013, and then further prolonged it. However, the budget law for 2014 allowed for only a limited amount of permanent positions since it reinforced and prolonged the replacement rate constraint until 2018.

interprets each of the reported reforms in terms of model of action and typology of lessons learnt from the 2008–2014 intra-crisis policy learning perspective.

Discussion and Conclusions

As emerged from the empirical analysis, the response to the post-2008 crises has reproduced existing patterns of reducing expenditure via across-the-board cuts. In other words, in a context marked by protracted political instability, previous direct experience with a fiscal crisis, and lack of actor certification of substantive public management reform, spending containment rather than public management reform has been the chosen course of action. The following paragraphs briefly review our findings, including the pertinent literature.

Previous Crisis Experience

Crisis management has been shaped by the effects of previous waves of administrative modernization, which discouraged policy makers from linking austerity measures to any major attempt to reform the public sector. The response to an earlier episode of fiscal austerity prompted a process of inter-crisis learning characterized by the coexistence of and interaction between “single” and “double-loop” lessons (Argyris and Schon Citation1978). Single- and double-loop lessons during the 1992–1994 crisis and 1995–2007 inter-crisis periods have exhibited different levels of implementation. Single-loop lessons have been progressively implemented as transversal cuts permitting governments to continue existing policies while enabling them to cope with the fiscal crisis. Conversely, double-loop lessons have been drawn (distilled) but not implemented. The different inter-crisis level of implementation of the two learning types triggered a process of intra-crisis learning in the midst of the sovereign debt crisis which placed attention only on single-loop lessons. Mindful of the implementation gap of previous reforms (Ongaro and Valotti Citation2008; Di Mascio et al. Citation2013), the governments that have been in office throughout the post-2008 crises have avoided endangering fiscal consolidation by re-launching selective interventions.

Political Instability

The “implementation gap” of double-loop lessons and the focus on single-loop learning could be considered the results of lack of time and intense political conflict (May Citation1992). These features are typical of fragmented coalition governments with short mandates, such as the Italian ones, activating a “time-compressing” effect (Fleischer Citation2013). Unless specific circumstances materialize (notably highly skilled policy entrepreneurs appropriately positioned in the administrative reform arena), governments under these circumstances are unlikely to engender consensus sufficient to trigger public management reforms, let alone sustain this consensus over the time span necessary to institutionalize double-loop lessons (Dekker and Hansen Citation2004; Broekema Citation2015).

Technocratic Government

The role of the technocratic Monti government proved to be different from that expected. The advent of technocratic governments was supposed to favor public management reform because its leaders were less likely to factor in the electoral repercussions of public management reforms purported to yield fruits only in the longer term. Yet, in the context of the quickly unfolding sovereign debt crisis, adverse political consequences were not limited to electoral losses but included the Italian membership in the euro area and the stability of the euro area itself. In these circumstances, the formation of the Monti government had the main effect of providing political support for cutbacks needed to rescue Italy and the eurozone: budget cutbacks became the only politically viable interventions in a context marked by political instability and lack of certification from the EU for more ambitious public management reforms.

EU Attitudes

Double-loop learning has not been sustained by the activation of a “certification” mechanism (Dunlop and Radaelli Citation2013) by external actors who enjoy the legitimacy needed to validate reform in domestic contexts. As in the Greek case (Zahariadis Citation2013, Citation2014), in the context of the sovereign debt crisis double-loop learning under the conditionality of external creditors has not occurred. This finding reflects the shift in European governance towards immediate measures to reduce spending over long-term modernization reforms. In the context of the fear of financial contagion from weaker countries, the Commission has emphasized the achievement of precise quantitative targets on a strict temporal schedule (Copeland and James Citation2014; Caporaso et al. Citation2015), despite the constant reminder of the need for structural reforms (which, it may well be assumed, should encompass also the development of public administration and cannot be confined to labor market reforms and other interventions geared to ameliorating the functioning of the markets). Hence, in the 2008–2015 fiscal crisis the external pressure of the European Commission has buttressed the use of single-loop learning processes.

Policy Results

The spending cuts have been successful in their own terms, as they kept the government payroll under control (). Most savings have been achieved through a combination of ever tighter control on replacement rates and cuts to temporary jobs, which brought down the number of tenured employees and temporary workers over 2007–2013.

Table 4. Size and features of public employment

Yet the sequential nature of cheese-slicing (Raudla Citation2013) imprisoned policy makers, who have not been able to take into account the cumulated effects of across-the-board cuts (see Brändström et al. Citation2004 on the notion of “prison”). Since the cuts took place in several rounds, efforts were devoted to adjusting spending between the rounds without taking into account the effects of more than two decades of cuts in public employment, which suffered from the failure to recruit new, fresh talent. Moreover, the measures to reduce personnel spending have contributed to creating “second class” public employees – the temporary staff condemned to an indefinite stay in that condition (if they can continue to work for the public sector at all).

At another level, the sequence of crises reduced the influence of trade unions on public personnel policy in Italy, much like what happened in a number of other European countries (Bach and Bordogna Citation2013). Public sector unions have traditionally been able to extract concessions from the governments of the day (Baccaro and Pulignano Citation2011). However, our study shows that in a context of crisis, the corporatist linkages between unions and parties in government are questioned by disaffected citizens pressurized by austerity policies and hence less forgiving towards forms of corporatist participation of organized interests in the public personnel policy. Consequently, the government’s unilateral power to determine terms and conditions of employment was strengthened. However, our study also highlights that the weakness of public sector trade unions has translated into weakened accountability on issues other than those related to curbing expenditure, thus indirectly favoring single-loop learning.

Analytical Generalizations

Finally, two limited analytical generalizations may tentatively be outlined from the case study. Technocratic governments instated under conditions of fiscal crisis are not in themselves sufficient to lead to major public management reform. The time compression generated by a short mandate facilitates resorting to available, ready-made solutions and historical analogy (the search for patterns that have already worked). Coupled with the lack of external actor certification for major public management reforms, this is likely to be conducive to a pattern of response to the fiscal crisis characterized by across-the-board cuts rather than in-depth reform.

Second, previous responses to crises may lead to a pattern whereby single-loop lessons are progressively implemented, since across-the-board cuts enable the pursuit of existing policies while coping satisfactorily enough with the fiscal crisis (satisficing decision-making pattern), and double-loop lessons are distilled but not implemented, engendering an overall pattern of response to crisis without substantive administrative modernization and reform of public management.

Acknowledgments

The article is the result of a common undertaking. However, sections “Introduction” and “Methodology” can be directly attributed to Davide Galli; “The Path to the 2008 Fiscal Crisis” to Alessandro Natalini; “The Response to the 2008 Fiscal Crisis” to Fabrizio Di Mascio. “Research Framework” and “Discussion and Conclusions” were co-authored by Edoardo Ongaro and Francesco Stolfi.

Additional information

Notes on contributors

Fabrizio Di Mascio

Fabrizio Di Mascio is Teaching Fellow of Political Science at Tuscia University, Viterbo, Italy. His research interests include political appointments, fiscal retrenchment, and public management reform in comparative perspective.

Davide Galli

Davide Galli is Assistant Professor of Management at the University Cattolica del Sacro Cuore, Piacenza, Italy. His research interests include performance management and comparative public administration.

Alessandro Natalini

Alessandro Natalini is Assistant Professor of Political Science at the Parthenope University, Naples, Italy. His research interests include better regulation, fiscal retrenchment, and public management reform in comparative perspective.

Edoardo Ongaro

Edoardo Ongaro is Professor of International Public Services Management at Northumbria University, Newcastle, UK. He is currently serving as President of the European Group for Public Administration (EGPA). He is editor of Public Policy and Administration.

Francesco Stolfi

Francesco Stolfi is a Assistant Professor of Political Science in the School of Politics, History and International Relations of the University of Nottingham Malaysia Campus, Selangor, Malaysia. His research interests include the impact of regional integration on national policy making and the politics of economic policy making and of administrative reform.

Notes

1. Although the concept of technocratic governments is contested, here term refers to a government in which all major decisions are not made by elected party officials (though these may be influential in decision making), policy is not deliberated within parties which then act cohesively to enact it, and the highest officials (ministers, prime ministers) are not recruited from political parties (McDonnell and Valbruzzi Citation2014).

References

  • Argyris, C., 1976, Single-loop and double-loop models in research on decision making. Administrative Science Quarterly, 21(3), pp. 363–375. doi:10.2307/2391848
  • Argyris, C. and Schon, D. A., 1978, Organizational Learning: A Theory of Action Perspective (Reading, MA: Addison-Wesley).
  • Armingeon, K. and Baccaro, L., 2012, The Sovereign debt crises of Ireland and Southern Europe, in: N. Bermeo and J. Pontusson (Eds) Coping with the Crisis (New York: Russell Sage Foundation).
  • Baccaro, L. and Pulignano, V., 2011, Employment relations in Italy, in: G. Bamber, R. D. Lansbury and N. Wailes (Eds) International and Comparative Employment Relations (London: Sage).
  • Bach, S. and Bordogna, L., 2013, Reframing public service employment relations: The impact of economic crisis and the new EU economic governance. European Journal of Industrial Relations, 19(4), pp. 279–294. doi:10.1177/0959680113505031
  • Bennett, C. J. and Howlett, M., 1992, The lessons of learning: Reconciling theories of policy learning and policy change. Policy Sciences, 25(3), pp. 275–294. doi:10.1007/BF00138786
  • Boin, A. and ‘t Hart, P., 2003, Public leadership in times of crisis: Mission impossible? Public Administration Review, 63(5), pp. 544–553. doi:10.1111/puar.2003.63.issue-5
  • Boin, A., ‘t Hart, P. and McConnell, A., 2009, Crisis exploitation: Political and policy impacts of framing contests. Journal of European Public Policy, 16(1), pp. 81–106. doi:10.1080/13501760802453221
  • Bonatti, L. and Fracasso, A., 2013, The German model and the European crisis. JCMS: Journal of Common Market Studies, 51(6), pp. 1023–1039. doi:10.1111/jcms.2013.51.issue-6
  • Bordogna, L. and Neri, S., 2011, Convergence towards an NPM programme or different models? Public service employment relations in Italy and France. The International Journal of Human Resource Management, 22(11), pp. 2311–2330. doi:10.1080/09585192.2011.584393
  • Brändström, A., Bynander, F. and ‘T Hart, P., 2004, Governing by looking back: Historical analogies and crisis management. Public Administration, 82(1), pp. 191–210. doi:10.1111/padm.2004.82.issue-1
  • Broekema, W., 2015, Crisis-Induced Learning and Issue Politicization in the EU. Public Administration, Published online. doi:10.1111/padm.12170
  • Caporaso, J. A., Kim, M., Durrett, W. N. and Wesley, R. B., 2015, The European Union and the financial crisis. Journal of European Public Policy, 22(7), pp. 889–907. doi:10.1080/13501763.2014.988638
  • Cassese, S., 1993, Hypotheses on the Italian administrative system. West European Politics, 16(3), pp. 316–328. doi:10.1080/01402389308424976
  • Cohen, M. D., March, J. G. and Olsen, J. P., 1972, A garbage can model of organizational choice. Administrative Science Quarterly, 17(1), pp. 1–25. doi:10.2307/2392088
  • Copeland, P. and James, S., 2014, Explaining the re-launch of the European Union’s economic reform agenda. Journal of European Public Policy, 21(1), pp. 1–19. doi:10.1080/13501763.2013.800789
  • De Grauwe, P. and Yumei, J., 2013, Panic-driven Austerity in the Eurozone and Its Implications. Voxeu.org. Available at http://www.voxeu.org/article/panic-driven-austerity-eurozone-and-its-implications ( accessed 5 July)
  • Dekker, S. and Hansen, D., 2004, Learning under pressure. Journal of Public Administration Research & Theory, 14(2), pp. 211–230. doi:10.1093/jopart/muh014
  • Demmke, C. and Moilanen, T., 2010, Civil Services in the EU of 27: Reform Outcomes and the Future of the Civil Service (Frankfurt am Main: Peter Lang).
  • Derlien, H. U. and Peters, B. G. (Eds), 2008, The State at Work: Comparative Public Service Systems (Cheltenham, UK: Edward Elgar).
  • Deverell, E., 2009, Crises as learning triggers. Journal of Contingencies and Crisis Management, 17(3), pp. 179–188. doi:10.1111/j.1468-5973.2009.00578.x
  • Di Mascio, F., 2012, Changing political parties, persistent patronage: The Italian case in comparative perspective. Comparative European Politics, 10, pp. 377–398. doi:10.1057/cep.2011.4
  • Di Mascio, F., Natalini, A. and Stolfi, F., 2013, The ghost of crises past: Analyzing reform sequences to understand Italy’s response to the global crisis. Public Administration, 91(1), pp. 17–31. doi:10.1111/padm.2013.91.issue-1
  • Dunlop, C. A. and Radaelli, C. M., 2013, Systematising policy learning: From monolith to dimensions. Political Studies, 61(3), pp. 599–619. doi:10.1111/post.2013.61.issue-3
  • Elliott, D. and Macpherson, A., 2010, Policy and practice: Recursive learning from crisis. Group & Organization Management, 35, pp. 572–605. doi:10.1177/1059601110383406
  • European Commission, 2011, Addressing Italy’s High Debt/Low-Growth Challenge Ares (2011) 1271959 – 28/11/2011. Brussels.
  • Fleischer, J., 2013, Time and crisis. Public Management Review, 15(3), pp. 313–329. doi:10.1080/14719037.2013.769852
  • Geddes, B., 1994, Politician’s Dilemma: Building State Capacity in Latin America (Berkeley, CA: University of California Press).
  • Haydu, J., 1998, Making use of the past. American Journal of Sociology, 104(2), pp. 339–371. doi:10.1086/210041
  • Hermann, M. G. and Dayton, B. W., 2009, Transboundary crises through the eyes of policymakers: Sense making and crisis management. Journal of Contingencies and Crisis Management, 17(4), pp. 233–241. doi:10.1111/jccm.2009.17.issue-4
  • Hood, C., 2011, The Blame Game (Princeton: Princeton University Press).
  • Hood, C. and Wright, M. (Eds), 1981, Big Governments in Hard Times (Oxford: Martin Robertson).
  • Howarth, D. and Rommerkirchen, C., 2013, The politics of the German stability culture. West European Politics, 36(4), pp. 750–770. doi:10.1080/01402382.2013.783355
  • Jabko, N., 2006, Playing the Market: A Political Strategy for Uniting Europe, 1985-2005 (Ithaca: Cornell University Press).
  • Keeler, J., 1993, Opening the window for reform: Mandates, crises, and extraordinary policy-making. Comparative Political Studies, 25(4), pp. 433–486. doi:10.1177/0010414093025004002
  • Kickert, W. and Randma-Liiv, T., 2015, Europe Managing the Crisis: The Politics of Fiscal Consolidation (London, UK: Routledge).
  • Levine, C. H., 1985, Police management in the 1980s: From decrementalism to strategic thinking. Public Administration Review, 45, pp. 691–699. doi:10.2307/3135022
  • Lodge, M. and Hood, C., 2012, Into and age of multiple austerities? Governance, 25(1), pp. 79–101. doi:10.1111/j.1468-0491.2011.01557.x
  • May, P., 1992, Policy Learning and Failure. Journal of Public Policy, 12(4), pp. 331–354. doi:10.1017/S0143814X00005602
  • McDonnell, D. and Valbruzzi, M., 2014, Defining and classifying technocrat‐led and technocratic governments. European Journal of Political Research, 53(4), pp. 654–671. doi:10.1111/1475-6765.12054
  • Mele, V. and Ongaro, E., 2014, Public sector reform in a context of political instability: Italy 1992–2007. International Public Management Journal, 17(1), pp. 111–142. doi:10.1080/10967494.2013.849168
  • Moynihan, D. P., 2009, From intercrisis to intracrisis learning. Journal of Contingencies and Crisis Management, 17(3), pp. 189–198. doi:10.1111/jccm.2009.17.issue-3
  • Neustadt, R. E. and May, E. R., 1986, Thinking in Time: The Use of History in Decision-Making (New York: The Free Press).
  • Ongaro, E., 2009, Public Management Reform and Modernization: Trajectories of Administrative Change in Italy, France, Greece, Portugal and Spain (Cheltenham, UK and Northampton, MA: Edward Elgar).
  • Ongaro, E., 2011, The role of politics and institutions in the Italian administrative reform trajectory. Public Administration, 89(3), pp. 738–755. doi:10.1111/j.1467-9299.2010.01885.x
  • Ongaro, E. and Valotti, G., 2008, Public management reform in Italy: Explaining the implementation gap. International Journal of Public Sector Management, 21(2), pp. 174–204. doi:10.1108/09513550810855654
  • Peters, B. G., Pierre, J. and Randma-Liiv, T., 2011, Global financial crisis, public administration and governance: Do new problems require new solutions? Public Organization Review, 11(1), pp. 13–27. doi:10.1007/s11115-010-0148-x
  • Pollitt, C., 2010, Cuts and reforms. Society and Economy, 32(1), pp. 17–31. doi:10.1556/SocEc.32.2010.1.3
  • Pollitt, C. and Bouckaert, G., 2011, Public Management Reform. A Comparative Analysis (Oxford: Oxford University Press).
  • Posner, P. and Blondal, J., 2012, Democracies and deficits: Prospects for fiscal responsibility in democratic nations. Governance, 25(1), pp. 11–34. doi:10.1111/gove.2012.25.issue-1
  • Ragioneria Generale dello Stato, 2014, Rapporto sulla spesa delle amministrazioni centrali dello Stato [Report on General Government Expenditure] (Rome: RGS-Ministry of Finance).
  • Raudla, R., 2013, Fiscal retrenchment in Estonia during the financial crisis. Public Administration, 91(1), pp. 32–50. doi:10.1111/j.1467-9299.2011.01963.x
  • Raudla, R., Savi, R. and Randma-Liiv, T., 2015, Cutback management literature in the 1970s and 1980s: Taking stock. International Review of Administrative Sciences, 81(3), pp. 433–456. doi:10.1177/0020852314564313
  • Rehn, O., 2013, Letter to the Ecofin, February 13 2013, Ares (2013) 185796, Brussels.
  • Reinhart, C. M. and Rogoff, K. S., 2010, Growth in a time of debt. American Economic Review: Papers & Proceedings 100 (May 2010): pp. 573–578 10.1257/aer.100.2.573
  • Shipan, C. R. and Volden, C., 2012, Policy diffusion: Seven lessons for scholars and practitioners. Public Administration Review, 72 (6), pp. 788–796.
  • Smith, D. and Elliott, D., 2007, Exploring the barriers to learning from crisis: Organizational learning and crisis. Management Learning, 38(5), pp. 519–538. doi:10.1177/1350507607083205
  • Stern, E., 1997, Crisis and Learning: A Conceptual Balance Sheet. Journal of Contingencies and Crisis Management, 5(2), pp. 69–86. doi:10.1111/jccm.1997.5.issue-2
  • Zahariadis, N., 2013, Leading reform amidst transboundary crises: Lessons from Greece. Public Administration, 91 (3), pp. 648–662.
  • Zahariadis, N., 2014, Powering over puzzling? downsizing the public sector during the Greek Sovereign debt crisis. Journal of Comparative Policy Analysis: Research and Practice, pp. 1–15. Published online. doi:10.1080/13876988.2013.861971

Reprints and Corporate Permissions

Please note: Selecting permissions does not provide access to the full text of the article, please see our help page How do I view content?

To request a reprint or corporate permissions for this article, please click on the relevant link below:

Academic Permissions

Please note: Selecting permissions does not provide access to the full text of the article, please see our help page How do I view content?

Obtain permissions instantly via Rightslink by clicking on the button below:

If you are unable to obtain permissions via Rightslink, please complete and submit this Permissions form. For more information, please visit our Permissions help page.