1,528
Views
0
CrossRef citations to date
0
Altmetric
Research Article

The interdependence of investment by different levels of government in a federal context

ORCID Icon & ORCID Icon
Pages 219-240 | Received 17 Dec 2019, Accepted 01 May 2021, Published online: 13 Jul 2021

ABSTRACT

We use the Stochastic Frontier Approach to analyse for the first time the regions’ investment response to the central and local governments’ capital expenditure. The Spanish context is very interesting for this analysis because responsibilities are distributed between the three levels of government in a very interesting dual way: the distribution of spending responsibilities between central and regional governments corresponds to an exclusionary attribution of functions, while between regional and local levels, governments opt for cooperation. Results show that capital expenditure undertaken by the central government in the regions acts as substitute for regional investment, while capital expenditure by local governments appears to complement it. These results should be taken into account by public administrations when designing the distribution of responsibilities between different levels of government and their economic policy aims.

1. Introduction

During the recent years of economic recession, several countries have started stimulus spending packages, in which sub-central governments have played a very important role in implementing investment recovery strategies (Del Bo & Sirtori, Citation2016). However, access to traditional sources of investment financing for governments is usually restricted in periods of recession, when public investment may be forced to play its traditional role of financial adjustment (Allain-Dupre, Hulbert, & Vammalle, Citation2012). In this context of budgetary austerity, each jurisdiction can react differently: raising tax pressure, increasing public indebtedness, or reducing public investment and other expenses, although they may also try to manage public capital expenditure more efficiently.

Alongside these strategies, we have recently observed how several of Spain’s regional governments have revised their Statutes of Autonomy, which provide the legislative framework for the sub-central political institutions, adding clauses which guarantee a minimum of direct investment in their region by the central government. The political justification for that rests on a hypothetical historical tort by the central government in terms of lower central investment in infrastructure in those territories, or lower per capita funds allocated to those jurisdictions by the national system for regional financing.

Investment by the central or local governments in a region may stimulate or reduce investment by the region itself in its territory, in the same way as public and private investment (crowding in/out effect), although as far as we know, there is no empirical evidence on the relationship between capital expenditure by the different levels of government in a federal context. Exploring this relationship should help us understand what is really behind the interest of the Spanish regions in guaranteeing a minimum investment by the central government ending the political debate around this issue. For this reason, and taking into account that in Spain the regions are the main agents of public investment (making 45% of total public investments), the aim of this paper is to evaluate whether direct investment in the regions, by the central government on one hand and by local governments on the other, have a stimulus or a contracting effect on regional investment, with the ultimate purpose of seeing whether the relationships between these investments are complementary or substitutional.

The Spanish case is very interesting for these analyses, because responsibilities are distributed among its three levels of government in two different ways, which may lead to investments by both levels of government (central and local) having different effects on regional capital expenditure. While the distribution of spending responsibilities between central and regional governments responds to an exclusionary attribution of functions, in distributions between the regional and local levels, these bodies opt for a framework of intensive cooperation in rural development policies and social welfare functions.

To conduct this study, we used a simple but interesting technique, based on frontier investment estimations, which we applied to the sample consisting of the 17 Spanish regions and the period 2000–2012. The results obtained show that investment by local and regional governments is complementary, and that investment by central and regional governments appears to be substitutional. This result is consistent with the distribution of responsibilities mentioned above, and could explain the interest of the regions in guaranteeing a minimum level of investment by the central government, insofar as this allows them to release funds for other purposes.

The work is structured as follows. The second section describes the state of the subject. The third section describes the frontier methodology, the model and the variables we use in our empirical approach. In the fourth section, we present our results. We end the work with our conclusions.

2. Problem statement

Spain is not strictly speaking federal, although it is as heavily politically and economically decentralised as any federal country (İrepoğlu , Citation2016). The 1978 Constitution (Constitución Española, CE) establishes three levels of government: central, regional, and local; Part VIII of the Constitution sets out the core areas of the decentralisation process, assigning the State exclusive powers (Article 149) to ensure the unity and identity of the Spanish economic system and national economic policy and regulate the sectors with significant externalities. All other matters correspond to the Autonomous Regions (art. 149.3) if they are included in their Statutes of Autonomy or in Article 148 of the CE (Lopez-Laborda, Martinez-Vazquez, & Monasterio, Citation2007). Responsibilities at the local level, which consists of municipalities and provinces, are intended to meet the needs of local people and to complement those of other administrations (according to the law establishing the basis of local governance: Ley de Bases del Régimen Local, LBRL). This distribution of responsibilities means that Spain’s regional governments are now the ones making the most public spending and investments (Catalina, Citation2009).

There are two regional funding regimes: the “‘Foral’” system in the Basque Country and Navarre, and the “‘common’” system applicable in the other fifteen regions. With the Foral system, the Basque Country and Navarre have greater tax autonomy, with practically all tax revenue at their disposal to fund their regional public services, and have to make a contribution to the central government to fund central spending in their territory. In contrast, the 15 regions in the common funding system have the revenue from the taxes established as their own and the state taxes assigned to them, and the transfers from the central government (Autonomous Regions Funding Act, LOFCA). This financing system relegates the funding of regional capital expenditure (Blöchliger & King, Citation2006; Lago, Citation2006) to current savings, to borrowing and to income from capital transfers, these last from three sources: European Union funds (EUF), which require co-financing of 15%-85% of the investment; the national Inter-territorial Compensation Fund (ICF),Footnote1 which does not require co-financing; and other transfers which finance part of the investment projects agreed bilaterally (centre-region), without co-financing. However, as the distribution of capital transfers tends to exclude the most developed territories,Footnote2 this obliges the wealthier regions to make more intensive use of savings or borrowing to finance their investment; although given the increasing restrictions on regional debt (budget stability requirements) and the limited tax capacity of regional governments, transfers are increasingly important (Bahl & Bird, Citation2013).

Different indicators (population, regional income, or size of area) can be used to compare the relative supply of public capital in each region, which clearly leads to controversy when attempting a comparison between jurisdictions. However, regardless of the indicator used to compare them, the large differences between the regions are always clearly revealed (see the first half of ). This heterogeneity in distribution of the stock of public capital between regions has led to several regional governments trying to consolidate a certain “obligatory” participation by central investment in their territory, always responding to the criterion which most favours each of the regions: Andalusia, the Region of Valencia, and the Balearic Islands have managed to get the participation of the central government calculated according to population; Aragon, according to surface area; Catalonia, according to its weight in GDP, etc.

Table 1. Territorial distribution of the stock of public capital

If each region selects the indicator that most benefits it, and more regions join in making these demands, it will be impossible for the central government to comply with all these requirements at the same time (Cucarella, Citation2011). As shown in the column “best option” in , this would require a central investment 40.8% higher than the current amount. Moreover, the current investments committed to according to the best criterion would be nearly 60% of the total amount distributed, leaving just a little over 40% to be distributed among the remaining eleven regions. This could reduce investment in regions which do not have this clause in their Statutes of Autonomy.

To understand the regional interest underlying the clauses being adopted by some regions, we will quantify the stimulus effect of direct investments by the central government on the investment of regional jurisdictions. This will let us see whether investments by central and regional levels of government have a relationship of complementarity, which would support and justify these demands (based on arguments of inequities in the stock of capital or lack of funds for investment). However, if the relationship is substitutional, with central government investment being a disincentive for regional investment, the argument behind these clauses is probably more spurious, with the intention of releasing funds for purposes other than capital expenditure. Similarly, we will extend the analysis to study the relationship of complementarity or substitutability between local and regional public investments, as although the degree of financial autonomy of the local level of government is very similar to the regional level,Footnote3 the philosophy underlying the distribution of responsibilities between these sub-central levels of government is different.

For this study, we will need to know the territorial distribution of investment by the different levels of government, which is possible in Spain thanks to the complex task of territorialising the expenditure of the different public administrations, carried out by Uriel and Barberán (Citation2007) and the Fundación BBVA e Ivie (Instituto Valenciano de Investigaciones Económicas)-BBVA Foundation and Valencian institute of Economic Investigations (Citation2015), and later taken on by the Finance Ministry. Therefore, the availability of this information will dictate the period to be studied.

3. Frontier of capital expenditure and investment gap

3.1. Methodology

Any level of government has incentives to try to guarantee external sources of profits, transfers, or investments, regardless of the agents’ own expenditure decisions. However, the literature has shown that the effects of a transfer on expenditure depend on the amount of the transfer, and the spending habits and preferences of the receiving government (Rego, Citation2002). Fiscal federalism theory (Bradford & Oates, Citation1971) shows us that if the income elasticity of capital expenditure is greater than 1, when it receives the transfer the receiving government will take funds from current spending to allocate to investment. If the receiving governments are required to co-finance a percentage of the subsidised capital goods (matching grants), the donor and receiving administrations will share the investment cost, reducing the price of capital expenditure for the receiver. In this case, the final result will also depend on the price elasticity of capital expenditure: if it is greater than 1, the receiving government will take funds from other uses and allocate them to capital goods, while if less than 1, part of the transfer will be allocated to current expenditure. In other words, when the transfer is co-financed, a substitution effect is added which reinforces the expansion of capital. Meanwhile, as long as a conditional grant stimulates investment beyond the preferences of the jurisdiction, there will be incentives for the jurisdiction to work towards its own preferences and divert resources to other purposes (Bradford & Oates, Citation1971; Petchey & MacDonald, Citation2007). In this way, if there is a strong leakage effect, a conditional grant (or a capital investment by another level of government, as these are equivalent from the point of view of economics) will essentially be equivalent to an unconditional grant, and will therefore have a very limited effect on investment.

However, the free rider problem which can arise from transfers, due to the different preferences of the receiving regions, can be prevented if the region is required to co-finance or maintain its tax effort (Zampelli, Citation1986). This could favour a “bandwagon effect” pulling resources towards investment (Sagbas & Tolga, Citation2008), leading the receiving government to make a greater investment effort than its available resources permit, taking resources from current expenditure which will be abandoned, or obtaining them from other sources, such as borrowing or taxes. On the other hand, an exclusionary distribution of spending functions between the donor and receiving governments, as in the Spanish case, makes such co-financing impossible, so that in this context there will be no substitution effect reinforcing the expansion of capital expenditure, making it more likely that spending will leak or be diverted towards other purposes.

Although a review of the extensive empirical literature on transfers and their incentives is outside the scope of this,Footnote4 it is worth paying attention to studies which analyse certain distorting effects, such as the flypaper effect (Hines & Thaler, Citation1995); the fungibility effect (Islam, Citation1998;; González-Alegre, Citation2012); the crowding out effect on private investment (Xu & Yan, Citation2014); displacement effects on the composition of domestic public spending, from both a thematic and a geographical perspective (Del Bo & Sirtori, Citation2016); or the gapfilling effect, by which central government bails out local governments in fiscal distress, giving them incentives to spend beyond their revenues (Brun & El Khdari, Citation2016). Other papers analyse how fiscal equalization transfers distort the fiscal policies of recipient governments, because their taxes and expenditures can affect the parameters of the grant formula, thereby affecting the size of their grant (Buettner, Citation2006). The literature also studies the different effects of transfers according to the characteristics of the regions (Becker, Egger, Von Ehrlich, & Fenge, Citation2010). And recently, some authors have modelled the effect of sub-central tax autonomy on transfer efficiency (Volden, Citation2007; Kappeler, Solé-Ollé, Stephan, & Välilä, Citation2013; González-Alegre, Citation2015).

The theoretical model underlying our empirical exercise is based on the conventional mathematical development of budget balancing (Bahl & Bird, Citation2013; Buiter, Citation2001; Dabla-Norris, Brumby, Kyobe, Mills, & Papageorgiou, Citation2012; Pack & Rothenberg, Citation1993), to which we add the institutional, tax, and political incentives introduced by second-generation fiscal federalism (Weingast, Citation2014). This approach allows us to take into account the stimuli affecting regional governments, arising from use of borrowing and its institutional restrictions, transfers, and the demand for co-financing, which must come from current savings.

The starting point would thus be the expression [1], which reflects the budget restriction facing any government and connects its public investment (INV) with the financing sources for that investment; in other words, with income from capital transfers (TRANS), current savings (SAVE), and net borrowing (BORROW).

(1) INV=SAVE+TRANS+BORROW(1)

However, as this is merely an accounting expression, it cannot capture the stimuli or disincentives affecting the investment behaviour of regional governments, such as those relating to the functioning of the political market and vote-seeking, which are often left out of economic analysis. There are significant political benefits derived from using borrowing and getting aid from other levels of government, insofar as these are financing mechanisms which make it possible to enjoy the benefits associated with the availability of public assets while avoiding paying for them (moral hazard problem). This has led to the appearance of a set of tax rules, such as requiring budget stability, or that borrowing and capital transfers must only finance investment costs. These tax rules are intended to protect the solvency of the public sector, but they can distort the investment behaviour of regional governments, favouring or discouraging investment, altering its composition (a mix of current and capital expenditure), and even incentivising the use of a little “creative accounting” (Buiter, Citation2001; Milesi-Feretti, Citation2003; Dabla-Norris et al., Citation2012).

For this reason, in this paper we have considered that investment is the output of the regional governments’ policy,Footnote5 and we have connected it with the sources of financing using stochastic frontier analysis (SFA).Footnote6 This methodology will allow us, first, to determine the maximum potential investment which regions can reach for financial resources and other factors (yM), such as the stock of available capital,Footnote7 and a set of institutional factors which enable us to adapt the theoretical model to the context of Spanish institutions and which may condition regional investment capacity.Footnote8 Second, to compare the real capital expenditure by each region to their potential expenditure; in other words, to determine the region’s investment gap (u). Including this investment gap in the equation (2), explaining the investment output, lets us correct the problem of the existing empirical literature, which assumes the total efficiency of the public sector, even when there is no empirical or theoretical basis for such a supposition (Dabla-Norris et al., Citation2012). And third, to identify and quantify the explanatory hypotheses (k) which enable us to understand this investment gap (u), shown in equation (3).

Thus, SFA facilitates the construction of a frontier within which the regions with the maximum investment level, given certain financial resources and characteristics, would be located. The distance from the real to the potential investment is the potential investment not achieved. If investment by local or central government increases the gap or distance from regional investment in terms of potential or frontier investment, this would be a disincentive effect of the central/local investment in that region (crowding out effect), or in other words, there would be a relationship of substitutability between investments by both levels of government. If, on the other hand, the distance to potential or frontier investment is reduced, this would demonstrate a relationship of complementarity between both investment policies, or the existence of a crowding in effect.

As far as we know, there is no literature analysing this phenomenon in the federal government context, so our proposal provides novel empirical evidence on the interdependence of`public investments by different levels of government.

For these calculations we use panel data for the 17 Spanish regions and for the 13 years for which we have information (2000–2012). The stochastic frontier technique is implemented with the following regression model with two error terms:

(2) INVit= β0+ β1TRANSit+β2SAVEit+ β3BORROWit+ ΣMφMyMit+ vit uit(2)

where the output INVit is the capital expenditure of the region i in year t in terms of its income, with i = 1, 2, …, 17 and t = 2000, …, 2012; β0 is the common constant for all the regions, and β1, β2, β3 are the parameters of the three sources of funding for regional investment: TRANS, SAVE, and BORROW,Footnote9 all of them measured in terms of regional income.Footnote10 We expect they have a positive effect on regional investment. yMit identifies regions with special characteristics: the regions with the highest level of responsibility (RESPONS),Footnote11 for which the expected effect is, a priori, undetermined because although these regions have assumed responsibility for education and healthcare, these responsibilities are labour-intensive; the single-province regions (SINGLE), which assumed the responsibilities and projects of their respective Provincial Governments, so we expect a positive effect for this variable; and the regions with the greatest tax autonomy, as a consequence of their unique (foral) financing systems (FINAN). The expected sign for FINAN is, a priori, undetermined depending on the preferences of these foral regions. We also include a dummy variable (RULE) for the 2002’s budget balancing rule to strengthen financial solvency, which removed the borrowing as a source of funding, as well as discouraged the political benefits associated with the use of borrowing; and the stock of regional public capital available in per capita terms (STOCK). To consider the stock of capital available at the start of the year, we have lagged this variable by one financial year. The expected sign for both variables is negative, because the obstacles to the use of borrowing (RULE) will probably hinder investment, and the regions with the largest supply of capital (STOCK) will have lower investment needs, and their potential investment will be less.

The definition and source of the variables can be seen in of the Appendix. shows the main descriptive statistics and the correlation matrix.

The error term vit is the statistical noise, and the error term uit captures the investment gap or distance to the potential investment, so uit is our key dependent variable, and depends on variables, kit.

(3) uit=δkit+εit,(3)

where ɛit is the error term.

The variables, kit, explaining the gap or unrealised potential investment, u, are the following. A first group of budget variables, including the two key variables of our study: investment in the region by the central government on one hand (FEDERALINV) and by local governments on the other (LOCALINV), which will enable us to measure the relationship of complementarity or substitutability between central or local and regional investments. As we have pointed above, if investment by central government (FEDERALINV) increases the gap or unrealised potential investment, u, i.e., shows a positive sign, there would be a relationship of substitutability between investments by both levels of government. This is what can be expected from the exclusionary attribution of spending responsibilities between central and regional governments. If investment by local government (LOCALINV) reduces the distance to potential or frontier investment, i.e., shows a negative sign, this would demonstrate a relationship of complementarity between both investment policies, or the existence of a crowding in effect, as can be expected from the cooperation of local and regional governments. We have also included in this group of variables the regional tax revenues (TAX) and the interaction between regional income from capital transfers and tax revenues (TRANSEFFICIENCY-TAX), in response to theoretical approaches which affirm that the efficiency of capital transfers, in terms of capacity to increase investment, depends on the degree of tax autonomy (González-Alegre, Citation2015; Kappeler et al., Citation2013). The expected sign for these two variables is negative, i.e., we expect that a larger fiscal autonomy makes intergovernmental grants more effective in raising public investment. Moreover, we have considered the financial expenditure (FEXP), which would be a measure of the capacity to co-finance new investments (negative expected effect); and the current expenditure (CEXP) to test whether the regions opting or obliged to prioritise the provision of current or personal goods and services are further from their potential investment (positive expected effect). All this group of variables are measured in terms of regional income.

A second group would include socioeconomic variables, such as per capita income (INCOME) and the population density of the region (DENSITY). The expected sign for INCOME is negative, as investment and income are directed related, so the gap will probably be minor. However, the sign of DENSITY is, a priori, undetermined because it is an indicator of the relative need for investment, but it can also reflect the economies of scale. We have also included a variable (CRISIS) to identify the years of economic recession (2008–2012), expecting a positive sign for its.

Third, we consider a variable relating to management, which measures the fungibility of finally executed capital expenditure compared to budgeted amounts (QGEST), intended to approximate the quality of the investment project managers. A positive sign for this variable means management quality is lower, so the investment gap is likely to be larger.

And finally, we have included such political factors as political ideology (IDEOLOGY), the percentage of votes obtained (SUPPORT), the electoral cycle (ELECT) and whether the central and regional governments are from the same party (ALIGNED). In the year before regional elections there should be a greater investment effort, i.e., the expected sign for ELECT would be negative. However, the expected sign of the other political variables would, a priori, be undetermined. The lower the competition and its control over the governing party, the greater the investment effort should be (the Leviathan hypothesis), although the opposite sign, indicating a slackening of investment effort, is also possible. And something similar occurs when the party in power in the regional government is the same as the national governing party.

The variables are in logarithms.Footnote12

3.2. Results

We have estimated with panel data (2000–2012) and in one step, the following stochastic frontier model with true random effects (Greene, Citation2005; Belotti, Daidone, Ilardi, & Atella, Citation2013),Footnote13 in which the error term u excludes unobserved heterogeneity:

(4) INV=fTRANS,BORROW,SAVE,RESPON,SINGLE,FINAN,RULE,STOCK +vu(4)
(5) u=g(FEDERALINV,LOCALINV,TAX,TRANSEFFICIENCYTAX,FEXP,CEXP,INCOME,DENSITY,QGEST,SUPPORT,IDEOLOGY,ELECT,ALIGNED,CRISIS)(5)

Table 2. Results of the stochastic frontier analysis of investment

The results are shown in Model 1 of . Model 2 of , to which we refer later, takes into account the fact of differences in the volume of transfers received according to the region’s income level. The significance of the estimator λ in indicates the rejection of the null hypothesis that γ = σu22 = 0. This confirms the suitability of SFA as a study method in this case; in other words, the need to include unrealised potential investment, u, in the investment capacity function, which should not be estimated using a mean behaviour function (OLS). The significance of parameter θ of variance in unobserved heterogeneity, also shown in , suggests that unobserved heterogeneity of the regions must be separated from the investment gap, validating the approximation we use from Greene (Citation2005).

To determine whether the endogeneity problems affect a series of variables (i.e., TRANS, BORROW, FEDERALINV, LOCALINV, TAX, FEXP and CEXP), we have applied the two-stage Hausman procedure and calculated the Durbin and Wu-Hausman statistics, which can be seen in of the Appendix. For this, we take as instrumental variables the lagged variables themselves or their rate of variation, as well as regional income and the weight of the agricultural sector in regional income, checking their validity with the Sargan and Basmann tests (which can also be seen in the last columns of ). The output of Wu-Hausman and Durbin tests show that we cannot reject the null hypothesis of exogeneity of the variables. The Sargan and Basmann tests present strong evidence that we cannot reject the null hypothesis that the overidentifying restrictions are valid. The validity of the instruments used ratifies the Wu-Hausman and Durbin tests.

The top of model 1 in indicates which variables explain the potential investment of regional governments (equation (4)). Specifically, income from capital transfers (TRANS) is the main financing source (12.1%), which is in line with the roles of these resources in the regional financing model. Moreover, the single-province regions (SINGLE) have greater potential investment capacity. However, the level of responsibility (RESPON) which, as we explained earlier, is associated with having assumed responsibility for education and healthcare, appears to reduce potential investment, probably because both responsibilities are labour-intensive (the salaries represent 56% of education and healthcare expenditure, while general government services represent only 20%). Also, while spending on salaries is committed, the same is not true of investment, so that spending cuts tend to reduce investment disproportionately, rather than current expenditure (Mintz & Smart, Citation2006).

The model also shows that the regions with the largest supply of capital stock per capita (STOCK) show less need for investment, leading to lower potential investment.

Spanish regions use 59% to 76% of their potential investment, depending on the model 1 or 2 considered (this can be seen at the bottom of , in the row “Average investment effort”). The distance to the frontier is the unrealised potential investment or investment gap. Many of the variables considered in the explanation of this gap (equation (4)) are significant and have the theoretically expected sign.Footnote14 As for the basic hypotheses we want to test, there is some empirical evidence that capital expenditure by the central government acting directly in the regions (FEDERALINV) may act as a substitute for regional investment (at 10% significance), as the distance increases between effective and potential regional investment, i.e., the coefficient of FEDERALINV is positive. In contrast, capital expenditure by local governments (LOCALINV) seems to complement regional spending, insofar as it reduces the investment gap in the region. These results are in line with the regulations on the distribution of responsibilities between levels of government which we saw in the introduction. The allocation of functions between central and regional governments stated in the CE has in most cases enabled a relationship of substitutability between the capital expenditures of both levels of government. In general, responsibilities are assumed exclusively by the central government, and the central infrastructure articulates the regional territory, thus mitigating the need for regional investment. Meanwhile, the regions and their local governments have followed the criteria established in the LBRL regarding the need to complement and coordinate the main local policies on social services, environment, sport, healthcare, tourism, education, town planning and local development; the general tendency is to share activities relating to design and planning, and leave execution in the hands of Town Councils, who also usually receive grants or subsidies from the regional government for these functions.Footnote15

Despite the strict financial restrictions imposed on the regions, those which prioritise providing goods and services to their citizens (CEXP) do not seem to do so at the cost of lower capital expenditure, and so they are also closer to their potential investment levels, since its coefficient is negative. Regarding the variable relating to the management of capital projects, we can observe that if public managers are less skilled (QGEST), measured by the distance between executed and budgeted regional investment, there is a greater distance between potential and real investment. The results also indicate that the investment gap is inversely related to the region’s income level (INCOME), and that according to the ideology of the governing party, left-wing governments are nearer the frontier (IDEOLOGY).

To take into account the fact of differences in the volume of transfers received according to the region’s income level, we have interacted in model 2 of each one of the variables TRANSEFFICIENCY-TAX, FEDERALINV and LOCALINV, with a dummy which captures the main regions receiving transfers (POORREGION), which are those constituting the objective of the territorial rebalancing policy. Although the significance of some control variables may change with these interactions, the two variables we are interested in are found to be robust. Also, the significance and value of the coefficients of some variables of the model seem to improve considerably with these interactions. They especially accentuate the effect of capital expenditure by the central government (FEDERALINV) on the regional investment gap, which would indicate that the substitutability relationship between central and regional investment is more marked in the most disadvantaged regions, which are the ones receiving the most funds. The coefficient of the variable interacting transfers and tax revenues (TRANSEFFICIENCY-TAX) is significant when interacted with the dummy POORREGION. Its positive sign means that a larger fiscal autonomy makes intergovernmental grants less effective – in raising public investment – in poor regions. This result, which seems to go against what we would expect in theory, is also obtained for the Spanish case in González-Alegre (Citation2015).Footnote16

On the other hand, the most dynamic regions, where the population tends to concentrate with greater density (DENSITY), which is an indicator of the relative need for investment and differential costs (economies of scale), now show a significant and positive coefficient, indicating a greater investment gap. The variable which captures the electoral support of the governments (SUPPORT) is also significant now, and shows how governments with large majorities, or which are subject to less control due to the weakness of their political rivals, tend to move further away from their potential investment levels (Bahl & Bird, Citation2013). This result seems to prove that when pacts are necessary due to the precarious position of the ruling party, investment expenditure expands, getting closer to its potential level. The period of economic crisis or budget stress (CRISIS) increases the gap between potential and actual investment (Allain-Dupré, Citation2011).

4. Conclusions

This work presents the first empirical investigation of the relationship between investments by the different levels of government in a federal context. Specifically, we evaluate whether direct investments in the regions, by the central government on one hand and by local governments on the other, have a stimulating or a contracting effect on regional investment, with the ultimate purpose of seeing whether the relationships between these investments are complementary or substitutional. To do this, we use a technique which is increasingly popular in public economics studies, the Stochastic Frontier Approach, which lets us determine, on one hand, the potential or frontier investment each region could achieve with the resources available to it and its institutional situation, and the gap or distance from the real investment to that frontier; and on the other, the factors explaining that gap. This way, we will be able to measure the regions’ investment response both to direct investment by central and local governments, and to other relevant variables.

For the Spanish case these estimates are made for two reasons. First, because fortunately we have data on the territorial distribution of investment by different levels of government over a long enough period for study. And second, because responsibilities are distributed between the three levels of government (central, regional and local) in Spain in a very interesting dual way, providing a particular scenario for analysis which can help to explain the different results obtained according to the level of government considered.

The results obtained clearly show that investments by local and regional governments are complementary, a reasonable result given that responsibilities are distributed between both levels of government based on a philosophy of cooperation. In contrast, there are signs that investments by the central government and by regions may be substitutional. This could explain the regions’ interest in establishing a guaranteed minimum investment in their Statutes of Autonomy. This substitutability relationship could suggest the need for a capital expenditure co-financing policy between the regions and the central government, which would probably require the absence of legislation which distributes expenditure functions in an exclusionary manner. This could counter the free rider effect to some extent, by introducing the right stimuli to strengthen regional investment policies and generate crowding-in effects in public investment, and reduce regional governments’ incentives to demand higher central investment.

The connection observed between the distribution of responsibilities among levels of government and the results obtained could serve as a guide for other countries to preview the potential relationship between the investments of their levels of government (substitutional or complementary) and the distribution of responsibilities established in their regulations (exclusionary or cooperative).

A different approach to that taken in this paper could consist of analysing how investment by the central government (or by local governments) in the region is affected by the investments of other government levels, an aspect which we leave for future research.

Disclosure Statement

No potential conflict of interest was reported by the author(s).

Additional information

Funding

This work was supported by the Spanish Ministry of Science, Innovation and Universities, the Spanish State Research Agency, and the European Regional Development Fund [Project RTI2018-095799-B-I00]; Regional Government of Aragón and the European Regional Development Fund (Public Economics Research Group).

Notes on contributors

Anabel Zárate-Marco

Anabel Zárate-Marco received her Ph. D. Degree in 1999. She is profesor of Public Economics at the University of Zaragoza (Spain). Her main research areas are taxation, tax planning and fiscal federalism. She has published numerous papers in different leading journals.

Jaime Vallés-Giménez

Jaime Vallés-Giménez received his Ph. D. Degree in 1999. He is profesor of Public Economics at the University of Zaragoza (Spain). His main research areas are fiscal federalism, taxation, and tax planning. He has published numerous papers in different leading journals and has headed several research projects.

Notes

1 These are studied in Fernández-Leiceaga, Lago, and Álvarez (Citation2013).

2 The first two funds only apply to regions with per capita income below 75% of the European average, and must be allocated to financing capital expenditure (although since 2001, one third of ICF resources can be allocated to financing current expenditure linked to maintenance of previous investments). Thus, they are instruments of inter-territorial solidarity, intended to reduce gaps in regional development levels. For a recent study of the effect of Cohesion Funds on economic growth, see Berkowitz, Monfort, and Pieńkowski (Citation2019).

3 The main source of revenues for Spanish municipalities is taxation, followed by transfers, which provide 62% and 35% of their resources respectively, and most of the transfers come from the central government.

4 The work of Bergvall, Charbit, Kraan, and Merk (Citation2006), Boadway and Shah (Citation2007), and Brun and El Khdari (Citation2016) can be consulted for a deeper understanding of intergovernmental transfers in a federal context.

5 It includes both direct investment and transfers, insofar as the region can make the investment directly or transfer funds to the private sector for them to invest. This enables to avoid the risks arising from the possible substitutability and interdependence of different types of investment.

6 SFA, suggested by Aigner, Lovell, and Schmidt (Citation1977) and Meeusen and Van Den Broeck (Citation1977) to examine producer behaviour, although it is an emerging methodology in the field of intergovernmental relations and incentives, has been implemented recently to analyse other aspects of public economics by Pessino and Fenochietto (Citation2010), Alm and Duncan (Citation2014), Karnik and Raju (Citation2015), Garg et al (Citation2017), Niaounakis and Blank (Citation2017), and others.

7 As shown in the traditional theoretical approach of Gramlich (Citation1969), Bradford and Oates (Citation1971), and Mehrotra and Välilä (Citation2006).

8 Non-frontier analyses only estimate the mean of the investment. If we were using methods based on the OLS technique, we would make the mistake of considering the random component of the residual as investment effort (Rao, Citation1993).

9 Here it should be borne in mind that Spain conditioned the use of borrowing to fund regional investment, stimulating capital over current expenditures, as well as strengthening intergenerational equity.

10 This lets us talk in terms of the capacity to obtain financial resources, and avoid the discrepancies the different dimensions of the regions would introduce. This is a regular practice in the conventional literature (i.e., Buiter, Citation2001) and even by the European Union when setting legal limits for debt and deficit.

11 The CE discriminates between two types of regions: regions with a high level of responsibility (art. 151) and regions with a low level of responsibility (art. 143), depending on whether they assume responsibility for education and healthcare (which represent around 60–70% of total regional spending, according to Las haciendas autonómicas en cifras,Ministerio de Hacienda-Ministry of Finance and Civil Service (various years)). In practice, the regions with high levels of responsibility experienced a higher level of fiscal autonomy in the beginning, but the gap between both types of regions has been reduced as the decentralization process has been taking place (González-Alegre, Citation2015).

12 The use of logarithms lets us obtain elasticities directly, as well as certain advantages in estimation, such as reducing heteroscedasticity and multicollinearity problems (Auci, Castelli, & Vignani, Citation2011)

13 The Hausman test, shown at the end of , suggests that the True Random Effects model (TRE) is preferable to the True Fixed Effects model (TFE).

14 We have also tested other variables. We tested different definitions of the SING variable, which we include to explain the investment potential of the region. To explain the incentive effects on regional investment, we also tested the weight of the agricultural sector in regional income, and population, as alternative socioeconomic variables, as well as a variable identifying the regions governed by nationalist/separatist parties, and another which captures whether the party in the regional government is the same as the national governing party (Bugarin & Marciniuk, Citation2017; Garofalo, Citation2019), electoral years, and special treatment of the archipelagos in development policy, among others. However, they all produced less satisfactory results.

15 For this reason, occasionally there is considered to be a problem of duplication of responsibility for spending at the local level, where there may actually be a relationship of cooperation or complementarity of functions.

16 Fernández-Leiceaga et al. (Citation2013) also show how poor regions divert resources towards reducing debt or savings effort, or even towards non-productive capital expenditure (education and healthcare).

References

  • Aigner, D., Lovell, K., & Schmidt, P. (1977). Formulation and estimation of stochastic frontier production function models. Journal of Econometrics, 6(1), 21–37.
  • Allain-Dupré, D. (2011): Multi-level Governance of Public Investment: Lessons from the Crisis. OECD Regional Development Working Papers, 2011/05, OECD Publishing, Paris.
  • Allain-Dupre, D., Hulbert, C., & Vammalle, C. (2012): Public Investment at Central and Sub-National Levels: An Adjustment Variable for OECD Countries in the Present Context of Austerity? OECD Workshop on Effective Public Investment at Sub-National levels in Times of Fiscal Constraints: Meeting the Coordination and Capacity Challenges, 21st June 2012.OECD Conference Centre, Paris
  • Alm, J., & Duncan, D. (2014). An International Comparison of Tax Agency Efficiency. Public Budgeting and Finance, 34(3), 90–110.
  • Auci, S., Castelli, A., & Vignani, D. (2011): “Local or National Environmental Spending in Italy: A Stochastic Frontier Analysis”, MPRA Paper No. 58621.
  • Bahl, R., & Bird, R. (2013): Decentralization and infrastructure in developing countries: Reconciling principles and practice. IMFG papers on Municipal Finance and Governance Papers 16.
  • BD.Mores, Base de datos regionales de la economía española-Regional database of the Spanish economy (2017), Secretaría de Estado de Presupuestos y Gastos-Secretariat of State for Budgets and Expenditure (Ministerio de Hacienda-Ministry of Finance and Civil Service). http://www.sepg.pap.minhafp.gob.es/sitios/sepg/es-ES/Presupuestos/Documentacion/paginas/basesdatosestudiosregionales.aspx
  • Becker, S. O., Egger, P., Von Ehrlich, M., & Fenge, R. (2010). Going NUTS: The effect of EU Structural Funds on regional performance. Journal of Public Economics, 94(9–10), 57.
  • Belotti, F., Daidone, S., Ilardi, G., & Atella, V. (2013). Stochastic frontier analysis using Stata. The Stata Journal, 13(4), 1–39.
  • Bergvall, D., Charbit, C., Kraan, D., & Merk, O. (2006). Intergovernmental Grants and Decentralized Public Spending. OECD Journal of Budgeting, 5(4), 112–158.
  • Berkowitz, P., Monfort, P., & Pieńkowski, J. 2019. Unpacking the growth impacts of European Union Cohesion Policy: Transmission channels from Cohesion Policy into economic growth. Regional Studies, 01 Apr 2019 forthcoming https://doi.org/10.1080/00343404.2019.1570491
  • Blöchliger, H., & King, D. (2006). Less than you thought: The fiscal autonomy of sub-central governments. OECD Economic Studies, 43(2), Paris.
  • Boadway, R., & Shah, A. (eds). (2007). Intergovernmental Fiscal Transfers. Washington, D. C.: The World Bank.
  • Bradford, D. F., & Oates, W. E. (1971). Towards a predictive theory of intergovernmental grants. American Economic Review, 61(2), 440–448.
  • Brun, J. F., & El Khdari, M. (2016): “The incentive effects of conditional and unconditional transfers on local own revenue generation: Empirical evidence from Moroccan municipalities”. Document de travail, Centre d’Études et de Recherches sur le Développement International, 06.
  • Buettner, T. (2006). The incentive effect of fiscal equalization transfers on tax policy. Journal of Public Economics, 90(3), 477–497.
  • Bugarin, M., & Marciniuk, F. (2017). Strategic partisan transfers in a fiscal federation: Evidence from a new Brazilian database. Journal of Applied Economics, 20(2), 211–239.
  • Buiter, W. H. (2001). Notes on ‘A Code for Fiscal Stability’. Oxford Economic Papers, 53(1), 1–19.
  • Catalina, A. (2009): “Public investment in Spain”, European Union, Regional Policy, Regional Focus, n° 02/2009.
  • Cucarella, V. (2011): “La difícil aritmética de los estatutos de autonomía”, in http://decigarrasyhormigas.com/, Ivie blog, April 2011.
  • Dabla-Norris, E., Brumby, J., Kyobe, A., Mills, Z., & Papageorgiou, C. (2012). Investing in Public Investment: An Index of Public Investment Efficiency. Journal of Economic Growth, 17(3), 235–266.
  • Del Bo, C., & Sirtori, E. (2016). Additionality and regional public finance – Evidence from Italy. Environment and Planning. C, Government & Policy, 34(5), 855–878.
  • Fernández-Leiceaga, X., Lago, S., & Álvarez, X. (2013): “The spanish inter-territorial compensation fund: analysis and reform proposals”, Munich Personal RePEc Archive, Paper 51107.
  • Fundación BBVA e Ivie (Instituto Valenciano de Investigaciones Económicas)-BBVA Foundation and Valencian institute of Economic Investigations (2015): Series históricas de capital público en España y su distribución territorial (1900-2012). http://www.fbbva.es/TLFU/tlfu/esp/areas/econosoc/bbdd/Capital_Publico.jsp
  • Garg, S., A. Goyal, and R. Pal (2017). Why Tax Effort falls Short of Capacity in Indian States: A Stochastic Frontier Approach. Public Finance Review, 45(2), 232–259
  • Garofalo, P. J. (2019). Strategic spending in federal governments: Theory and evidence from the US. Journal of Applied Economics, 22(1), 243–272.
  • González-Alegre, J. (2015). Does Fiscal Decentralization Affect the Effectiveness of Intergovernmental Grants? European Regional Policy and Spanish Autonomous Regions. Papers in Regional Science, 94(4), 817–847.
  • González-Alegre, J. G. (2012). An evaluation of EU regional policy. Do structural actions crowd out public spending? Public Choice, 151(1), 1–21.
  • Gramlich, M. (1969). State and Local Governments and their Budget Constraint. Lnternational Economic Review, 10, 163–182.
  • Greene, W. H. (2005). Fixed and random effects in stochastic frontier models. Journal of Productivity Analysis, 23(1), 7–32.
  • Hines, J. R., Jr., & Thaler, R. H. (1995). Anomalies: The Flypaper Effect. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 9(4), 217–226.
  • İrepoğlu Carreras, Y. (2016). Fiscal decentralization and inequality: The case of Spain. Regional Studies, 3(1), 295–302.
  • Islam, M. N. (1998). Fungibility of matching conditional grants to local governments. Papers in Regional Science: The Journal of the RSAI, 77(4), 361–373.
  • Kappeler, A., Solé-Ollé, A., Stephan, A., & Välilä, T. (2013). Does Fiscal Decentralization Foster Regional Investment in Productive Infrastructure. European Journal of Political Economy, 31, 15–25.
  • Karnik, A., & Raju, S. (2015). State Fiscal Capacity and Tax Effort: Evidence for Indian States. South Asian Journal of Macroeconomics and Public Finance, 4(2), 141–177.
  • Lago, S. (2006). Capital grants and regional public investment in Spain: Fungibility of aid or crowding in effect. Applied Economics, 38(15), 1737–1747.
  • Lopez-Laborda, J., Martinez-Vazquez, J., & Monasterio, C. (2007). Kingdom of Spain. In A. Shah (Ed.), The practice of fiscal federalism: Comparative perspectives (pp. 287–316). Montreal: McGill-Queen’s University Press.
  • Meeusen, W., & Van Den Broeck, J. (1977). Efficiency estimation from Cobb-Douglas production functions with composed errors. International Economic Review, 18(2), 435–444.
  • Mehrotra, A., & Välilä, T. (2006). Public investment in Europe: Evolution and determinants in perspective. Fiscal Studies, 27(4), 443–471.
  • Milesi-Feretti, G. M. (2003). Good, bad or ugly? On the effects of fiscal rules with creative accounting. Journal of Public Economics, 88(1–2), 377–394.
  • Ministerio de Hacienda–Ministry of Finance and Civil Service (various years): Las haciendas autonómicas en cifras, Madrid. http://www.hacienda.gob.es/es-ES/CDI/Paginas/SistemasFinanciacionDeuda/InformacionCCAAs/haciendas%202005.aspx
  • Mintz, J. M., & Smart, M. (2006), Incentives for Public Investment under Fiscal Rules, World Bank Policy Research Working Paper No. 3860.
  • Niaounakis, T., & Blank, J. (2017). Inter-municipal cooperation, economies of scale, and cost efficiency: An application of stochastic frontier analysis to Dutch municipal tax departments. Local Government Studies, 43(4), 533–554.
  • Pack, H., & Rothenberg, J. (1993). Foreign Aid and the Question of Fungibility. The Review of Economics and Statistics, 75, 258–265.
  • Pessino, C., & Fenochietto, R. (2010). Determining Countries’ Tax Effort. Hacienda Pública Española/Revista De Economía Pública, 195(4), 65–87.
  • Petchey, J., & MacDonald, G. (2007). Financing capital expenditure through grants. In R. Boadway & A. Shah (Eds.), Intergovernmental Fiscal Transfers. Principles and Practice (pp. 425–452). Washington D.C: The World Bank.
  • Rao, H. (1993): Taxable Capacity Tax-efforts and forecasts of tax-yield of Indian States. Institute for Social and economic Change research (ISEC). http://203.200.22.249:8080/handle/123456789/9760
  • Rego, G. (2002). Las transferencias y sus efectos sobre el gasto. Una aproximación. Revista Galega De Economía, 11(1), 1–24.
  • Sagbas, I., & Tolga, N. (2008). the surge impact of the flypaper, substitution and stimulation effect on local tax effort in turkey. International Research Journal of Finance and Economics, 13, 42–49.
  • Uriel, E., & Barberán, R. (2007). Las balanzas fiscales de las comunidades autónomas con la Administración Pública Central (1991-2005). Bilbao: Fundación BBVA.
  • Volden, C. (2007). Intergovernmental grants: A formal model of interrelated national and subnational political decisions. The Journal of Federalism, 37(2), 209–243.
  • Weingast, B. R. (2014). Second Generation Fiscal Federalism: Political Aspects of Decentralisation and Economic Development. World Development, 53, 14–25.
  • Xu, X., & Yan, Y. (2014). Does government investment crowd out private investment in China? Journal of Economic Policy Reform, 17(1), 1–12.
  • Zampelli, E. M. (1986). Resource fungibility, the flypaper effect and the expenditure impact of grants-in-aid. The Review of Economics and Statistics, 68(1), 33–40.

APPENDIX

Table 1A. Variables: definitions and sources

Table 2A. Descriptive statistics

Table 3A. Correlation matrix

Table 4A. Analysis of potential endogeneity